Skip to main content

Full text of "Review of the Administration's federal crop insurance reform proposal : hearings before the Subcommittee on Environment, Credit, and Rural Development of the Committee on Agriculture, House of Representatives, One Hundred Third Congress, second session"

See other formats


\^ 


REVIEW  OF  THE  ADMINISTRATION'S  FEDERAL 
CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  PROPOSAL 


Y4.AGB/l;103-60/PT.l 

Revieu  of  the  Adninistration's  Fede. 


HEARINGS 

BEFORE  THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT, 
AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

OF  THE 

COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 
HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

ONE  HUNDRED  THIRD  CONGRESS 
SECOND  SESSION 


MARCH  25,  1994 

APRIL  5,  1994,  LUVERNE,  MN 

APRIL  21,  1994 


Serial  No.  103-60 
PART  1 


n.. 


L'  C  V/    I  0    <v^\,,-  J 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the  Committee  on  Agricultixre 


U.S.  GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 
81-128  WASHINGTON  :  1994 

For  sale  by  the  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office 
Superintendent  of  Documents.  Congressional  Sales  Office,  Washington,  DC  20402 
ISBN  0-16-046037-9 


.'-N 


REVIEW  OF  THE  ADMINISTRATION'S  FEDERAL 
CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  PROPOSAL 


Y4,AG8/l;103-60/PT.l 

Revieu  of  the  Adninistration's  Fede... 

HEARINGS 

BEFORE  THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  OX  EMIROXMEXT,  CREDIT, 
AND  RURAL  DEA^LOPMEXT 

OF  THE 

COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 
HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

ONE  HUNDRED  THIRD  CONGRESS 

SECOND  SESSION 


MARCH  25,  1994 

APRIL  5,  1994,  LUVERNE,  MN 

APRIL  21,  1994 


Serial  No.  103-60 

PART  1 


DEC  1  3  ..,. . 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the  Committee  on  Agriculture 


U.S.   GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 
81-128  WASHINGTON  :  1994 

For  sale  by  the  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office 
Superintendent  of  Documents.  Congressional  Sales  Office,  Washington,  DC  20402 
ISBN  0-16-046037-9 


COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 


E  (KIKA)  DE 

GEORGE  E.  BROWN,  Jr.,  California, 

Vice  Chairman 
CHARLIE  ROSE,  North  Carolina 
DAN  GLICKMAN,  Kansas 
CHARLES  W.  STENHOLM,  Texas 
HAROLD  L.  VOLKMER,  Missouri 
TIMOTHY  J.  PENNY,  Minnesota 
TIM  JOHNSON,  South  Dakota 
BILL  SARPALIUS,  Texas 
JILL  L.  LONG,  Indiana 
GARY  A.  CONDIT,  CaUfomia 
COLLIN  C.  PETERSON,  Minnesota 
CALVIN  M.  DOOLEY,  CaUfomia 
EVA  M.  CLAYTON,  North  CaroUna 
DAVID  MINGE,  Minnesota 
EARL  F.  HILLIARD,  Alabama 
JAY  INSLEE,  Washington 
THOMAS  J.  BARLOW  III,  Kentucky 
EARL  POMEROY,  North  Dakota 
TIM  HOLDEN,  Pennsylvania 
CYNTHIA  A.  McKINNEY,  Georgia 
SCOTTY  BAESLER,  Kentucky 
KAREN  L.  THURMAN,  Florida 
SANFORD  D.  BISHOP,  Jr.,  Georgia 
BENNIE  G.  THOMPSON,  Mississippi 
SAM  FARR,  CaUfomia 
PAT  WILLIAMS,  Montana 
BLANCHE  M.  LAMBERT,  Arkansas 


LA  GARZA,  Texas,  Chairman 

PAT  ROBERTS,  Kansas, 

Ranking  Minority  Member 
BILL  EMERSON,  Missouri 
STEVE  GUNDERSON,  Wisconsin 
TOM  LEWIS,  Florida 
ROBERT  F.  (BOB)  SMITH,  Oregon 
LARRY  COMBEST,  Texas 
WAYNE  ALLARD,  Colorado 
BILL  BARRETT,  Nebraska 
JIM  NUSSLE,  Iowa 
JOHN  A.  BOEHNER,  Ohio 
THOMAS  W.  EWING,  IlUnois 
JOHN  T.  DOOLITTLE,  CaUfomia 
JACK  KINGSTON,  Georgia 
BOB  GOODLATTE,  Virginia 
JAY  DICKEY,  Arkansas 
RICHARD  W.  POMBO,  California 
CHARLES  T.  CANADY,  Florida 
NICK  SMITH,  Michigan 
TERRY  EVERETT,  Alabama 


Professional  Staff 

DiANNE  Powell,  Staff  Director 

Vernie  Hubert,  Chief  Counsel  and  Legislative  Director 

Gary  R.  Mitchell,  Minority  Staff  Director 

James  A.  Davis,  Press  Secretary 


Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural  Development 


TIM  JOHNSON, 

JILL  L.  LONG,  Indiana, 

Vice  Chairman 
EVA  M.  CLAYTON,  North  Carolina 
DAVID  MINGE,  Minnesota 
THOMAS  J.  BARLOW  III,  Kentucky 
EARL  POMEROY,  North  Dakota 
TIM  HOLDEN,  Pennsylvania 
CYNTHIA  A.  McKINNEY,  Georgia 
KAREN  L.  THURMAN,  Florida 
TIMOTHY  J.  PENNY,  Minnesota 
BILL  SARPALIUS,  Texas 
COLLIN  C.  PETERSON,  Minnesota 
EARL  F.  HILLIARD,  Alabama 
JAY  INSLEE,  Washington 
SCOTTY  BAESLER,  Kentucky 
BENNIE  G.  THOMPSON,  Mississippi 
SAM  FARR,  California 


South  Dakota,  Chairman 

LARRY  COMBEST,  Texas 
STEVE  GUNDERSON,  Wisconsin 
WAYNE  ALLARD,  Colorado 
BILL  BARRETT,  Nebraska 
JIM  NUSSLE,  Iowa 
THOMAS  W.  EWING,  IlUnois 
JAY  DICKEY,  Arkansas 
RICHARD  W.  POMBO,  CaUfomia 
NICK  SMITH,  Michigan 


(II) 


CONTENTS 


March  25,  1994 

Page 

Barrett,  Hon.  Bill,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Nebraska, 
opening  statement 4 

Combest,  Hon.  Larry,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Texas, 
opening  statement  3 

Ewing,  Hon.  Thomas  W.,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of 
IlUnois,  opening  statement  5 

Johnson,  Hon.  Tim,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  South 

Dakota,  opening  statement  1 

Minge,  Hon.  David,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Min- 
nesota, opening  statement 3 

Penny,  Hon.  Timothy  J.,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of 
Minnesota,  opening  statement  5 

Smith,  Hon.  Nick,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Michigan, 
opening  statement 6 

Witnesses 

Ackerman,  Kenneth  D.,  Manager,  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation,  U.S. 

Department  of  Agriculture  8 

Prepared  statement  37 

Moos,  Eugene,  Under  Secretary,  International  Affairs  and  Commodity  Pro- 
grams, U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture  7 

Prepared  statement  34 

April  5,  1994,  Luverne,  MN 

Johnson,  Hon.  Tim,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  South 

Dakota,  opening  statement  79 

Minge,  Hon.  David,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Min- 
nesota, opening  statement 81 

Peterson,  Hon.  CoUin  C,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of 

Minnesota,  opening  statement  81 

Written  response  from  U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture  152 

Witnesses 

Ackerman,  Kenneth  D.,  Manager,  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation,  U.S. 

Department  of  Agriculture  82 

Prepared  statement  133 

Buschette,  Francis,  on  behalf  of  the  Minnesota  Association  of  Wheat  Growers  98 

Prepared  statement  161 

Christopherson,  Al,  president,  Minnesota  Farm  Bureau  Federation  96 

Prepared  statement  154 

Crowley,  Mike,  agent.  Crop  Agency,  Inc 108 

Prepared  statement  174 

Frederickson,  David  J.,  president,  Minnesota  Farmers  Union  101 

Prepared  statement  168 

Gyberg,  Stan,  farmer,  Luverne,  MN  127 

Keister,  John  R.,  Blue  Earth,  MN 122 

Prepared  statement  203 

Kleven,  Bruce  M.,  staff  attorney.  Farmers'  Legal  Action  Group,  Inc 124 

Prepared  statement 207 

Lacey,  Gerald,  president.  National  Barley  Growers  Association  100 

(in) 


IV 

Page 

Lacey,  Gerald,  president,  National  Barley  Growers  Association — Continued 

Prepared  statement  164 

Lewis,  Jim,  Luverne,  MN 125 

Lindholm,  Steve,  president,  Farmers  &  Merchants  State  Bank  of  Clarkfield, 

Clarkfield,  MN Ill 

Prepared  statement  191 

Marin,  Donald  R.,  agent  and  owner,  Marin-Biel  Insurance,  Inc.,  on  behalf 

of  the  National  Association  of  Professional  Insurance  Agents  110 

Prepared  statement  181 

Peterson,  Richard,  on  behalf  of  the  Minnesota  Com  Growers  Association 

and  the  Minnesota  Soybean  Growers  Association 98 

Prepared  statement  157 

Smestad,  Eugene  C,  branch  manager/insurance  director,  Farm  Credit  Serv- 
ices of  Fargo,  Valley  City,  ND 114 

Prepared  statement  197 

White,  Randy,  State  representative.  North  Central  Crop  Insurance,  Inc  129 

Willers,  Mack,  farmer,  Beaver  Creek,  MN  128 

Submitted  Material 

Weber,  William  V,  mayor,  city  of  Luverne,  MN,  letter  of  April  1,  1994  214 

Wheelock,  Greg,  Crop  Insurance  Services,  comments  and  suggestions  215 

April  21,  1994 

Allard,  Hon.  Wayne,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Colorado, 

opening  statement 222 

Combest,  Hon.  Larry,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Texas, 

opening  statement 221 

Johnson,  Hon.  Tim,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  South 

Dakota,  opening  statement  219 

Pomeroy,  Hon.  Earl,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  North 

Dakota,  prepared  statement 223 

Sarpalius,  Hon.  Bill,  a  Representative  in  Congress  from  the  State  of  Texas, 

opening  statement 222 

Witnesses 

Bums,  Phil,  president.  Farmers  and  Merchants  National  Bank,  West  Point, 

NE,  on  behalf  of  the  American  Bankers  Association  235 

Prepared  statement  268 

Conneab^,  Michael,  on  behalf  of  Rvu-al  Community  Insurance  Services,  Inc 254 

Prepared  statement 297 

Diedrich,  Larry,  president,  American  Soybean  Association  233 

Prepared  statement  265 

Hart,  James  F.,  president  and  CEO,  Hand  County  State  Bank,  Miller,  SD, 

on  behalf  of  the  Independent  Bankers  Association  of  America 237 

Prepared  statement  271 

Joyce,  John  H.,  chairman,  American  Association  of  Crop  Insiu-ers  256 

Prepared  statement  302 

Merja,  Chuck,  secretary/treasurer,  National  Association  of  Wheat  Growers  239 

Prepared  statement  • 277 

Mitchell,  Myrl,  chairman,  crop  insurance  advisory  task  force.  National  Cotton 

Council  of  America  241 

Prepared  statement  282 

Odom,  Bob,  commissioner,  Louisiana  Department  of  Agriculture  and  Forestry, 

and  president.  National  Association  of  State  Departments  of  Agriculture  224 

Prepared  statement  262 

Ozer,  Katherine,  director.  National  Family  Farm  Coalition 243 

Prepared  statement  286 

Parkerson,  Robert,  president.  National  Crop  Insurance  Services  258 

Prepared  statement  •• •. ^28 

Rahjes,  Doyle,  president,  Kansas  Farm  Bureau,  and  board  member,  American 

Farm  Bureau  Federation 245 

PrGD^TGci  stfltdTiGnt  ^yu 

Rudisill,  Thomas  A,  chairman.  Crop  insurance  Research  Bureau,  Inc 259 

Prepared  statement  ^^^ 


V 

Page 

Swenson,  Leland,  president,  National  Farmers  Union,  presented  by  Nancy 

F.  Danielson,  legislative  analyst 247 

Prepared  statement  293 

Submitted  Material 

American  Agriculture  Movement,  et  cetera,  letter  of  April  19,  1994  336 

American  Association  of  Nurserymen,  statement 337 

Barr,  Terry  N.,  chief  economist.  National  Council  of  Farmers  Cooperatives, 

statement  342 

Dakota  Rural  Action,  statement 345 

Fender,  Douglas  H.,  executive  director,  American  Sod  Producers  Association, 

statement  347 

Mosier,  Rodney,  executive  assistant,  Texas  Wheat  Producers  Association,  let- 
ter of  March  28,  1993 354 

National  Sunflower  Association,  statement 350 

Nodland,  Randolph,  Dakota  Resource  Council,  statement 352 

Orwig,   Deanna,  National  Association  of  Crop   Insurance  Agents,  letter  of 

April  20,  1994  357 

Panetta,  Leon  E.,  Director,  Office  of  Management  and  Budget,  letter  of  April 

14,  1994  389 

Plains  Cotton  Growers,  Inc.,  statement 390 

Weber,  William,  R.,  president  and  chief  executive  officer.  Farm  Credit  Coun- 
cil, statement  393 


REVIEW  OF  THE  ADMINISTRATION'S  FED- 
ERAL CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  PRO- 
POSAL 


FRroAY,  MARCH  25,  1994 

House  of  Representatrts, 
Subcommittee  on  Environment.  Credit. 

AND  RUR-AL  DEV-ELOPMENT, 

Com^httee  on  Agriculture, 

Washington,  DC. 

The  subcommittee  met,  pursuant  to  call,  at  10:35  a.m.,  in  room 
1302,  Longv-'orth  House  Office  Building,  Hon.  Tim  Johnson  i  chair- 
man of  the  subcommittee  I  presiding. 

Present:  Representatives  Minge,  Pomeroy,  Penny,  Peterson,  Corn- 
best,  Gunderson.  Barrett,  Ewing.  and  Smith  of  Michigan. 

Staff  present:  Glenda  L.  Temple,  clerk;  Anne  Simmons  and  Da\id 
Ebersole. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  TIM  JOHNSON,  A  REPRESENT- 
ATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  SOUTH  DAKOTA 

Mr.  Johnson.  We  will  bring  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment, 
Credit,  and  Rural  Development  to  order. 

I  have  called  this  hearing  to  re\'ie\v  the  administration's  com- 
prehensive proposal,  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of 
1994,  for  the  reform  of  our  Nation's  crop  insurance  program.  The 
need  for  reform  has  been  apparent  to  me  for  some  time,  and  was 
dramatized  as  I  toured  the  Midwest  flood  States  this  past  summer 
and  listened  to  the  many  concerns  of  the  producers  throughout  the 
region. 

Currently,  clearly,  our  Government  is  involved  in  a  dual  system, 
one  of  crop  insurance,  the  other  of  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  paNinents: 
and  frankly,  neither  of  them  work  as  well  as  they  ought.  The  gen- 
eral consensus  is  that  the  crop  insurance  program  is  not  fully  ade- 
quate to  the  needs  of  American  farmers. 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  experiences  large  losses 
more  years  than  not,  pegged  at  almost  SI  billion  this  year.  On  top 
of  this,  the  Congress  has  authorized  ad  hoc  disaster  programs 
every  year  since  1986. 

One  goal  of  the  1980  overhaul  of  the  crop  insurance  program  was 
to  eliminate  the  need  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs.  Clearly,  this 
has  not  occurred.  Despite  the  fact  that  the  Federal  Government  has 
spent  an  average  of  SI. 7  billion,  combined,  for  crop  insurance  and 
ad  hoc  disaster  pa>Tnents  each  year  over  the  past  10  years,  many 
producers  are  not  satisfied  with  either  program. 

(1) 


Producer  dissatisfaction  with  crop  insurance  is  evidenced  by  the 
fact  that  participation  is  limited;  only  30  percent  of  the  eligible 
acreage  is  enrolled,  and  when  they  do  experience  crop  losses,  cov- 
erage is  often  deemed  to  be  inadequate.  Ad  hoc  disaster  payments 
are  unpredictable  in  that  they  require  emergency  appropriations 
which,  in  turn,  generally  requires  large  regional  disasters  that  are 
subject  to  the  political  whims  of  the  moment.  Producers  cannot 
budget  for  ad  hoc  disaster  payments,  and  it  makes  finsincial  plan- 
ning for  them  and  for  the  lending  institutions  virtually  impossible. 

We  have  two  programs,  purportedly  working  side  by  side,  to  help 
producers,  but  in  many  respects,  they  are  working  at  cross-pur- 
poses. The  very  existence  of  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  undermines 
producer  willingness  to  invest  in  crop  insurance,  and  many  produc- 
ers all  too  often  do  not  take  out  crop  insurance  because  they  believe 
that  the  Federal  Government  will  in  fact  bail  them  out  by  offering 
free  ad  hoc  disaster  pa3mients. 

I  commend  the  administration  for  taking  a  comprehensive  ap- 
proach to  reform.  Offering  one  program  that  combines  crop  insur- 
ance for  program  crops  with  catastrophic  insurance  for  nonprogram 
crops  addresses  many  of  the  problems  enumerated. 

This  subcommittee  must  now  examine  the  details  of  the  adminis- 
tration's bill.  Above  all,  any  crop  insurance  proposal  must  be  fis- 
cally and  actuarially  sound  and  within  our  budget  requirements. 
Producers  must  be  convinced  of  two  things:  One,  that  their  out-of- 
pocket  costs  for  insurance  must  be  commensurate  with  potential  in- 
demnities that  they  may  earn;  and  second,  ad  hoc  chsaster  pro- 
grams are  a  thing  of  the  past. 

It  will  be  essential  that  Congress  goes  beyond  merely  restating 
its  opposition  to  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  programs  if  this  reform  is  in 
fact  going  to  work.  That  was  attempted  in  1980  and  proved  fully 
ineffective.  Part  and  parcel  of  any  effective  reform  will  have  to  be 
changes  in  the  budget  rules  that  will  make  ad  hoc  crop  disaster 
payments  in  the  future  exceedingly  difficult  to  come  by,  rather 
than  simply  adding  them  to  the  Federal  deficit  without  restraint  of 
pay-go  rules. 

There  are  many  other  concerns  that  have  been  expressed  to  me 
about  the  administration's  proposal,  ideas  and  thoughts  about  how 
to  implement  this  concept,  this  bill,  and  I  will  discuss  them  later 
in  the  hearing. 

This  hearing  is  the  first  in  a  series  I  will  be  having  on  crop  in- 
surance. On  April  5,  I  will  be  holding  a  field  hearing  in  Mr.  Minge's 
district  in  Minnesota,  and  on  April  21,  I  have  scheduled  a  hearing 
here  in  Washington  with  additional  outside  witnesses. 

But  I  plan  on  being,  as  chairman  of  this  subcommittee,  very, 
very  aggressive  in  moving  this  legislation  through  this  subcommit- 
tee; and  I  plan  on  holding  a  markup  as  soon  as  the  schedule  at  all 
permits.  I  think  this  is  a  matter  of  extreme  importance,  and  I  do 
not  think  it  is  in  our  best  interests  to  allow  this  issue  to  lay  over 
to  the  1995  farm  bill  debate  of  the  next  Congress, 

I  will  continue  to  work  with  Chairman  de  la  Garza,  Ranking  Mi- 
nority Member  Combest,  and  with  other  members  of  the  committee 
as  this  legislation  moves  to  full  committee. 

I  would  like  to  welcome  Gene  Moos  and  Ken  Ackerman  to  the 
subcommittee  today.  I  look  forward  to  hearing  their  testimony. 


I  recognize  the  ranking  minority  member  of  this  subcommittee, 
a  Member  who  has  great  credibility  on  agricultural  issues  in  gen- 
eral, on  both  sides  of  the  aisle,  the  gentleman  from  Texas,  Mr. 
Combest. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  LARRY  COMBEST,  A 
REPRESENTATIVE  IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  TEXAS 

Mr.  Combest.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  believe  that  we  have  before  us  today  the  foun- 
dation of  a  workable  crop  insurance  program,  and  if  we  can  find 
the  means  to  adopt  some  form  of  it,  we  should  do  so. 

With  the  exception  of  1987,  the  Congress,  since  1986,  has  paid 
out  huge  sums  annually  for  disaster  assistance  in  addition  to  crop 
insurance  indemnities.  This  legislation  has  the  potential  to  solve 
this  problem.  Assuming  the  FCIC  numbers  are  correct,  I  also  be- 
lieve the  legislation  could  provide  incentives  for  producers  who 
have  never  purchased  crop  insurance  to  buy  coverage  at  increased 
levels  at  an  affordable  price.  This  may  be  the  answer  to  the  low 
participation  problem. 

Solving  these  two  issues  would  be  a  public  policy  success  for  Ag- 
riculture. Our  problems  now  lie  in  the  budget  process,  and  as  be- 
fore, when  a  catastrophic  insurance  program  was  discussed,  lack  of 
money  may  be  this  proposal's  undoing. 

I  know  there  are  different  opinions  on  how  this  program  should 
be  implemented  and  administered  in  the  field.  As  we  proceed,  how- 
ever, I  hope  that  all  of  us  on  the  subcommittee  will  keep  an  open 
mind  and  let  the  process  work.  I  also  hope  that  the  crop  insurance 
industry,  as  well  as  FCIC  officials,  will  work  together  toward  a 
common  goal.  American  agriculture  would  benefit  substantially. 

Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Combest. 

The  gentleman  from  Minnesota,  Mr.  Minge. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  DAVID  MINGE,  A  REPRESENT- 
ATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  MINNESOTA 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  would  just  like  to  make 
a  brief  comment,  and  that  is  that  we  have  had  a  chance,  of  course, 
to  review  the  outline  of  the  proposed  reforms;  and  I  find  them  very 
exciting.  I  think  that  this  is  long  overdue  and  represents  an  aggres- 
sive position  on  the  part  of  the  administration  to  try  not  only  to 
improve  crop  insurance,  but  also  to  reconcile  the  inherent  inconsist- 
ency between  a  good  crop  insurance  program  and  an  ad  hoc  disas- 
ter program. 

My  experience  has  led  me  to  conclude  that  we  have  a  number  of 
inequities  in  the  crop  insurance  program  as  it  currently  exists,  not 
the  least  of  which  is  a  regional  inequity  in  that  users  or  partici- 
pants in  certain  parts  of  the  country  are  pajdng  a  disproportionate 
share  of  the  cost  of  crop  insurance,  and  users  in  other  parts  of  the 
country  are  being  heavily  subsidized  both  by  those  premiums  and 
also  by  the  Federal  Government. 

We  have  additional  problems  in  that  the  yield  bases  in  parts  of 
the  country  and  for  several  crops  are  very  conservative,  and  this 
has  led  to  really  an  extreme  level  of  disappointment  and  unhappi- 
ness  with  many  of  the  users  of  Federal  crop  insurance  because  they 


find  that  they  are  not  being  adequately  covered  for  the  losses  that 
they  are  incurring. 

An  additional  problem  that  we  faced  is  the  difficulty  of  farmers 
who  are  trying  to  purchase  higher  levels  of  crop  insurance  cov- 
erage; and  I  recognize  that  there  are  problems  of  high  premium 
costs  once  you  receive — reach  those  levels,  but  I  am  hopeful  that 
we  will  be  able  to  offer  a  comprehensive  package  that  will  give 
farmers  the  opportunity  to  at  least  elect  a  level  of  coverage  that 
they  feel  is  important  in  their  operation,  and  decide  whether  or  not 
the  cost  is  one  that  is  prohibitive  or  not. 

Finally,  I  would  like  to  point  out  the  problem  that  beginning 
farmers  face — and  I  know  that  there  is  an  attempt  to  address  that, 
but  I  would  like  to  see  it  sharpened  up  a  little  bit — and  that  is, 
how  do  they  deal  with  the  lack  of  a  base,  period,  to  establish  a 
yield  that  is  used  to  calculate  the  level  of  protection  that  they  re- 
ceive when  they  have  not  been  farming?  And  many  of  these  begin- 
ning farmers  are  individuals  who  have  extensive  experience  with 
their  family.  Also  many  of  them  are  people  who  have  had  good 
training  in  our  universities  and  technical  colleges  and  are  deter- 
mined to  farm  using  the  best  management  practices,  and  from 
what  I  have  seen,  many  of  these  beginning  farmers  have  yields 
which  outstrip  most  of  their  neighbors,  because  in  fact  they  are  cre- 
ative, imaginative,  hard-working  young  farmers,  and  they  need  and 
deserve  adequate  levels  of  protection  as  opposed  to  having  to  use 
some  t5rpe  of  a  county  average  which  puts  them  at  a  severe  dis- 
advantage. 

So  these  are  but  a  few  of  the  additional  topics  that  I  think  go 
beyond  the  interrelationship  between  crop  insurance  and  the  disas- 
ter program  that  ought  to  be  addressed  in  Federal  crop  insurance 
reform,  and  I  would  like  to  personally  thank  you,  Mr.  Ackerman, 
for  the  time  that  you  have  taken  going  around  the  country  to  ex- 
plain the  ideas  that  you  have  been  considering  in  the  Federal  crop 
insurance  reform,  because  I  can  tell  you,  from  my  experience,  that 
your  visit  to  Minnesota  was  very  well  received,  and  the  credibility 
of  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program  was  enhanced  substantially 
by  your  taking  a  day  out  of  your  schedule  to  spend  in  sub-zero  Min- 
nesota after  having  spent  the  previous  2  weeks  in  a  much  more 
hospitable  climate. 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you. 

The  gentleman  from  Nebraska,  Mr.  Barrett. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  BILL  BARRETT,  A  REPRESENT- 
ATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  NEBRASKA 

Mr.  Barrett.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I,  too,  want  to  com- 
pliment you  for  holding  this  hearing  on  the  administration's  plan 
to  reform  our  crop  insurance  program;  and  I  thank  you,  Mr.  Moos, 
and  you,  Mr.  Ackerman,  for  taking  the  time  and  the  trouble  to 
share  with  us  as  well. 

At  least  in  the  last  8  years  that  I  have  paid  much  attention,  we 
have  spent  probably  $1  billion  each  year  on  disaster  payments,  and 
that  is  on  top  of,  what,  a  $900  million  set-aside  for  crop  insur- 
ance— in  light  of  that  spending,  I  am  terribly  concerned  about  the 
final  product,  what  we  might  be  coming  up  with.  I  am  hoping  that 


the  reform  plan  ultimately  will  make  certain  that  we  can  stop  the 
disaster  payments. 

I  must  say  at  this  point  I  am  a  little  bit  skeptical,  but  I  hope 
I  and  the  rest  of  the  committee  will  maintain  somewhat  of  an  open 
mind,  and  perhaps  we  can  work  through  this  thing  and  come  up 
with  something  that  is  acceptable  to  everyone. 

Thank  you  very  much;  and  thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  gentleman  from  Minnesota,  Mr.  Penny. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  TIMOTHY  J.  PENNY,  A  REP- 
RESENTATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  MIN- 
NESOTA 

Mr.  Penny.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  first  of  all  want  to  commend  Mr.  Espy  and  his  colleagues  at  the 
Department  of  Agriculture  for  their  strong  leadership  on  a  whole 
range  of  issues  in  the  last  year.  I  am  excited  about  their  Depart- 
ment reorganization  effort;  I  am  pleased  with  the  attention  they 
seem  to  be  devoting  to  restructuring  the  foreign  ag  service  and  re- 
lated issues;  and  here  is  another  example  where  they  are  ahead  of 
the  curve. 

Not  that  we  shouldn't  have  done  something  about  crop  insurance 
reform  many  years  ago,  but  to  be  only  12  months  into  this  adminis- 
tration and  to  have  a  major  proposal  for  consideration  by  Congress 
is  something  that  is  quite  encouraging. 

Frankly,  in  all  of  the  years  I  have  been  here — and  I  am  not  one 
to  make  partisan  remarks,  and  I  don't  mean  this  in  a  partisan 
sense — ^but  I  do  feel  that  the  efficacy  we  have  seen  for  farmers  in 
the  last  12  months  is  markedly  different  and  better  than  the  sort 
of  response  that  we  had  in  all  the  earlier  years.  Because  you  are 
out  front,  you  aren't  lagging  behind. 

We  on  this  committee  aren't  begging  you  to  pay  attention  to  an 
issue.  More  often  than  not,  we  are  applauding  you  for  being  on  top 
of  an  issue.  And  this  is  just  another  example  of  where  you  have 
t£iken  charge  and  put  a  very  laudable  proposal  on  the  table. 

We  may  dicker  a  little  about  what  the  payment  rate  ought  to  be 
for  the  catastrophic  coverage  and  other  details  of  the  bill,  but  in 
general  thrust,  it  is  a  sign  of — in  general  thrust,  it  is  a  proposal 
that  has  a  lot  of  merit,  and  in  the  final  analysis,  I  think  we  can 
move  this  legislation  rather  quickly. 

I  again  just  want  to  compliment  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Ewing. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  THOMAS  W.  EWING,  A  REP- 
RESENTATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  ILLINOIS 

Mr.  Ewing .  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  thank  you  for  hold- 
ing these  hearings. 

And  to  our  guests,  thank  you  for  your  appearance  and  your  in- 
volvement. 

In  the  short  time  that  I  have  been  in  Congress,  Federal  crop  in- 
surance has  been  an  issue  in  my  district  and  something  that  I  have 
been  trying  to  work  to  improve,  have  introduced  some  legislation 
in  that  regard,  worked  with  both  sides  of  the  aisle  in  the  Bush  ad- 
ministration, and  now  in  the  Clinton  administration,  to  try  and 


come  up  with  a  plan  that  works.  And  I  think  we  are  making  some 
headway. 

I  think  we  have  the  basis  with  this  legislation  to  do  something 
to  help  make  our  crop  insurance  program  the  floor  or  the  net  that 
we  need  to  protect  agriculture  from  disasters  and,  hopefully,  to 
avoid  the  need  for  special  disaster  payments. 

I  would  say  that  a  problem  we  have  here  in  Washington  often 
is  trying  to  make  one  size  fit  all.  American  agriculture  is  very  di- 
verse; it  is  very  different  even  in  Illinois  from  one  district  to  an- 
other and  from  one  section  to  another.  So  I  think  we  have  to  look 
at  that  and  see  if  we  can  make  flexibility  in  the  program,  put  flexi- 
bility in  the  program  so  that  it  will  work  and  it  will  serve  as  many 
of  our  agricultural  producers  across  the  Nation  as  possible. 

In  our  particular  area  in  Illinois,  without  bragging,  we  have  the 
best,  and  when  you  have  the  best  farmland  in  the  world — and  I  am 
not  bragging — then,  of  course,  you  have  to  have  higher  limits  if  you 
are  going  to  have  protection,  and  that  is  a  problem.  We  have  pro- 
ducers who  would  never  have  collected  under  the  current  pro- 
grams, who  aren't  real  interested  in  a  program  when  it  doesn't  ben- 
efit them. 

So  I  look  forward  to  working  with  you  and  with  the  chairman  in 
trjdng  to  have  some  input  on  this  legislation;  and  hopefully,  we  can 
get  a  good  bill  and  get  it  signed  soon. 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  gentleman  from  Minnesota,  Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  Thank  you  and  every- 
one for  their  leadership.  Rather  than  plow  all  the  ground  one  more 
time,  I  will  just  say,  amen,  let's  get  going  and  let's  get  it  done. 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  gentleman  from  Michigan,  Mr.  Smith. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  NICK  SMITH,  A  REPRESENTA- 
TIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  MICHIGAN 

Mr.  Smith  of  Michigan.  Mr.  Chairman,  thank  you. 

Also,  Mr.  Ackerman  and  Mr.  Moos,  I  compliment  you  on  your  en- 
ergetic work. 

I  would  especially  like  to  associate  myself  with  the  comments 
made  by  the  gentleman  from  Minnesota,  Mr.  Minge.  I  think  that 
we  need  to  resist  the  temptation  to  require  everybody  to  pay  a  base 
premium  that  spreads  the  cost  and  makes  it  cheaper  for  everybody. 
The  more  we  can  make  premiums  reflect  real  risks  for  different 
areas  of  the  country  and  for  different  farmers,  the  greater  the 
chances  are  that  it  will  be  well  accepted  and  well  used  in  agri- 
culture. 

I  see  an  agricultural  community  in  Michigan  that  has  been  reluc- 
tant to  buy  crop  insurance  simply  because  the  costs  were  much 
greater  than  the  ultimate  benefits  that  most  farmers  have  experi- 
enced. 

I  would  like  to  make  one  more  comment.  It  is  unfair  that  there 
has  to  be  wide  spread  disasters  in  order  for  a  single  farmer  to  re- 
ceive benefits.  A  farmer  can  be  wiped  out  by  hail,  but  if  the  county 
isn't  declared  a  disaster  that  farmer  doesn't  get  as  much  help.  As 
a  freshman,  I  see  a  Congress  that  has  changed  over  the  years  since 
I  was  in  USDA.  There  is  less  interest  in  the  future  of  production 


agriculture;  there  is  probably  less  knowledge  of  how  agriculture 
really  works.  So  I  am  concerned  that  pressures  coming  from  the  po- 
litical system  outside  the  Department  of  Agriculture  put  consum- 
ers' interests  higher  than  they  should  be  in  determining  how  to 
best  develop  a  strong  future  for  production  agriculture. 

Thanks,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  We  will  proceed  with  our  panel.  We 
have  a  one-panel  hearing  today,  but  I  think  it  will  be  very  valuable 
to  the  subcommittee  and  to  our  staffs. 

With  us  today  is  the  Honorable  Eugene  Moos,  who  is  Under  Sec- 
retary for  International  Affairs  and  Commodity  Programs,  U.S.  De- 
partment of  Agriculture;  and  he  is  accompanied  by  Mr.  Kenneth 
Ackerman,  Manager,  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  of 
USDA. 

Welcome  to  you  both.  Your  full  statements  are  received  for  the 
record,  and  you  may  choose  to  summarize  or  to  proceed  however 
you  wish.  We  welcome  you  to  the  subcommittee. 

STATEMENT  OF  EUGENE  MOOS,  UNDER  SECRETARY,  INTER- 
NATIONAL AFFAIRS  AND  COMMODITY  PROGRAMS,  U.S.  DE- 
PARTMENT OF  AGRICULTURE,  ACCOMPANIED  BY  KENNETH 
D.  ACKERMAN,  MANAGER,  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  COR- 
PORATION 

Mr.  Moos.  Thank  you  very  much,  Chairman  Johnson,  for  the  op- 
portunity to  appear  before  you  this  morning.  We  want  to  express 
our  appreciation  to  you  and  to  the  members  of  this  subcommittee 
for  their  interest  in  this  very  important  issue. 

I  am  particularly  impressed  by  the  interest  that  is  being  shown 
here  this  morning  in  terms  of  the  number  of  your  subcommittee 
members  who  are  still  in  town  and  felt  it  was  important  to  be  a 
participant  in  this  kind  of  a  hearing. 

Before  I  turn  over  the  testimony  to  our  Manager,  Ken  Ackerman, 
I  would  like  to  make  a  couple  of  comments.  I  have  a  short  state- 
ment that  I  hope  can  be  included  in  the  record.  But  I  want  to  talk 
for  just  a  second  about  the  fact  that  the  Department  is  very  mis- 
sion-oriented. 

One  of  the  missions,  of  course,  is  the  mission  that  my  office  is 
responsible  for;  namely,  for  the  mission  to  maintain  the  viability  of 
production  agriculture  in  this  country.  And  that  is,  as  I  look  at  the 
challenge  in  that  regard,  I  look  at  the  need  for  the  necessary  tools, 
both  the  domestic  policy  tools  as  well  as  the  international  policy 
tools,  to  accomplish  that  kind  of  a  mission.  We  have  got  to  main- 
tain a  viable  agricultural  economy  out  there  across  the  United 
States,  £ind  we  have  got  to  have  the  tools  then  to  compete  in  the 
world  market  if  we  are  going  to  really  take  advantage  of  the  com- 
parative advantage  that  we  have  here  in  the  United  States  as  re- 
gards our  agricultural  potential. 

I  look  upon  crop  insurance  as  one  of  the  most  important  tools  in 
terms  of  domestic  policy.  Given  the  huge  capital  requirements  on 
an  annual  basis  that  American  farmers  experience  each  year,  we 
need  to  do  what  we  can  to  provide  a  basis  of  strong  support  in  that 
risk  management. 


8 

So,  again,  I  welcome  the  opportunity  to  appear  here  and  thank 
you  very  kindly;  and  I  will  now  call  on  the  Manager,  Ken  Acker- 
man. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Moos  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Moos.  Now,  Mr.  Ackerman. 

STATEMENT  OF  KENNETH  D.  ACKERMAN,  MANAGER,  FEDERAL 
CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION,  U.S.  DEPARTMENT  OF  AG- 
RICULTURE 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  want  to  echo  Under 
Secretary  Moos's  thanks  to  the  subcommittee  for  holding  this  hear- 
ing very  promptly  and  for  moving  very  quickly  on  this  proposal. 
Secretary  Espy  transmitted  legislation  to  Congress  just  a  few 
weeks  ago,  and  we  are  already  at  this  point  in  the  hearings. 

This  is  a  proposal  which,  because  of  the  timeframes  involved  and 
the  possibility  of  the  thought  toward  implementation,  really  re- 
quires action  on  a  fairly  quick  basis;  and  we  do  very  much  appre- 
ciate this  very  prompt  hearing  and  discussion  of  the  legislation. 

As  was  evident  from  a  lot  of  the  comments  by  members  of  the 
subcommittee,  crop  insurance  is  a  program  which,  as  much  as  any 
other  program  in  Washington,  has  been  the  subject  of  criticism, 
discontent,  and  of  calls  for  change;  and  those  calls  for  change  come 
from  almost  every  direction.  You  hear  criticisms  from  farmers,  from 
taxpayers,  from  Congress,  from  Presidents,  from  GAG,  from  the  In- 
spector Greneral — ^you  name  it,  and  they  have  criticized  crop  insur- 
ance. 

To  a  great  extent,  much  of  the  current  dilemma  comes  from  the 
fact  that  crop  insurance  is  caught  between  two  major  historical 
forces.  On  the  one  side,  the  past  half-dozen  years  we  have  seen  an 
unprecedented  parade  of  natural  disasters  causing  damage  to  agri- 
culture. Beginning  with  the  1988  drought  of  the  century,  the  1989 
drought,  the  1992  hurricane  of  the  century,  the  1993  flood  of  the 
half  millenium  coming  the  same  year  as  a  major  drought  in  the 
Southeast. 

Farmers  are  very  aware  today  that  they  need  protection.  Along 
with  the  awareness  of  risk,  we  are  undergoing  a  period  of  historic 
budget  restraint.  Because  the  Federal  Government  of  this  country 
has  a  historically  high  deficit,  deficit  reduction  is  one  of  the  pre- 
eminent domestic  priorities. 

Last  year,  as  part  of  the  reconciliation  process,  Agriculture  was 
required  to  make  cuts  of  $3  billion.  Presumably  as  the  deficit  re- 
duction pressures  continue  in  future  years.  Agriculture  will  con- 
tinue to  be  front  and  center.  So  crop  insurance  finds  itself  between 
these  two  forces  of  more  awareness  of  risk  and  tighter  budgets. 

The  problems  were  highlighted  very  much  by  the  crisis  last  sum- 
mer, the  combination  of  a  major  flood  or  series  of  floods  in  the  Mid- 
west coming  at  the  same  time  as  a  major  drought  in  the  Southeast. 
These  crises  really  exposed  many  of  the  problems  in  the  crop  insur- 
ance program. 

For  one  thing,  there  was  the  sheer  magnitude  of  the  loss.  Just 
to  give  you  some  impression  of  it,  for  crop  year  1993  to  date,  the 
crop  insurance  program  has  paid  out  $1.64  billion  in  claims  to 
farmers  across  the  country.  By  comparison,  in  1992,  the  year  of 


Hurricane  Andrew,  we  paid  out  $920  million  in  claims  across  the 
country.  That  is  $700  million  less;  and  the  difference  is  the  amount 
of  damage  that  occurred  in  American  agriculture  this  past  year. 

To  give  you  another  comparison,  in  crop  year  1988,  the  year  of 
the  big  drought,  we  paid  out  $1.2  billion  in  claims  at  a  time  when 
our  system  was  not  as  financially  tight  as  it  is  today.  That,  too,  is 
$400  million  less  than  we  paid  out  for  1993,  again  because  of  the 
magnitude  of  the  damage  in  American  agriculture  last  summer. 

'nie  kind  of  weaknesses  that  this  revealed  in  the  crop  insurance 
program  surfaced  on  many  levels.  For  instance,  the  fact  that  most 
farmers  did  not  have  preventive  planning  coverage,  something  that 
we  have  since  fixed  to  a  great  extent;  the  fact  that  we  had  a  prob- 
lem with  overly  rigid  price  selections. 

But  the  biggest  problem  that  was  made  evident  by  the  crisis  last 
summer  is  one  that  Chairman  Johnson  mentioned  and  that  a  lot 
of  other  Members  have  referred  to,  and  that  is  that  we  have  devel- 
oped in  this  country  over  the  past  several  years  two  parallel  sys- 
tems operating  side  by  side,  tr3dng  to  address  the  same  problem, 
which  is  crop  loss  for  farmers  from  unavoidable,  natural  causes. 

On  the  one  hand,  you  have  crop  insurance  costing  upwards  to- 
ward $900  million  every  year,  a  lot  of  money;  and  at  the  same 
time,  despite  that  investment,  the  Grovemment  has  had  to  step  in, 
Washington  has  had  to  step  in  with  ad  hoc  disaster  pajnnents  in 
8  out  of  the  last  8  years,  as  the  chart  over  here  demonstrates. 

What  we  have  seen  is  that  disaster  programs  are  good  at  serving 
a  purpose.  They  have,  in  fact,  gotten  millions  of  Americans  through 
times  of  very  severe  crisis.  They  were  a  very  responsible  act  of  Cjov- 
emment. 

However,  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  have  created  a  very  harmful 
tjrpe  of  uncertainty,  both  for  farmers  and  for  taxpayers.  From  the 
farmers'  point  of  view,  the  main  problem  is  that  if  you  do  not  have 
crop  insurance  and  you  are  rel3dng  on  disaster  aid,  you  simply 
don't  know  at  the  beginning  of  the  year  what  your  protection  is 
going  to  be. 

As  you  can  see  from  the  chart,  some  years  there  were  large  dis- 
aster programs,  and  some  years  there  were  none  at  all.  Some  years 
the  formulas  were  different  than  others. 

If  you  are  a  farmer  and  you  suffer  a  loss  and  you  don't  have  crop 
insurance,  you  have  to  worry  whether  farmers  in  the  rest  of  your 
State  or  in  10  or  20  other  States  are  having  similar  losses  in  order 
for  the  political  momentum  for  a  disaster  bill  to  move  forward. 

Farmers  who  suffered  losses  from  Hurricane  Andrew  in  1992  re- 
ceived disaster  aid  at  50  percent  proration.  Farmers  who  suffered 
losses  in  the  1993  flood  received  the  aid  at  100  percent  proration. 

From  the  point  of  view  of  the  farmer  who  suffered  the  loss,  it 
was  no  different  from  one  year  to  another;  he  or  she  suffered  a  loss. 
However,  because  of  the  number  of  States  involved,  the  aid  was  dif- 
ferent. This  kind  of  uncertainty  is  simply  no  way  to  run  a  farm  as 
a  business. 

From  the  point  of  view  of  taxpayers,  you  have  the  same  problem. 
Ad  hoc  disaster  aid  is  off-budget,  emergency  spending.  It  is  voted 
by  Congress,  signed  by  the  President;  it  goes  directly  to  the  Federal 
deficit.  It  is  not  subject  to  the  same  types  of  budget  discipline  rules 
that  govern  virtually  every  other  kind  of  Federal  spending. 


10 

As  a  result,  what  we  have  seen  is  that  while  the  average  disaster 
aid  expenditure  over  the  past  10  years,  simple  arithmetic  average, 
has  been  about  $1  billion  a  year  for  crop  loss,  the  disaster — ^the  av- 
erage expenditure  over  the  past  6  years  has  been  over  $1.5  billion. 
The  numbers  keep  rising,  and  we  are  seeing  a  growing  resistance, 
both  within  Congress  and  in  the  public,  to  this  continual  parade  of 
disaster  bills.  Every  one  of  them  has  become  incrementally  harder 
to  pass  on  the  floor  of  the  House  and  Senate. 

In  response  to  this  set  of  problems.  Secretary  Espy  announced  3 
weeks  ago  a  reform  package  which  tries  to  correct  crop  insurance 
from  a  number  of  directions  at  once.  The  centerpiece  of  the  pro- 
posal is  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  which  this 
committee  is  now  considering.  And  the  core  purpose  of  that  legisla- 
tion is  to  resolve  this  conflict  between  crop  insurance  and  ad  hoc 
disaster  aid. 

The  way  we  propose  to  do  it  is  to  combine  the  two,  insurance  and 
disaster  aid,  into  one,  single,  unified  on-budget  program. 

To  do  that  requires  two  steps.  On  the  one  hand,  we  have  to  cut 
off  or  drastically  reduce  the  possibility  of  passing  ad  hoc  disaster 
bills  in  the  future.  We  propose  to  do  that  by  amending  the  Budget 
Enforcement  Act  to  make  future  crop  disaster  spending  on-budget, 
to  take  away  its  emergency  designation.  In  other  words,  in  the  fu- 
ture, a  crop  disaster  bill  would  have  to  be  paid  for  with  offsetting 
cuts. 

We  feel  this  is  a  very  significant,  very  serious  parliamentary  hur- 
dle against  these  types  of  bills  in  the  future. 

The  second  step  is  to  protect  farmers  in  the  absence  of  ad  hoc 
disaster  bills.  We  propose  to  do  that  by  expanding  the  crop  insur- 
ance program.  What  we  would  do  is  to  take  the  program  somewhat 
as  currently  structured  with  a  number  of  reforms  and  expand  it  by 
creating  a  new  level  of  catastrophic  coverage  that  would  be  made 
available  to  all  farmers  of  insurable  crops  for  a  processing  fee.  The 
Government  would  pay  the  premium  for  this  low-level  coverage, 
something  like  a  rainy  day  fund  to  protect  against  a  catastrophe, 
and  the  farmer  would  pay  a  processing  fee  of  $50  per  crop  per 
county  with  a  cap  of  $100  per  county. 

The  t5T)e  of  coverage  that  this  would  provide  would  be  50  percent 
of  individual  yield  at  60  percent  of  price.  We  chose  those  levels  in 
order  to  provide  a  payment  similar  to  what  farmers  would  have 
gotten  under  disaster  bills  over  the  past  several  years.  We  under- 
stand that  this  comparison  is  not  exact;  the  formulas  are  a  little 
different.  In  many  cases,  what  they  would  get  under  50/60  cata- 
strophic is  a  little  bit  less  than  they  would  have  gotten  under  dis- 
aster bills  at  100  percent  proration;  but  again,  who  knows  whether 
next  year  there  will  be  a  disaster  bill  at  100  percent  proration? 

I  direct  the  attention  of  the  members  of  the  subcommittee  to  a 
number  of  charts  toward  the  end  of  the  testimony  setting  out  spe- 
cifically how  50/60  coverage  would  compare  to  disaster  bills  over 
the  past  couple  of  years.  The  one  key  difference,  however,  is,  cata- 
strophic coverage  is  an  insurance  policy;  it  is  not  ad  hoc.  It  is  some- 
thing certain.  It  is  a  financial  asset  that  a  farmer  would  have  at 
the  beginning  of  the  year.  They  can  use  it  as  collateral  on  a  loan 
from  a  bank.  Moreover,  even  if  no  other  farmer  in  the  country  suf- 
fers a  loss,  they  are  guaranteed  protection. 


11 

In  order  to  make  sure  that  the  largest  number  of  farmers  in  fact 
get  their  hands  on  this  coverage,  we  are  proposing  to  link  it  to  par- 
ticipation in  farm  programs  and  Farmers  Home  Administration 
loans.  In  other  words,  to  get  a  deficiency  pa5rtnent  or  to  get  a  Farm- 
ers Home  loan,  a  farmer  would  have  to  acquire  catastrophic  cov- 
erage or  more. 

Our  projection  is  that  this  would  result  in  participation  increas- 
ing from  approximately  33  percent  to  about  80  percent,  as  the 
aquamarine  colored  chart  will  show  you.  The  1993  level  shows  you 
our  current  participation  of  about  33  percent.  The  total  bar  shows 
you  what  we  project  to  be  the  full  participation  in  the  program 
based  on  linkage.  The  dark  blue  bar  on  the  bottom  shows  what  we 
expect  to  have  slowly,  over  time,  an  increase  in  buy-up  coverage  at 
higher  levels. 

Third,  in  order  to  encourage  farmers  to  get  higher  levels  of  cov- 
erage, we  are  proposing  to  sweeten  the  pot  at  the  higher  levels. 
The  reform  bill  will  provide  targeted  incentives  so  that  a  farmer 
purchasing  coverage  at  a  65  or  75  percent  yield  level  would  get  an 
out-of-pocket  discount  of  about  10  to  15  percent. 

In  order  to  make  delivery  more  convenient  for  farmers,  given  the 
fact  that  we  are  looking  at  a  linked  program,  we  are  proposing  a 
change  in  our  delivery  system.  Currently,  as  you  know,  crop  insur- 
ance is  delivered  through  private  agents  representing  private  com- 
panies which  are  reinsured  by  the  Federal  Government.  We  are 
proposing  that  the  system  in  place  to  deliver  buy-up  coverage  to  re- 
main the  same.  We  think  it  has  worked  well;  we  think  the  private 
sector  has  done  a  good  job. 

However,  for  catastrophic  coverage,  because  of  the  very  serious 
workload  implications,  particularly  in  the  early  years,  we  are  pro- 
posing that  a  farmer  would  have  a  choice.  They  can  either  pur- 
chase it  through  a  private  agent  or  through  a  local  office  of  USD  A. 

Finsdly,  for  those  crops  that  are  not  covered  at  all  under  crop  in- 
surance, we  are  proposing  to  provide  a  standing  disaster  program 
structured  very  much  like  disaster  programs  are  structured  today. 
We  did  not  want  to  expand  crop  insurance  into  those  areas  where 
we  are  not  ready.  We  want  to  keep  the  program  actuarially  sound, 
and  so  for  those  crops  that  are  not  currently  covered,  we  are  pro- 
viding a  standing  disaster  program  with  an  area  trigger. 

Again,  just  for  clarity,  in  our  testimony  you  will  notice  that  we 
have  included  a  list  of  all  of  the  crops  that  are  currently  covered 
under  crop  insurance.  There  are  about  50  of  them,  and  they  cover 
two  pages.  We  have  also  included  a  list  of  crops  that  are  currently 
in  the  pipeline  to  be  added  to  crop  insurance  over  the  next  2  to  4 
years.  The  crops  on  these  lists  that  are  covered  by  crop  insurance, 
would  be  under  the  catastrophic  coverage  system.  Those  that  are 
not  on  the  list — that  are  not  covered  by  crop  insurance,  would  be 
covered  by  the  standing  disaster  program.  We  do  not  want  to  leave 
any  crop  totally  out  in  the  cold. 

The  price  tag  for  this  program  is  summarized  by  the  next  chart. 
Basically  what  we  are  looking  at  is  this:  The  cost  of  adding  cata- 
strophic coverage,  plus  incentives  for  buy-ups,  plus  providing  the 
standing  disaster  program  will  add  about  $1  billion  a  year  to  the 
cost  of  crop  insurance. 


12 

What  we  are  trying  to  do  conceptually  is  basically  to  rechannel 
the  money  that  the  Federal  Grovernment  has  been  pa3dng  for  ad 
hoc  disaster  relief  over  the  past  10  years  and  rechannel  it  into  a 
crop  insurance  program.  We  feel  that  this  is  a  better  deal  for  farm- 
ers because  they  get  certainty;  and  we  feel  that  it  is  a  better  deal 
for  taxpayers  because  they  know  in  advance  what  their  exposure 
is. 

That  is  the  sum  of  our  legislative  proposal. 

I  want  to  take  a  brief  moment,  if  I  may,  just  to  mention  the  other 
two  parts  of  our  reform  program  for  crop  insursince,  because  I  think 
when  you  look  at  the  legislation,  it  needs  to  be  looked  at  in  context. 

The  second  major  element  is  the  Blueprint  for  Financial  Sound- 
ness, which  is  the  document  that  is  an  attachment  to  my  prepared 
statement. 

As  Chairman  Johnson  mentioned  earlier,  one  of  the  chief  criti- 
cisms of  crop  insurance  over  the  years  is  that  it  chronically  loses 
money. 

Our  average  loss  ratio  over  the  past — since  1981  has  been  $1.47. 
That  means  that  we  pay  out  $1.47  in  claims  for  every  $1  we  take 
in  in  premiums,  not  counting  overhead  costs.  Any  private  business 
that  ran  numbers  like  that  would  have  gone  bankrupt  years  ago. 
It  is  simply  not  an  acceptable  way  to  do  business.  Our  feeling  is 
that  American  taxpayers  will  not  tolerate  it. 

The  reconciliation  bill  passed  by  Congress  and  signed  by  the 
President  last  year  requires  us  to  improve  that  loss  ratio  to  1.1  by 
the  fiscal  year  beginning  October  1995.  We  are  committed  to  reach 
that  goal.  The  blueprint  document  spells  out  the  steps  that  we  are 
taking  to  get  there. 

It  includes  items  like  our  actual  production  history  records  pro- 
gram, our  nonstandard  classification  system  designed  to  isolate  and 
Wentify  high-risk  farmers  in  high-risk  areas  and  adjust  their  rates, 
increased  emphasis  on  compliance,  and  our  new  participant  track- 
ing system. 

The  third  major  element  is  an  attempt  by  USDA  and  FCIC  to 
make  this  program  more  flexible,  more  responsive  to  farmer  needs. 
We  hope  to  do  that  through  a  number  of  steps,  including  more  in- 
novative products,  more  flexibility  on  items  like  units,  price  selec- 
tions and  crop-specific  issues  that  have  come  up,  and  also  to  de- 
velop a  better  attitude  toward  listening  to  farmers  and  listening  to 
agents,  listening  to  companies,  listening  to  the  people  who  are  in- 
volved in  this  program. 

On  this  note,  I  would  mention  that  in  putting  this  program  to- 
gether, we  spent  a  lot  of  time  talking  to  farmers.  We  held  meetings 
with  farmers  across  the  country.  Mr.  Minge  mentioned  my  day  in 
Minnesota  with  the  subfreezing  temperatures.  I  would  only  men- 
tion that  I  personally  am  from  Albany,  New  York,  and  grew  up  in 
heavy  winter  weather.  Every  winter  in  Washington  for  a  few  days 
in  December  I  started  to  feel  nostalgic  for  it. 

I  thank  Congressman  Minge  for  an  opportunity  to  get  that  out 
of  my  system  early  in  the  year. 

So  with  that,  I  thank  the  committee  for  holding  this  hearing;  and 
we  would  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions  you  may  have. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Moos  and  Mr.  Ackerman  appears 
at  the  conclusion  of  the  hearing.] 


13 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Moos  and  Mr.  Ackerman. 

The  chairman  will  try  to  enforce  a  5-minute  rule  on  members' 
questions.  We  c£in  come  around  as  many  times  as  it  requires,  but 
that  will,  I  think,  allow  everyone  a  more  orderly  way  of  asking 
their  questions. 

One  of  the  concerns  that  all  of  us  have  is  whether  there  will  be 
a  sufficient  buy-up  above  the  catastrophic  coverage.  If  that  does  not 
occur,  it  will  jeopardize  the  viability  of  this  entire  strategy,  and 
there  will  be  tremendous  pressure  to  once  again  augment  crop  in- 
surance benefits  with  some  kind  of  catastrophic — or  some  kind  of 
ad  hoc  pajonent.  It  is  going  to  be  very  important  that  people  under- 
st£ind  the  need  for  more  than  catastrophic  coverage. 

I  wonder  if  you  would  comment  on  that,  about  whether  cata- 
strophic coverage  is  in  fact  adequate,  and  how  you  envision  promot- 
ing better  coverage  than  that,  and  for  people  to  buy  better  coverage 
than  that. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  think  that  is  a  very  important 
question.  Catastrophic  coverage,  the  way  we  envision  it,  is  basically 
a  replacement  for  a  disaster  payment.  It  is  a  way  of  replacing  the 
disaster  programs  by  providing  farmers  with  a  base  coverage.  But 
you  are  correct  that  for  farmers  to  run  their  operations  in  a  busi- 
nesslike way,  in  most  cases  they  would  require  a  higher  level  of 
coverage.  And  the  more  farmers  that  have  higher  levels  of  cov- 
erage, the  more  sound  the  system  is  going  to  be.  Also,  the  farmers 
who  buy  higher  levels  of  coverage,  will  be  in  a  position  to  with- 
stand a  real  disaster  with  some  meaningful  financial  stability. 

When  we  designed  this  program,  we  thought  one  of  the  most  im- 
portant elements  was  the  financial  incentives  for  buy-ups.  We  spe- 
cifically did  not  want  to  have  a  program  where  there  would  be  in- 
centives for  farmers  to  buy  down  rather  than  to  buy  up.  That  was 
why  we  did  not  want  to  sweeten  the  pot  too  much  at  the  cata- 
strophic level.  We  thought  50-60  was  enough  to  replace  a  disaster 
program,  but  it  was  not  so  much  that  it  would  entice  farmers  to 
get  lower  levels  of  coverage  rather  than  higher  levels  of  coverage. 

In  order  to  get  farmers  to  buy  up,  we  think  that  a  number  of 
things  have  to  happen.  First  of  all,  we  feel  that  the  subsidies  at  the 
higher  levels  are  essential.  As  we  have  noted  in  the  testimony,  this 
will  result  in  an  out-of-pocket  discount  for  farmers  of  about  10  to 
15  percent. 

We  also  think  that  the  private  sector  is  going  to  have  to  work 
very  hard  to  convince  farmers  to  buy  up.  A  good  deal  of  public  edu- 
cation is  going  to  be  required  to  make  this  program  work  well. 

We  are  also  going  to  have  to  do  a  good  bit  of  training  for  the 
USDA  county  offices,  so  that  when  farmers  come  in  to  use  those 
offices  to  get  catastrophic  coverage,  they  are  sensitized  to  the  need 
for  higher  levels. 

Mr.  Johnson.  One  of  the  most  controversial  aspects  of  any  farm 
policy  decision  we  make  is  that  whenever  we  tie  it  to  participation 
in  farm  programs  and  give  it  a  mandatory  nature — I  think  all  of 
us  have  an  initial  reaction  against  mandatory  programs,  although 
in  this  case  it  is  one  where  it  may  be  msmdatory;  but  it  is  one  of 
the  best  buys  imaginable,  $50  for  a  crop  coverage.  Still,  that  is  a 
sore  point  with  some  people. 


14 

I  wonder  if  you  would  comment  about  some  who  have  suggested 
that  maybe  there  ought  to  be  a  waiver  outlet  that  in  effect  a  farmer 
would  have  a  choice  if  he  so  chose  to  release  himself  from  buying 
that  catastrophic  coverage,  so  long  as  he  very  explicitly  waives  not 
only  the  crop  insurance,  but  the  ability  to  participate  in  any  kind 
of  crop  disaster  program. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  feel  the  linkage  provision  is  very  important, 
and  we  would  have  a  serious  concern  about  the  waiver  proposal. 
The  basic  reason  is  this:  Obviously,  we  understand  that  farmers, 
like  anyone  else,  do  not  like  mandates;  people  don't  like  being  told 
what  to  do.  Our  main  concern  is  that  we  don't  want  to  have  a  situ- 
ation 2  or  3  years  down  the  road  where  we  have  gone  through  the 
trouble  and  the  expense  of  reforming  crop  insurance,  such  as  put- 
ting in  place  these  parliamentary  hurdles  against  future  disaster 
bills,  and  a  crisis  strikes — a  flood  or  a  drought  or  whatever — and 
it  turns  out  that  a  large  number  of  farmers,  for  whatever  reason, 
simply  have  not  acquired  the  coverage,  either  because  they  were 
skeptical  of  a  new  Government  program,  or  because  the  word 
hadn't  gotten  out  well  enough,  or  because  of  simple  inertia — ^for 
whatever  reason. 

If  you  have  a  large  number  of  farmers  who  have  not  acquired  the 
coverage,  then  that  creates  two  problems.  For  one  thing,  those 
farmers  are  unprotected,  and  for  another,  that  could  create  the 
very  kind  of  political  pressure  for  this  new  program  to  unravel. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  gentleman  from  Texas,  Mr.  Combest. 

Mr.  Combest.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Ackerman,  I  have  to  get  this  down  to  where  I  can  under- 
stand this.  Say  I  have  three  farms  in  one  county.  On  farm  A,  I 
have  500  acres  of  cotton  and  500  acres  of  grain.  On  farm  E,  I  have 
500  acres  of  cotton;  and  on  farm  C,  I  have  500  acres  of  grain.  When 
I  go  in  to  sign  up  at  the  ASCS  office,  how  do  they  determine  how 
much  I  owe  for  the  catastrophic  coverage?  Is  it  per  farm  or  per 
crop? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  It  is  per  producer,  per  crop,  per  county. 

Mr.  Combest.  I  am  the  sole  producer. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  If  you  are  the  sole  producer  and  all  of  these 
farms  are  in  one  county? 

Mr.  Combest.  They  are. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Then  you  would  pay  $100. 

Mr.  Combest.  So  $50  for  the  cotton  and  $50  for  the  grain? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  That  is  correct. 

Mr.  Combest.  So  I  would  have  1,000  acres  of  grain  and  1,000 
acres  of  cotton,  even  though  the  farms  are  separate — it  is  totally 
separate  entities  as  far  as  ASCS  records — I  would  only  pay  for,  per 
crop? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  You  would  pay  per  crop,  correct. 

Mr.  Combest.  Within  the  county? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Yes. 

Mr.  Combest.  If  I  only  farmed  100  acres  of  cotton  in  the  entire 
county,  it  would  also  be  $50? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  That  is  correct. 

Mr.  Combest.  Let  me  back  up. 

On  those  farms,  I  am  a  sole  producer  and  I  have  that  question 
answered,  so  it  is  per  crop. 


15 

If  I  am  farming  within  a  county  and  I  am  a  tenant  farmer,  obvi- 
ously the  amount  coming  to — or  through  ASCS  to  Federal  crop  in- 
surance for  my  catastrophic  premium  would  be  the  same.  Would  it 
split  at  the  ASCS  office  where  I  would  pay  my  percentage  and  the 
owner  of  the  land  would  pay  their  percentage,  based  upon  our 
farming  agreement? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  must  tell  you  that  on  some  of  these  points,  that 
level  of  detail  of  how  it  would  be  divided  between 

Mr.  COMBEST.  That  is  very  understandable. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  The  one  clarification  I  would  make,  though,  is 
that  the  $50  or  $100  is  not  premium. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  Sure.  The  terminology  is  important;  I  was  just 
calling  it  that. 

In  a  situation,  in  your  testimony,  the  next-to-the-last  page;  if  it 
doesn't  surprise  you,  I  have  turned  to  the  cotton  page.  In  the  exam- 
ple on  either  one,  actually  it  wouldn't  matter  whether  it  is  example 
one  or  example  two  in  the  amount;  let's  take  example  one,  so  we 
will  be  talking  about  the  same  one. 

The  catastrophic  protection,  per  acre,  on  a  loss  would  pay  that 
farmer  $64.55  an  acre? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Correct. 

Mr.  CoMBEST.  Tell  me  exactly  how  the  price  is  determined  to 
where  you  are  arriving  at  60  percent  of  the  price.  How  exactly  is 
that  price  determined? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  The  60  percent  price  is  based  on  the  projected 
market  price  that  is  picked  by  FCIC  at  the  beginning  of  the  grow- 
ing season,  based  on  projections  by  the  World  Agricultural  Outlook 
Board. 

Mr.  CoMBEST.  And  that  is  the  same  way  it  is  done  today? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  That  is  correct. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  In  this  example,  so  I  don't  have  to  figure  back- 
wards, would  that  be  the  53  cents  a  pound  in  both  of  those  exam- 
ples? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  The  deficiency  pa3rment  obviously  would  have  still 
been  made  in  that  example? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes. 

Crop  insurance  does  not  have  an  offset  with  deficiency  payments 
like  disasters. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  I  often  think  it  was  probably  crop  insurance  that 
caused  our  former  chairman  to  leave  the  Congress  and  go  to  an- 
other job.  Hopefully,  that  won't  happen  to  Mr.  Johnson. 

This  subcommittee  itself  has  been  dealing  with  this  thing  for 
years  and  years.  I  will  say  I  will  have  to — ^Mr.  Penny  left,  but  I  will 
have  to  agree  with  him  on  a  portion  of  what  he  said  in  his  non- 
partisan effort.  We  have  been  trying  in  this  subcommittee  for  years 
to  come  up  with  the  magic  word,  adequate  crop  insurance  program, 
to  replace  disaster.  And  I  think  that  the  message  has  got  to  be — 
I  will  just  finish  this  comment,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  then  come  back 
later. 

The  message  has  to  be  sent,  we  have  to  deliver  the  message;  and 
you  said  what  we  have  to  do  is  get  the  word  out;  that  so  many 
farmers  anticipate  because  it  has  happened  so  regularly,  that  there 


16 

is  going  to  be  a  disaster  program,  many  of  them  decide  not  to  play 
in  the  program.  And  we  have  to  try  to  get  that  message  out. 

Our  biggest  problem  has  always  been  getting — having  the  oppor- 
tunity to  have  credit  for  how  much  was  being  expended  on  disas- 
ters and  being  able  to  put  that  into  the  crop  insurance  program 
and  come  up  with  a  chart  like  you  did  where  you  are  going  to  save 
$750  million;  we  could  never  get  credit  for  that. 

And  as  you  and  I  discussed  in  the  office — in  my  office,  I  think 
the  biggest  difficulty  may  potentially  be  that;  but  if  we  can  over- 
come that  hurdle,  I  feel  very  comfortable  that  we  can  come  up  with 
an  adequate  crop  insurance  program  that  will  be  very  attractive  to 
farmers  and  hopefully  will  even  exceed  your  anticipated  participa- 
tion proposal  and  have  a  lot  of  farmers  participate  in  that  program, 
particularly  if  we  can  tie  that  together  with  the  fact  that  there 
probably  is  not  going  to  be  a  disaster  payment,  or  that  we  would 
work  very  hard  against  it. 

I  have  several  other  things  I  would  like  to  talk  about,  Mr.  Chair- 
man, I  will  come  back  the  next  time. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Minge. 

Mr.  Minge.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  understand  that  we  are  going  to  have  pajntnents  under  the  50/ 
60  formula  under  this  program  and,  of  course,  there  will  simply  be 
a  sign  up  fee  for  the  payments  that  go  out. 

"NAHiat  I  am  wondering  is  if  you  have  any  projections  as  to  the 
amount  of  money  that  would  be  paid  out  under  this  base  level  or 
catastrophic  level  of  coverage  of  Federal  crop  insurance  as  proposed 
compared  to  the  money  that  would  be  paid  out  as  farmers  insured 
at  the  higher  levels? 

I  am  particularly  interested  in  this  because  what  I  see  is  that 
there  are  certain  sections  of  the  country  where  there  is,  say,  a  hur- 
ricane or  some  other  catastrophic  event  that  results  in  almost  total 
destruction,  and  other  parts  of  the  country  it  is  once  in  100  years 
or  something  that  we  have  a  level  of  crop  loss  that  will  exceed  50 
percent,  and  I  think  there  is  a  certain  regional  issue  that  is  at 
work  here,  and  it  would  be  important  to  have  that  on  the  table  so 
that  as  this  moves  through  Congress,  if  there  is  any  debate,  that 
can  be  taken  into  account  and  we  don't  have  people  coming  up  later 
and  complaining  that  this  was  not  adequately  addressed. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Two  points.  First  of  all,  on  the  question  of  actual 
projections,  yes,  we  have  those  numbers  and  I  can  supply  those  to 
you.  I  have  them  here. 

Generally,  what  we  have  looked  at,  what  we  have  broken  down 
is  how  much  of  the  total  budget,  how  much  of  our  indemnities  we 
expect  will  be  paid  out  under  catastrophic  versus  under  buy-ups. 
As  a  general  matter,  just  based  on  this  chart  showing  the  relative 
number  of  farmers  with  buy-up  versus  catastrophic,  we  would  ex- 
pect over  time  that  more  would  be  paid  out  through  buy-up  rather 
than  catastrophic.  So  we  will  provide  you  the  specific  numbers  for 
the  record,  but  generally  that  is  the  direction  that  they  move. 

[The  information  follows:] 


17 


Crop  Insurance  Reform:  Estimated  Indemnities  by  Fiscal  Year, 
by  Coverage  Level,  Fiscal  Years  1995-1999 


1995 

1996 

1997             1998 
Millions  of  Dollars 

1999 

95-99 

Catastrophic  (50/60) 

351 

392 

378              369 

363 

1.853 

Buy-up  Coverage 

1.131 

1,284 

1.485           1.681 

1,874 

7.456 

Total 

1.482 

1.677 

1,863           2.049 

2.238 

9.309 

Crop  Insurance  Rerorm:  Number  of  Participants  by  Fiscal  Year 
by  Coverage  Level,  Fiscal  Years  1995-1999 

1995  1996  1997  1998  1999, 

Thousands  of  Partidpants 
Catastrophic  (50/60)  357  325  299  278  261 

Buy-up  Coverage  312  353  387  416  441 

Total  669  678  686  694  702 

Note:  Participant  count  is  based  on  assumption  that  average  farmer  has  2.5  crops. 


18 

Mr.  MiNGE,  Do  those  numbers  reflect  the  different  type  of  crops, 
different  regions,  where  this  level  of  disaster  assistance  would  be 
important  as  compared  to  other  regions? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  The  numbers  we  put  together  thus  far  just  sim- 
ply on  a  nationwide  level  breakdown  the  amount  that  would  go  out 
catastrophic  versus  the  amount  that  would  go  out  through  buy-up. 
We  have  not  done  a  projection — it  would  be  a  very  hard  one  to  do — 
about  how  many  farmers  in  different  parts  of  the  country  would 
purchase  buy-up  versus  those  who  would  not. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  am  not  talking  about  purchasing  it.  What  I  mean 
is,  if  the  base  level  as  a  requirement  for  participation  in  Federal 
farm  programs  of  any  type  will  have  this  high  level,  hopefully  80, 
90  percent  participation,  and  if  there  is  something  that  shows  ei- 
ther by  crop  or  by  State  what  you  feel  the  level  of  pay  out  would 
be  under  the  base  of  the  catastrophic  level,  that  is  the  type  of 
breakdown  I  am  looking  for,  not  farmer  by  farmer. 

Mr.  AcKERMAN.  We  could  try  to  put  something  together  like  that, 
yes. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  think  it  would  be  important  in  terms  of  fairness  as 
this  moves  along  to  address  that. 

Second,  there  have  been  a  number  of  objections  that  have  oc- 
curred over  the  last  year  to  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program  be- 
cause those  farmers  who  have  livestock  operations  and  feed  their 
crop  can  have  an  effective  farm  program  without  participating  in 
any  of  the  commodity  programs,  and  they  feel  that  the  price  elec- 
tion that  is  available  to  them  is  not  really  adequate,  and  what  they 
have  ended  up  with  is  with  a  program  crop  like  com,  they  do  not 
have  the  target  price,  that  is,  the  price  that  is  used  for  the  calcula- 
tions but  instead  a  price  which  is  substantially  lower,  and  going  be- 
yond that,  they  find  that  there  are  other  penalties  that  they  feel 
are  built  into  the  system. 

Does  the  proposal  that  you  have  presented  address  the  inequities 
that  those  farmers  that  feed  their  crop  face  as  compared  to  those 
that  simply  are  doing  cash  cropping? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Not  directly.  We  understand  that  there  are  two 
particular  problems  that  farmers  who  feed  their  crops  face  that 
need  to  be  addressed.  One  is  the  question  of  how  they  would  fit 
within  the  APH  program,  because  in  many  cases,  farmers  who  feed 
their  crops  don't  have  sales  records  on  which  to  base  their  actual 
production  history  yield,  and  that  is  something  that  we  are  going 
to  have  to  work  with  in  the  APH  program  to  correct.  There  are 
ways  that  we  can  develop  for  them  to  get  an  accurate  jdeld  other 
than  the  records  used  by  farmers  who  sell  their  crops,  and  that  is 
something  that  we  are  going  to  have  to  correct. 

On  the  question  of  the  price  election,  that  is  an  area  which  is 
problematic  throughout  our  program  and  which  became  very  ap- 
parent this  year.  As  mentioned  this  year,  in  response  to  Mr.  Com- 
best  on  cotton,  we  pick  a  price  election  at  the  beginning  of  the 
growing  season  and  hold  it  throughout  the  year.  That  is  the  way 
our  program  works. 

This  year  it  became  very  clear  that  that  was  not  an  adequate 
way  to  run  our  program.  We  had  situations,  for  instance,  with  the 
price  of  wheat  where  we  picked  a  price  last  summer  of  $2.80,  which 
was  based  on  the  projections  of  the  World  Outlook  Board  at  that 


19 

time.  However,  given  the  drought — ^the  flood  over  the  summer  and 
the  run-ups  in  the  markets  in  the  fall,  that  price  became  out  of 
date. 

We  have  had  a  similar  situation  with  com  prices  going  up  very 
sharply.  This  is  a  problem  that  we  are  going  to  have  to  address 
programwide.  So  far  we  have  taken  an  initial  step  by  approving  a 
private  sector  wraparound  policy  that  would  provide  replacement 
cost  coverage,  and  there  are  one  or  two  others  like  that  in  the  pipe- 
line. In  the  legislative  proposal  we  have  put  before  you,  it  contains 
statutory  language  to  allow  us  to  fix  that  and  provide  an  actual 
market  price  on  a  more  systematic  basis. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Ewing. 

Mr.  Ewing.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  I  think  that  the  adminis- 
tration's plan  to  put  more  money  in  this  program  certainly  eases 
our  ability  to  come  up  with  a  better  plan.  That  was  one  of  the  prob- 
lems I  was  having,  trjdng  to  make  a  better  plan  with  no  more 
money.  The  money  that  we  are  talking  about  here,  basically  is  that 
the  disaster  money  that  was  for  crops  or  was  that  disaster  money 
for  roads  and  houses  and  everything  else? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  It  is  solely  the  disaster  money  for  crops.  It  does 
not  include  the  other  disaster  money. 

Mr.  EwiNG.  Very  good.  What  would  happen  if  there  is  a  re- 
quest— and  I  will  just  use  the  amount  $1  billion,  by  the  administra- 
tion for  the  program  and  yet  we  appropriate — ^the  Congress  decides 
to  appropriate  less  than  that  amount?  What  happens  if  we  have 
claims?  Will  they  be  prorated? 

Mr.  AcKERMAN.  No,  they  would  not.  Under  the  appropriations 
rules  governing  this  program,  the  money  for  indeuMiities  comes  out 
of  a  FCIC  revolving  fund  which  is  paid  out  of  an  annual  mandatory 
appropriation.  So,  no,  that  would  not  occur.  You  would  not  cut  off 
payments  to  farmers  because  we  reached  any  kind  of  spending  cap. 

Mr.  Ewing.  Very  good.  I  think  that  is  an  important  point  to 
make. 

I  think  I  understand  that  the  signup  fee  is  an  administrative- 
type  charge  not  allocated  to  the  size  of  the  operation. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Correct. 

Mr.  Ewing.  Why  would  you  do  that  as  compared  to  having  even 
a  floating  signup  fee  for  big  farmers  who  really  are  getting  a  50 
percent  coverage,  maybe  only  by  pa5dng  the  administrative  fee? 
Why  wouldn't  big  operators  pay  a  little  more  for  that  sign  up? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Well,  under  the  proposal,  some  big  operators 
would  pay  a  little  more  if  they  were  in  more  than  one  county  be- 
cause the  cap  is  $100  per  county.  But  as  a  general  matter,  what 
we  were  trying  to  do  here  was  to  provide  a  form  of  insurance  that 
replaces  disaster  payments.  As  you  know,  you  can  get  disaster  pay- 
ments without  a  signup  fee  no  matter  how  big  your  farm  is.  It  does 
not  have  a  signup  fee  that  varies  by  acreage,  so  to  the  extent  that 
there  may  be  an  implied  inequity  here,  it  is  carried  over. 

But  we  were  trying  to  keep  a  differentiation  between  the  pre- 
mium which  the  Government  would  pay  and  a  processing  fee  which 
the  farmer  would  pay,  and  generally  the  cost  of  processing  is  based 
on  the  number  of  units  or  based  on  the  number  of  farms,  and  that 
$50  is  designed  to  cover  simply  the  cost  of  processing  the  paper.  We 


20 

do  not  want  to  start  getting  into  the  complexity  of  formulas  based 
on  the  size  of  farms  because  then  it  would  really  look  like  you  are 
pajdng  a  premium,  which  you  would  not  be. 

Mr.  EwiNG.  One  final  question.  When  you  talked  about  crops 
that  weren't  covered  and  that  they  would  be  covered  under  the 
standing  disaster  program,  do  we  have  a  standing  disaster  program 
that  would  apply  for  noncovered  crops? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes.  It  is  part  of  the  legislative  package  to  create 
it  and  it  is  modeled  after  the  current  program  with  a  number  of 
adjustments. 

Mr.  EwiNG.  So  we  don't  now  have  such  a  program?  It  would  be 
part  of  this  program  to  create  a  new  one? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  That  is  right. 

Mr,  EwiNG.  Thank  you  very  much. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  This  question  may  be 
a  little  off  the  wall,  but  in  the  last  year,  I  think  it  was  in  some 
bill  last  year,  we  got  this  pilot  project  put  in  that  we  were  going 
to  have  a  look  at  revenue-tj^je  insurance  in  Minnesota,  North  Da- 
kota, and  Mississippi,  or  do  either  one  of  you  remember  that? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  It  was  report  language  that  was  put  into  the  rec- 
onciliation bill,  yes. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Is  that  now  out  the  window  or  are  you  going 
to 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  No,  it  is  in  the  works.  What  we  have  done  on 
that  particular  language  is  that  we  have  asked  the  Economic  Re- 
search Service  to  do  a  study  on  what  is  involved  in  it,  and  there 
are  a  number  of  hurdles  to  doing  it  that  are  going  to  have  to  be 
worked  through.  The  idea  would  be  to  base  the  insurance  on  the 
cost  of  production  rather  than  the  value  of  the  crop,  which  is  a  new 
idea. 

There  are  a  number  of  concerns  about  how  you  get  the  right  ac- 
tuarial data  to  know  how  to  price  it.  There  are  some  concerns  of 
what  you  do  in  those  situations  where  the  cost  of  production  is,  in 
fact,  greater  than  the  value  of  the  crop  and  how  to  design  it,  but 
that  is  underway. 

Mr.  Peterson.  When  is  that  going  to  be  completed? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  I  don't  know  the  exact  due  date  from  ERS.  I 
know  we  had  an  initisd  report  from  them  where  we  have  been  re- 
viewing it.  Probably,  we  would  be  looking  for  something  for  1995, 
some  type  of  pilot. 

Mr.  Peterson.  So  this  hasn't  set  that  aside,  then? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  No. 

Mr.  Peterson.  I  haven't  had  time  to  read  your  whole  proposal 
on  that.  I  am  not  sure  if  I  understand  it  yet,  but  one  of  the  issues 
that  keeps  coming  up  is  who  is  going  to  decide  the  yields  out  there. 
Has  that  been  resolved?  Are  you  going  to  have  ASCS  or  the  Fed- 
eral crop,  one  or  the  other  do  it  or  are  we  going  to  have  a  system 
where  they  both  are  involved?  Is  that  addressed? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Under  this  system,  the  yields  would  be  based  on 
the  FCIC  rules,  and  they  would  be  actual  production  history  yields 
rather  than  the  ASCS  program  yields. 

Mr.  Peterson.  So  the  SCS  is  taken  out  of  it,  then? 


21 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  The  ASCS  would  be  an  implementer  in  that  the 
farmer  could  go  to  the  ASCS  or  a  farm  service  agency  to  get  the 
work  done  if  they  choose  to  do  so,  but  the  rules  that  would  be  fol- 
lowed in  determining  the  yields  would  be  the  FCIC  actual  produc- 
tion history  record  rules. 

Mr.  Peterson.  And  if  they  don't  have  those  history — I  was  read- 
ing this.  I  probably  don't  want  to  go  into  that  right  now  but  I  guess 
I  will  have  to  take  some  more  time  to  look  at  it  and  try  to  see  if 
I  can — maybe  what  I  am  going  to  have  to  do  is  go  down  to  the 
ASCS  and  try  to  sign  out  and  see  how  this  works.  In  the  abstract, 
it  is  pretty  hard  to  figure  out,  so 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  could  just  tell  you  that,  very  briefly,  you  are 
required  to  have  4  years  of  records,  building  to  10.  If  you  don't 
have  those  4  years,  you  are  given  a  program  yield  but  at  a  dis- 
count. 

Mr.  Peterson.  This  whole  idea  of  getting  to  a  1.1  to  1  ratio.  I 
guess  I  don't  understand  how  these  actuarial  computations  are 
made  and  maybe  I  need  to  sit  down  with  somebody,  but  it  is  un- 
clear to  me  how  all  that  works.  It  has  always  been  a  mystery.  Can 
you  explain  that  in  1  minute  or  less? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  I  can  try.  This  one  is  a  mystery  for  a  good  rea- 
son. It  is  not  a  straightforward  situation.  These  actuarial  numbers, 
1.1  or  1.4,  are  designed  to  be  averages  over  time.  A  1.1  loss  ratio 
means  you  are  paying  out  $1.10  for  each  $1  you  are  taking  in  in 
premiums.  We  are  trying  to  get  down  to  1.1.  What  that  means  is 
over  a  period  of  years,  the  program  should  be  designed  to  produce 
that  as  an  average. 

We  would  expect,  for  instance,  in  a  year  like  1993  with  a  major 
flood  and  a  major  drought,  our  loss  ratio  would  be  2.16  and  that 
is  acceptable. 

Mr.  Peterson.  But  if  you  get  to  this  level,  aren't  you,  in  effect, 
going  to  raise  the  premiums  to  make  this  happen? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Yes.  In  order  to  get  there,  we  are  having  to  take 
a  number  of  steps.  We  are  trying  not  to  do  all  of  it  by  raising  pre- 
miums, but  that  is  one  of  the  steps  we  are  taking.  IVemiums  will 
be  raised  in  various 

Mr.  Peterson.  Is  that  going  to  make  it  harder  to  get  the  people 
to  buy  this  insurance?  I  guess  that  is  my  concern.  Do  we  know 
what  the  effect  of  this  is  going  to  be?  Have  you  got  a  model  that 
you  can  say  with  certainty  just  exactly  what  the  outcome  of  this 
is  going  to  be? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  We  can  never  say  with  exact  certainty  what  the 
effect  will  be.  There  are  some  concerns  that  over  the  past  few  years 
we  have  been  raising  rates  and  there  has  been  some  movement  of 
farmers  from  the  75  percent  protection  level  down  to  65  percent. 
We  are  trying  to  raise  rates  moderately  and  not  do  it  too  quickly. 
We  don't  want  to  lose  our  good  customers.  We  are  also  trying  to 
get  to  that  1.1  loss  ratio  by  taking  a  number  of  other  steps,  such 
as  the  actual  records  and  tracking  systems  and  trying  to  isolate  the 
highest  risk  farmers,  the  farmers  with  disproportionate  losses  and 
then  adjusting  their  rates  first.  It  is  one  of  those  unavoidable  steps 
we  have  to  take. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  have  to  go  to  another  meeting. 
Could  I  just  ask  one  related  to  this? 


22 

Mr.  Johnson.  Proceed,  without  objection. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Mr.  Durbin's  idea  about  knocking  out  people  who 
are  in  an  area  where  they  have  had  losses  7  years  out  of  10  or 
whoever's  idea;  is  that  in  here  at  all?  Just  yes  or  no. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  That  is  in  here  but  in  a  different  form. 

Mr.  Peterson.  You  are  getting  at  that  problem  somehow? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Yes. 

Mr.  Peterson.  I  will  try  to  figure  out  what  it  is.  Thank  you. 
Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Barrett. 

Mr.  Barrett.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  and,  Mr.  Ackerman,  I 
appreciate  your  succinct  answers  and  your  grasp  of  the  subject 
matter  very  much. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Barrett.  I  believe  that  the  reform  plan  does  include  for  the 
first  time  ever  coverage  being  allowed  for  losses  from  floods  and 
other  disasters  which  prevent  the  farmer  from  planting  a  crop,  and 
this  is  an  interesting  new  idea. 

Can  you  share  with  us  what  guidelines  will  be  used  for  such  cov- 
erage? What  is  to  prevent  a  person  from  taking  advantage  of  that 
particular  section,  that  particular  coverage?  How  do  you  monitor? 
How  do  you  adjust?  Share  with  us,  please. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  To  give  you  a  general  overview,  this  preventive 
planting  coverage  has  actually  been  available  for  a  number  of  years 
as  an  option  but  most  farmers  have  chosen  not  to  buy  it  because 
it  generally  is  not  triggered  very  often.  Last  year's  flood  turned  out 
to  be  the  situation  where  farmers  needed  it. 

Basically,  what  it  says  is  that  if  you  cannot  plant  a  crop  because 
of  an  insurable  cause,  like  excessive  rain  or  whatever,  you  would 
get  a  pa3anent.  It  is  a  smaller  pa3mnent  than  you  would  get  for  a 
crop  loss  because  you  haven't  invested  as  much  in  the  crop.  It  is 
generally  about  half,  and  it  is  tied  to  a  late  planting  coverage,  that 
if  you  plant  past  the  usual  deadline  for  planting,  you  would  get 
coverage  for  that  rather  than  simply  being  cut  off. 

Yes,  it  does  raise  some  compliance  issues.  It  is  something  we  are 
going  to  have  to  watch  carefully.  We  are  already  having  to  wrestle 
with  some  situations  created  by  the  aftermath  of  the  flooding  last 
year  where  we  know,  for  instance,  that  there  are  a  number  of 
farms  where  the  soil  is  still  very  soggy,  where  there  is  sand  on  the 
soil  from  last  year,  and  where  there  is  still  water  on  the  soil  from 
last  year.  We  are  going  to  have  to  make  some  very  close  calls  about 
whether  the  insurer's  cause  exists  within  this  year's  insurance  pe- 
riod or  last  year's.  So  it  is  something  we  are  going  to  have  to  watch 
closely,  but  that  is  generally  how  it  works. 

Mr.  Barrett.  How  will  you  know  what  crop  that  farmer  was 
going  to  plant? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  How  would  we  know  what  they  are  going  to 
plant? 

Mr.  Barrett.  Yes. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Generally,  we  ask  them.  We  look  at  their  history 
of  planting.  And  a  lot  of  these  cases  with  preventive  planting,  it  is 
going  to  involve  case-by-case  determinations. 

Mr.  Barrett.  There  would  be  possibly  an  opportunity  for  exag- 
geration or  taking  advantage  of  the  system? 


23 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  There  is  always  that  possibility.  We  do  have  a 
compliance  program  in  the  field  and  they  are  there  for  a  reason. 
The  companies  have  compliance  programs  also  for  the  same  reason. 
I  know  it  is  a  new  program,  but  we  have  not  been  aware,  to  date, 
of  farmers  abusing  this  in  any  systematic  way,  but  we  are  watch- 
ing this  very  closely.  The  biggest  problems  actually  are  going  to  be 
some  of  the  close  questions  about  drenched  fields  and  soil  covered 
fields  and  how  it  will  apply  there. 

Mr.  Barrett.  Good.  You  have  touched  on — I  think  Mr.  Ewing 
touched  on  it  basically — a  question  of  noncovered  crops.  Why  not 
cover,  I  would  like  you  to  elaborate  on  this,  why  not  cover  millet, 
pinto  beans,  that  sort  of  thing?  You  mentioned  a  standing  disaster 
plan.  Would  you  embellish  just  a  bit,  please? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Pinto  beans,  by  the  way,  I  think  we  do  cover  in 
some  situations,  but 

Mr.  Barrett.  Refried  beans,  whatever. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  The  reason  we  do  not  cover  a  lot  of  crops  is  our 
program  is  an  insurance  program.  We  need  to  design  it  where  we 
charge  a  rate,  a  premium  rate  for  the  coverage  which  covers  the 
potential  for  loss,  and  where  we  are  not  taking  on  risks  that  we 
can't  measure  or  that  are  disproportionate  to  the  costs. 

Mr.  Barrett.  You  don't  have  a  history,  then? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  don't  have  a  history.  We  know  that  the  crop 
doesn't  have  a  stable  history  in  a  particular  area.  Before  we  bring 
a  crop  in,  we  study  the  rates.  We  make  sure  that  there  is  enough 
history,  that  we  can  set  a  rate  that  is  meaningful.  For  some  of  the 
newer  crops  or  crops  that  are  grown  in  very  small  amounts,  we 
have  not  been  able  to  do  that. 

Grenerally,  the  crops  that  are  hsted  as  being  in  the  pipeline  are 
ones  that  we  have  a  fairly  rigorous  analysis  underway. 

Mr.  Barrett.  I  have  had  a  few  questions  already  asked  from  my 
district  in  this  particular  area. 

The  plan  calls  for  coverage  on  losses  greater  than  50  percent  at 
a  payment  rate  of  60  percent.  Again,  the  rationale,  and  I  think  Mr. 
Combest  touched  on  this,  why  not  80  percent?  Why  not  40  percent? 
Would  you  please  elaborate  a  bit? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Well,  again  the  reason  is  that  we  were  trying  to 
replicate  a  disaster  payment.  We  did  not  want  to  make  this  essen- 
tially free  level  of  coverage  so  attractive  that  farmers  would  give 
up  their  higher  levels  of  coverage  and  run  to  it.  We  wanted  to 
make  it,  in  fact,  a  replacement  for  disaster  coverage.  We  were  also 
operating  within  a  budget  and  we  just  had  so  much  money  avail- 
able. 

Mr.  Barrett.  My  time  is  expired,  Mr.  Chairman.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Pomeroy. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  want  to  thank  you  for  having 
this  hearing  today,  and  I  commend  our  lead  witness.  I  have  spoken 
with  him  many  times  and  know  that  he  brings  some  really  strong 
incisive  leadership  to  crop  insurance  reform. 

Here  is  a  threshold  question,  Mr.  Ackerman.  The  plan  proposed 
depends  upon  adequate  funding.  At  this  point  in  the  budgeting 
process,  the  House  did  go  along  with  the  plan  but  only  to  the  tune 
of  about  three-quarters  of  the  funding  required  and  the  Senate 
didn't  go  along  with  it  at  all.  It  is  my  belief  that  the  program  does 


24 

not  work  if  funded  at  the  level  the  House  provided  for  it.  Do  you 
have  a  comment  on  that? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  think  generally  we  would  agree  that  we  would 
need  the  higher  level.  I  would  say  that  we  very  much  appreciate 
the  action  of  the  House  on  this  because  we  feel  that  the  House  in 
making  the  budget  adjustment  of  about  $700  million  a  year  made 
a  very  strong  statement  and  adopted  the  rationale  for  a  baseline 
adjustment,  which  was  a  very  historic  action.  There  was  a  dis- 
agreement about  the  number,  but  still  the  action  was  very  impor- 
tant. 

The  Senate,  as  I  understand  it,  because  of  other  issues  that  were 
raised,  never  quite  reached  this  issue,  so  I  think  we  can  character- 
ize it  as  a  neutral,  which  leaves  open  the  opportunity  to  raise  the 
issue  in  conference  between  the  House  and  Senate  and  hopefully 
resolve  it  in  a  good  way. 

Mr.  POMEROY.  I  think  that  that  is  possible.  This  is  what  worries 
me — the  other  things  that  were  preoccupying  the  Senate  were  re- 
moving an  additional  $25  billion  or  something  like  that  from  the 
President's  budget.  That  makes  the  prospect  of  them  meeting 
House  action  to  the  tune  of  $750  million  and  adding  an  additional 
$300  million  or  a  little  better  than  that  to  adequately  fund  this  pro- 
gram, I  think,  unlikely.  Not  necessarily  prohibitively  unlikely,  but 
somewhat  unlikely. 

This  committee  would  have  to,  in  my  opinion,  strongly  object  to 
a  proposal  that  went  along  with  your  ideas  but  only  provided  the 
funding  of  $750  million  as  occurred  in  the  House  and  as  was  scored 
by  the  Congressional  Budget  Office. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Let  me  make  two  points.  One  is  that,  as  I  under- 
stand the  budget  process,  and  the  rules  get  very  complicated  as  you 
get  into  it,  but  that  the  baseline  adjustment  does  not  necessarily 
involve  increased  spending.  It  is  changing  a  baseline.  It  is  recogniz- 
ing money  that  is  currently  being  spent  in  the  real  world,  $1  billion 
a  year  for  disaster  aid,  and  adding  it  to  the  baseline  from  which 
spending  or  spending  additions  or  cuts  are  calculated.  So  that  may 
provide  a  way  for  this  to  be  resolved  in  conference  divorced  from 
the  larger  issue  of  whether  there  will  be  more  spending  cuts. 

Mr.  POMEROY.  I  think  your  point  is  well  made.  In  fact,  the  pro- 
posal represents  $750  million  savings  over  5  years. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  That  is  correct. 

Mr.  POMEROY.  That  comes  out  of  indemnity  payments  presently 
received  by  farmers,  insurance  or  disaster.  So  to  obtain  the  greater 
stability  of  the  program  you  are  offering,  the  farmers  and  the  agri- 
cultural sector  is  prepared  to  pay  a  price  for  that  security.  Will  it 
be  a  position  of  the  administration  that  this  has  to  be  funded  at 
the  amount  requested  or  the  program  should  not  go  forward? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  think  the  way  I  would  have  to  answer  that  is 
this  way,  we  are  still  proposing  the  full  baseline  adjustment  that 
we  have  put  forward.  We  feel  the  billion  dollar  adjustment  is  rea- 
sonable, we  feel  it  is  well  documented.  We  feel  it  makes  sense. 

When  we  put  together  this  program  with  the  costs  that  are  in 
it,  we  think  it  is  a  tight  program.  I  don't  see  a  lot  of  fluff  in  it.  If 
there  is  a  lower  number  that  we  are  presented  with,  we  will  go 
back.  We  will  reexamine  our  assumptions,  we  will  look  at  our  nun^- 
bers,  run  them  again,  see  what  flexibility  we  can  find,  but  at  this 


25 

point,  my  impression,  £ind  Mr.  Moos  is  here  to  back  me  up  if  need 
be,  is  that  we  are  still  advocating  the  full  baseline  adjustment  that 
we  have  been  talking  about.  The  subsidies  for  higher  level  coverage 
are  very  important.  The  50/60  coverage  is  designed  to  serve  a  spe- 
cific purpose  of  replacing  disaster  aid.  The  numbers  were  chosen 
with  care,  and  so  our  proposal  at  this  point  stands  as  is. 

Mr.  POMEROY.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  share  the  concerns  expressed  by  Mr.  Pomeroy. 
The  surest  way  to  doom  any  reform  is  to  grossly  underfund  the  re- 
form and  then  find  that  it  simply  does  not  work,  not  that  the  re- 
form was  conceptually  wrong,  but  simply  there  wasn't  enough  fund- 
ing to  make  it  truly  workable  and  this  is  something  we  will  have 
to  monitor  very  closely  and  we  may  have  some  difficult  decisions 
to  make  about  whether  to  go  forward  with  the  reform  if  it,  in  fact, 
is  inadequately  funded  at  whatever  level  that  threshold  may  be. 

Relative  again  to  the  mechanics  of  the  legislation  before  us,  I 
have  a  lot  of  concern  expressed  to  me  about  the  use  of  actual  pro- 
duction history  for  the  4  previous  crop  years,  building  up  to  10 
years  and  then  that  use  the  transitional  jdelds  or  T  yields  if  the 
APH  is  not  available  when  disasters  have  occurred  over  several 
years  in  a  row.  In  many  parts  of  my  State  that  is  true.  Or  new  land 
is  purchased  or  the  land  is  in  rotation,  the  yield  coverage  can  be 
extraordinarily  low.  Is  there  anjrthing  that  we  can  do  to  address 
that  problem? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes,  sir.  One  of  the  provisions  in  our  blueprint 
that  we  have  committed  to  publicly  was  in  response  to  this  very 
specific  concern.  It  is  to  provide  a  catastrophic  jrield  adjustment  for 
crop  year  1995.  We  have  heard  from  many  parts  of  the  country  in- 
volving many  different  crop  concerns  about  the  4-year  APH  and  the 
effect  of  catastrophes  on  that.  Obviously,  the  purpose  of  the  APH 
program  is  to  provide  a  realistic  yield  projection.  For  a  farmer  com- 
ing in  after  this  past  year's  flood  with  a  yield  of  zero,  that  is  not 
a  realistic  projection,  and  we  understand,  particularly  for  many 
farmers  coming  in  for  the  first  time  this  year,  they  are  starting  out 
with  no  records  and  their  first  year's  record  is  a  zero  and  they  are 
very  much  at  a  disadvantage. 

We  understand  in  other  parts  of  the  country,  for  inst£mce,  cotton 
in  the  South  has  been  hit  several  years  recently  very  hard.  We  are 
very  much  committed  to  trying  to  address  that.  I  don't  want  to 
overbill  it.  A  catastrophic  yield  adjustment  will  not  get  everyone  to 
as  high  of  a  yield  as  they  would  want  to  be,  but  it  is  a  way  of  at 
least  trying  to  soften  this  provision  to  make  sure  that  it  is  work- 
able. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Will  you  elaborate  just  a  bit  on  the  expense  reim- 
bursement formula?  How  much  are  insurance  agents  going  to  re- 
ceive for  their  catastrophic  as  well  as  for  their  buy-up  coverage  and 
how  that  expense  mechanism  works? 

Mr.  AcKERMAN.  Currently,  under  the  program,  the  insurance 
companies  receive  a  subsidy  for  their  administrative  expenses  set 
at  an  industrywide  percentage.  This  year  it  is  31  percent  of  the 
premium.  That  money  goes  to  the  companies  to  reimburse  them  for 
their  administrative  costs. 

Under  the  new  program,  for  catastrophic  coverage,  there  would 
not  be  a  premium — ^there  would  not  be  an  expense  reimbursement. 


26 

Rather,  the  farmer  would  pay  a  processing  fee  of  $50  or  $100.  That 
$50  or  $100  would  go  to  either  the  company,  if  that  is  where  the 
farmer  chooses  to  purchase  it,  or  the  ASCS  or  farm  service  agency 
office.  That  is  what  there  would  be  available  at  the  other  end. 
There  would  also  be  an  allowance  for  loss  adjustment  costs. 

For  the  buy-up  coverage,  we  would  change  the  system  from  the 
status  quo  by  combining  the  two  current  subsidies,  the  premium 
subsidy  and  the  expense  reimbursement  subsidy  into  a  single 
amount,  and  in  doing  that,  we  would  say  that  if  one  company  can 
deliver  the  product  more  efficiently  than  another  company,  that 
they  could  pass  along  the  savings  to  the  farmer.  In  other  words, 
we  would  start  out  by  giving  every  company  that  same  31  or  what- 
ever percent  for  the  buy-up  coverage,  but  then  allow  price  competi- 
tion so  that  savings  could  be  passed  along  to  the  farmer. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Would  you  elaborate  just  a  bit  on  your  belief  in 
the  need  for  a  dual  delivery  system,  whether  this  is  going  to  gen- 
erate some  large  training  problems  at  the  FSA  level  and  whether 
this  is  a  transitional  or  is  this  a  permanent  feature  of  the  crop  in- 
surance system? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  would  view  this  as  a  permanent  feature.  And 
yes,  we  understand  that  getting  this  up  and  running  does  require 
and  involve  a  certain  burden  on  us,  USDA,  to  put  this  together.  We 
are  going  to  have  to  train  people  in  the  field.  We  are  going  to  have 
to  provide  computer  support.  We  are  going  to  have  to  provide  data 
processing  support  in  order  to  make  this  work. 

However,  when  we  took  a  look  at  this  project  from  the  beginning, 
one  of  the  things  that  stuck  out  right  away,  particularly  with  man- 
datory linkage,  is  the  workload  involved.  We  are  looking  at  going 
from  33  percent  participation  to  about  80  percent  participation. 
That  means  going  from  about  700,000  policies  to  about  1.7  million 
or  1.8  million  policies.  That  is  a  very  big  increase  in  workload. 

It  became  apparent  that  while  there  are  a  number  of  States, 
maybe  half  a  dozen  to  a  dozen,  where  you  have  1,000  or  2,000  or 
3,000  agents  present,  there  are  a  lot  of  other  States  where  you  sim- 
ply don't.  To  require  every  farmer  to  go  to  a  private  agent  to  get 
this  work  done,  particularly  in  the  early  years  when  we  are  not 
sure  how  many  private  companies  are  going  to  want  to  get  into  this 
business,  when  we  are  still  trying  to  work  things  through,  we  did 
not  want  to  run  the  risk  of  disruptions  in  sign-ups  during  the  early 
years.  So  the  main  force  driving  this  is  a  workload  force. 

Mr.  Moos.  Mr.  Chairman,  perhaps  I  could  make  a  comment  on 
that  point.  Given  certain  statutory  restrictions  to  go  ahead  and  to 
plan  and  to  develop  the  implementing  programs  here  in  terms  of 
the  merger  under  the  Farm  Service  Agency,  I  would  encourage  ev- 
eryone to  move  and  to  consider  moving  quickly  on  the  reorganiza- 
tion plan.  That  could  complicate  our  ability  to  provide  this  kind  of 
dual  service  this  fall. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  think  it  is  a  point  well  taken.  Having  consumed 
my  allotted  time,  Mr.  Combest. 

Mr.  Combest.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Barrett  was  questioning  earlier  about  someone  not  telling 
you  exactly  what  they  intended  to  plant  in  preventive  planting.  A 
person  would  sign  up  for  this  when  they  came  in  for  sign-up;  isn't 
that  correct?  They  would  sign  up  for  their  participation. 


27 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  So  you  would  obviously  in  sign-up  know  where  at 
least  those  crops  which  required  identification 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  That  is  correct. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  Have  you  run  the  numbers  on  what  your  esti- 
mated cost  of  the  program  would  be  versus  what  it  is  by  using 
ASCS  proven  jdelds? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  You  mean  if  we  were  to  use  ASCS  3delds  instead 
of  individual  yields? 

Mr.  COMBEST.  Right.  Proven  yields,  a  proven  yield  within  the 
counties. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Proven  yields  instead  of? 

Mr.  COMBEST.  ASCS  proven  yields.  The  yields  by  which  each 
farmer  in  the  ASCS  office  has  their  yields  established. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  My  understanding,  when  we  ran  the  numbers 
last  year,  when  we  put  the  APH  program  into  effect  and  when  this 
was  being  considered  during  the  reconciliation  bill,  they  were  based 
on  ASCS  program  yields  county  by  county. 

Mr.  CoMBEST.  County-by-county  average. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Right. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  Rather  than  by  farm. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Rather  than  the  proven  jrields  by  farm?  I  don't 
think  we  have  the  data  on  the  proven  yields  by  farm  to  make  that 
specific  comparison. 

Mr.  CoMBEST.  One  of  the  considerations  has  always  been  in  look- 
ing at  the  crop  insurance  program,  I  am  an  advocate  of  using  ASCS 
proven  yields  for  crop  insurance,  and  I  had  just  wondered  if  you, 
in  fact,  had  happened  to  run  those  numbers.  There  is  no  reason 
you  necessarily  would.  I  just  wondered  how  much  more  it  would 
cost.  I  am  sure  it  would  be  higher,  but  in  an  instance,  let's  say, 
where  we  have  got  a  farmer  who  signs  up  for  the  cotton  program. 
It  is  too  wet,  too  dry,  whatever,  and  preventive  planting  is  a  very 
significant  part  of  this,  I  think,  is  not  able  to  plant,  passes  the 
planting  date,  the  optimum  planting  date,  and  is  signed  up  and 
would  be  eligible  for  their  participation  in  the  cotton  portion  of 
that,  goes  back  in  and  follows,  they  can  also  then  pay  another  $50 
at  that  time  on  that  same  acreage  that  had  initially  been  intended 
to  be  devoted  to  cotton  and  insure  their  replacement  crop — I  guess 
they  would  have  to,  wouldn't  they? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  think  they  would  have  to,  yes. 

Mr.  CoMBEST.  They  would  have  to  do  that,  OK. 

You  kind  of  addressed  the  workload.  Having  come  from  ASCS 
years  ago,  that  is  always  a  concern  of  mine,  is  how  much — ^they  are 
always  very  willing,  as  all  agencies  of  USDA  are,  to  take  on  extra 
work,  and  yet  there  is  a  point,  obviously,  that  they  can't,  and  rec- 
ognizing that  there  is  an  interest  in  moving  to  FSA  rather  than 
ASCS  or  the  other  agencies,  I  am  not  telling  you  anything  here 
that  I  am  sure  you  haven't  thought  of,  but  we  have  found  in  deal- 
ing, for  example,  in  Farmers  Home  loans  and  so  forth,  one  of  the 
big  concerns  we  used  to  have,  just  the  burdensome  paperwork,  just 
the  stacks  of  it,  and  that  has  been  significantly  reformed.  We  want 
to  take  a  little  credit  for  that  just  because  of  our  persistence. 

But  I  would  think  that  there  would  be,  in  that  you  have  already 
got  established  FSA,  wherever  it  is,  that  we  are  going  to  be  calling 


81-128  0-94-2 


28 

them  by  the  time  this  program  starts,  which  I  hope  would  be  very 
soon;  that  I  would  think  there  would  be  a  fairly  simple  way  when 
a  person  comes  in  to  sign  up,  the  other  sign  up  work  they  have  got 
to  do  anyway,  just  simply  to  add  this  on  without  a  tremendous 
amount  of  additional  paperwork  at  sign-up  time,  which  is  always 
a  critical  time  because  you  have  everybody  coming  in  at  one  time. 

The  workload  would  seem  to  be  that  it  could  potentially  be  in- 
creased when  one  has  to  start  making  those  assessments.  Of 
course,  they  have  to  go  out  and  spot  check  an)rway  during  the  year 
with  various  farms,  but  I  could  see  there  to  be  a  potenti£d  add-on 
there  of  work  which  might  not  normally  be  required  in  doing  nor- 
mal, what  we  consider  today  ASCS  duties. 

And  just  from  a  personnel  standpoint,  going  into  this,  if  there  is 
some  kind  of  way,  and  I  know  we  used  to  be  able  to  do  this  and 
still  do  in  some  agencies,  where  you  can  get  help  from  other  em- 
ployees in  certain  parts  of — maybe  if  you  get  hit  with  a  pgu-ticularly 
hard  year  in  one  area,  you  are  not  going  to  need  maybe  as  many 
people  doing  that  in  other  parts,  so  we  can  sort  of  shift  people 
around  and  try  to  accommodate  that. 

Just  that  in  itself  and  the  ease  with  which  the  farmer  can  see 
that  it  has  worked  with  this  program  I  think  will  also  help  in  the 
long  run  on  the  participatory  side. 

I  hope  you  will  keep  that  in  mind,  as  you  are  dealing,  you,  Mr. 
Under  Secretary,  probably  more  so  in  encompassing  a  number  of 
agencies,  the  ability  to  do  some  shifting  there  where  we  cannot  be 
overstafted  but  adequately  staftied  as  this  new  program  would  be 
starting. 

Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Minge. 

Mr.  Minge.  First,  I  would  like  to  ask  what  leadtime  do  you  need 
to  set  up  this  program  for  the  1995  crop  year? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  What  we  are  looking  at  is  we  would  need  to  have 
the  bill  signed  by  about  the  middle  of  the  year  to  get  this  up  and 
running  for  the  1995  crop  year.  Even  that  will  be  very  tight  and 
we  will  probably  have  to  make  some  special  arrangement  for  the 
fall  planted  crops,  because  for  them,  sign-up  dates  are  as  early  as 
September  or  earlier.  So  we  would  probably  have  to  make  some 
special  provision  for  them  even  under  the  best  of  circumstances. 

Mr.  Minge.  Would  you  have  to  have  the  appropriation  in  place 
too  then  by  the  middle  of  the  summer? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  If  we  know  the  appropriation  is  coming,  gen- 
erally appropriation  bills  are  somewhat  later  in  the  year,  but  if  we 
know  the  appropriation  is  coming,  we  should  be  able  to  go  forward. 

Mr.  Minge.  I  don't  think  anything  is  known  until  it  is  done.  That 
is  the  impression  of  this  place  after  15  short  months. 

Is  there,  as  a  part  of  the  proposal,  the  expectation  that  the  Fed- 
eral Crop  Insurance  Corporation  will  be  using  ASCS  figures  so  that 
we  will  be  working  off*  of  one  set  of  data  as  opposed  to  two? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  We  would  be  working  off  of  FCIC  yield  data 
rather  than  ASCS  data.  It  is  true  that  over  time,  as  ASCS  and 
FCIC  are  merged  to  become  one  single  agency,  that  we  will  be  get- 
ting better  at  that.  But  what  we  would  be  looking  at,  particularly 
on  the  yield  data  because  that  is  really  the  most  sensitive  and  most 
work  intensive  is  FCIC  data  rather  than  ASCS  data. 


29 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  have  heard  many  farmers  talk  about  the  moral  risk 
of  insurance  and  what  they  see  is  neighbors  who  have  taken  ad- 
vantage of  programs,  including  Federal  crop  insurance.  Is  there 
any  active  program  that  you  have  to  identify  either  errors  or  fraud 
in  connection  with  Federal  crop  insurance,  including  allowing  peo- 
ple to  report  on  activities  that  they  see  that  are  occurring  in  their 
community? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  have  a  very  active  compliance  program  and 
it  is  something  that  we  are  hoping  to  emphasize  more  as  we  go  on. 
Obviously,  to  expand  the  program  to  this  extent,  we  are  going  to 
have  to  police  it  very  carefully.  I  believe  we  do  have  an  800  number 
that  farmers  can  call  to  report  complaints,  and  we  can  provide  that 
to  you. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  am  interested  in  the  changes  that  you  have  alluded 
to  with  respect  to  the  preventive  planting  and  late  planting.  Would 
it  be  correct  to  say  that  the  level  of  benefits  under  late  planting 
would  always  be  greater  than  the  level  of  benefits  for  preventive 
planting? 

Mr.  AcKERMAN.  I  think  that  is  right. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  would  like  to  emphasize  the  importance  of  this,  es- 
pecially based  on  your  experience  with  the  flooding  last  summer, 
where  we  had  farmers  who  had  large  areas  that  they  could  not 
plant  at  all  and  then  areas  where,  if  they  were  very,  very  diligent 
and  willing  to  take  a  risk,  they  could  go  in  and  plant  and  hope  to 
get  a  crop.  And  as  I  understand  it,  many  of  those  farmers  felt  that 
they  were  penalized  if  they  went  in  late  in  the  year  and  tried  to 
do  their  very  best  to  get  a  crop  because  they  received  less  in  the 
form  of  coverage  and  ultimately  benefits  than  those  farmers  who 
were  less  aggressive  and  simply  tried  to  maximize  potential  bene- 
fits. That  is  one  aspect  of  this  I  would  like  to  emphasize. 

The  second  is  that  several  people  have  told  me  that  they  have 
seen  farmers  in  their  township  who  were  very  diligent  about  cul- 
tivating or  spraying  or  taking  steps  necessary  to  try  to  maximize 
their  yields  in  1993  and  they,  in  fact,  did  have  jdelds  that  maybe 
only  resulted  in  a  60  percent  crop  loss. 

They  had  neighbors  who  said,  we  are  banking  on  a  disaster  pro- 
gram and  they  essentially  did  not  practice  any  sound  farming — ad- 
here to  any  sound  farming  techniques,  and  again,  I  know  we  can't 
micromanage  what  every  farmer  does,  but  I  trust  that  there  is 
some  sensitivity  to  this  type  of  taking  advantage  of  the  system,  if 
you  will,  in  the  administration  of  the  program. 

Mr.  AcKERMAN.  Yes,  sir. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  would  like  to  next  address  the  question  of  how  we 
prevent  this  from  becoming  an  entitlement  program  that  in  some 
years  just  runs  away  with  the  budget  and  adds  to  the  deficit.  Is 
there  any  plan  to  either  establish  a  type  of  reinsurance  pool  or  oth- 
erwise cover  the  catastrophic  monumental  loss  that  could  occur  if 
we  have,  again,  the  flood  of  the  century  or  the  flood  of  the  millen- 
nium that  we  are  facing? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  This  is  a  very  interesting  question  we  have 
looked  over  the  past  couple  of  months.  If  you  have  a  year  like  1993, 
even  under  the  best  planned  system,  there  will  be  a  large  loss  for 
the  Grovemment,  and  we  have  given  some  thought  to  the  possibility 
of  having  FCIC,  the  Federal  Government,  try  to  find  some  ways  to 


30 

cover  our  risk.  This  came  up  particularly  when  we  were  talking 
about  replacement  cost  coverage,  about  whether  we  might  be  able 
to  find  an  element  of  price  risk,  whether  there  is  some  way  for  us, 
the  Government,  to  pass  along  that  risk  to  the  private  futures  or 
options  market  perhaps  through  a  market  intermediary.  There 
have  been  some  thoughts  of  perhaps  taking  our  risk  in  toto,  large 
chunks  of  it  or  definable  parts  of  it  and  passing  it  on  to  a  commer- 
cial reinsurer. 

We  are  looking  at  some  of  those  ideas.  They  are  very  new  to  the 
Government.  Very  few,  if  any,  Ciovemment  agencies  currently  do 
that.  It  would  be  a  very  interesting  departure,  but  I  think  there  is 
a  lot  of  sense  to  it. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you.  I  see  my  time  is  up. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Pomeroy. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  Mr.  Ackerman,  I  have  some  questions  about  costs 
and  the  implementation  of  the  program.  The  nominal  sign-up  fee 
for  the  catastrophic  level  is  set  at  a  level  essentially  to  cover  proc- 
essing costs.  Have  you  done  an  internal  analysis  as  to  whether  the 
USDA  can  ultimately  deliver  these  policies  for  the  costs  or  charges 
assessed  to  the  farmers? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  We  are  having  a  number  of  discussions  with 
ASCS  to  talk  through  this  very  point,  and  those  talks  are  still  un- 
derway. We  feel  that  with  the  $50  or  $100  processing  fee,  we  can 
work  with  ASCS  or  our  partners  in  the  Farm  Service  Agency  to  de- 
liver this  program.  They  will  have  to  absorb,  obviously,  some  cost, 
just  as  in  the  past  they  have  had  to  absorb  the  cost  of  implement- 
ing ad  hoc  disaster  bills.  It  wiU  in  fact  put  some  strain  on  the  orga- 
nization in  order  to  get  this  done,  but  we  think  it  is  a  manageable 
one  and  we  are  starting  to  work  through  it  with  ASCS. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  I  ask  that  you  very  carefully  assess  the  relation- 
ship between  actual  cost  to  the  agency  and  money  received  as  an 
assessment  from  the  farmer,  because  as  you  have  acknowledged, 
the  dollar  amount  was  not  fixed  based  on  an  analysis  of  cost. 

In  the  event  you  are  dramatically  short,  and  I  think  you  might 
be,  there  will  be  a  fairly  substEmtiaJ  dislocation  of  ASCS  resources 
and  that  raises  a  host  of  policy  concerns  that  this  committee  would 
want  to  discuss. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  If  I  may,  one  of  the  major  variables  in  this  cal- 
culation is  to  what  extent  the  private  sector  will  step  in  and  ag- 
gressively market  this  product.  We  hope  that  they  will  and  we  hope 
that  in  most  parts  of  the  country,  farmers  given  a  choice  and  given 
a  reasonable  marketing  effort  by  the  private  sector,  that  the  bulk 
of  this  business  will  in  fact  go  to  private  agents. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  That  is  my  next  point.  The  public-private  partner- 
ship foundation  for  the  program  is  one  that  I  applaud  and  think, 
at  its  best,  represents  a  model  of  how  perhaps  many  programs 
could  work.  On  the  other  hand,  public-private  partnerships  only 
work  where  there  is  an  opportunity  for  the  private  sector  to  realize 
some  financial  return  competitive  to  what  they  might  resilize  in 
other  nonpartnership  ventures. 

Drawing  upon  my  experience  from  my  old  days  as  an  insurance 
regulator,  I  am  not  certain  that  present  return  to  the  private  sector 
adequately  compensates  for  risk.  I  am  familiar  with  one  company 
that  lost  last  year  fully  one-third  of  their  surplus.  Virtually  all  of 


31 

the  earnings  that  they  accured  during  the  preceding  years,  nearly 
10  years  in  Federal  crop  insurance  program  participation,  got 
wiped  out  last  year. 

As  you  work  toward  your  plan  for  the  1  to  1  actuarial  goal,  if  in- 
creased risk  is  laid  off  on  the  private  sector  while  return  to  the  pri- 
vate sector  is  screwed  down  a  little  tighter,  you  will  not  have  inter- 
est in  private  sector  participation.  Where  do  you  think  you  are  in 
trjdng  to  strike  that  delicate  balance  at  the  present  time? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  think  this  is  a  very,  very  important  point  and 
a  very  important  issue  that  we  are  working  with  the  private  indus- 
try on.  This  year,  as  you  note,  the  private  sector  companies  took 
a  major  loss — a  major  underwriting  loss  on  that  because  of  the  ca- 
tastrophe in  the  country.  Our  latest  numbers  show  that  the  under- 
writing loss  collectively  of  the  20-odd  companies  who  provide  crop 
insurance  is  in  the  range  of  $82  million  to  $83  million,  which  is  a 
lot  of  money. 

In  addition  to  that,  the  commercial  reinsurance  industry,  which 
provides  support  to  a  lot  of  the  private  companies,  is  very  tight  be- 
cause there  have  been  a  number  of  major  losses  outside  of  agri- 
culture, such  as  the  earthquakes  in  California  and  other  similar 
events.  So  generally  the  financial  picture  is  very  tight. 

We  are  going  to  be  going  forward  in  the  next  few  days  with  our 
proposed  reinsurance  contract  to  the  industry  which  sets  out  the 
actual  numbers,  the  actual  rules  for  risk  sharing  and  profit  poten- 
tial, and  this  is  something  that  we  are  going  to  have  to  work  with 
the  industry  on.  We  understand  that  we  have  to  provide  profit  po- 
tential to  the  industry  to  keep  them  in 'the  game. 

Mr.  Moos.  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Yes,  Mr.  Moss. 

Mr.  Moos.  I  have  got  another  commitment.  Might  I  be  excused 
at  this  point? 

Mr.  Johnson.  Yes,  you  may.  I  think  we  are  coming  down  the 
stretch.  There  may  be  a  couple  more  questions,  but  certainly,  Mr. 
Moos,  and  we  do  very  much  appreciate  your  willingness  to  attend 
this  hearing  and  participate  with  us,  and  we  look  forward  to  work- 
ing very,  very  closely  with  you  as  this  complex  issue  is  resolved. 
Thank  you. 

Mr.  Moos.  I  thank  you  and  the  members  very  much  for  this  op- 
portunity. We  think  we  have  a  good  workable  product  here  and 
would  look  forward  to  working  with  the  subcommittee  and  perfect- 
ing it.  So  thank  you  very  much,  and  I  am  sorry  I  do  have  to  run. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  Ken,  not  yet. 

Following  up  just  briefly  on  the  APH  issue  we  were  talking  about 
previously,  if  we  were  able  to  pass  this  legislation  and  would  ade- 
quately fund  it  and  do  it  on  the  time  line  you  recommend,  would 
catastrophic  adjustment  be  available  for  the  1995  crop  Winter 
wheat  planted  in  1994,  or  is  that  not  realistic? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  No,  I  think  that  is  realistic.  We  are  looking  to 
have  a  price  for  the  1995  crop  year,  yes. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  jdeld  my  time  to  my  colleagues  here.  Mr.  Minge. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  have  an  endless  supply  of  questions  here.  It  is  just 
a  question  of  when  to  stop.  I  would  like  to  ask  one  other  question 
and,  that  is,  do  we  have  a  system  built  into  Federal  crop  insurance 
to  address  the  dilemma  of  people  attempting  to  farm  areas  that 


32 

simply  cannot  be  successfully  farmed  due  to  various  weather  relat- 
ed or  other  risks,  and  if  we  do,  how  do  we  avoid  their  being  left 
out  of  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program  and  as  a  result,  begin- 
ning to  undermine  our  efforts  to  put  disaster  assistance  to  rest? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  The  answer  is  yes  and  it  requires  quite  a  lot  of 
careful  balancing.  There  are  a  number  of  elements  in  the  program 
that  reflect  the  high-risk  farmland.  For  instance,  if  a  certain  county 
is  a  very  risky  county  and  that  shows  up  in  annual  loss  ratios,  then 
that  will  affect  the  rates  charged  in  that  county.  Also,  by  basing 
the  program  more  on  actual  individual  yields,  that  would  reflect  a 
farmer's  individual  experience  if  they  farm  very  high-risk  land.  Fi- 
nally we  have  the  nonstandard  classification  system  to  identify 
farmers  with  very  disproportionate  loss  records. 

Yes,  you  are  right,  that  the  way  our  program  is  currently  struc- 
tured there  is  a  danger  of  pricing  people  out  of  the  market  and  cre- 
ating a  group  of  uncovered  farmers  who  would  be  needing  disaster 
aid.  My  hope  is  that  if  we  put  the  reform  package  into  place,  the 
catastrophic  coverage  could  operate  as  something  of  a  safety  net, 
that  if  you  have  farmers  who  are  bumped  out  of  the  system  by  the 
nonstandard  classification  system,  that  they  would  be  brought  back 
in  under  catastrophic  coverage.  Their  insured  jdelds  would  be  af- 
fected but  at  least  they  would  have  catastrophic  coverage. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Would  the  catastrophic  level  of  coverage,  in  effect, 
enable  them  to  continue  farming  land  that  should  not  be  farmed? 
I  will  just  say  I  have  heard  examples  of  people  who  don't  expect 
to  get  really  much  of  a  crop  at  all  but  they  farm  Federal  crop  insur- 
ance. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  They  would  have  coverage  but  it  would  be  very 
low  coverage.  They  would  not  be  farming  for  very  much,  and  the 
legislation  on  top  of  that  gives  us  the  ability  to  limit  coverage  in 
certain  areas  and  precisely  in  response  to  that. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Pomeroy. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  I  also  could  go  on  all  day  but  we  will  have  an  op- 
portunity soon  to  discuss  these  at  greater  length. 

The  only  other  question  I  would  have  involves  the  private  sector 
administration  of  this  catastrophic  layer  at  the  price  of  that  cov- 
erage, the  nominal  price  of  the  coverage.  Is  it  anticipated,  for  ex- 
ample, in  adjustment  that  a  privately  written  catastrophic  layer 
will  be  adjusted  privately? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes.  There  would  be  a  separate  payment  for  a 
loss  adjustment  separate  from  the  $50. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  So  none  of  the  $50  relates  to  adjustment. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Correct. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  That  is  covered  elsewhere.  I  thought  that  this 
would  work  under  a  very  simple  bare  bones  type  of  coverage  that 
might  be  provided  and  the  actual  APH  formula  proposed,  I  believe, 
requires  a  level  of  administrative  detail  that  is  really  tough  to  ac- 
complish under  that  price.  Do  you  have  an  evaluation  of  that? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  understand  that  in  many  cases  the  APH  cal- 
culations can  be  complex.  But  we  feel  that  it  is  necessary  for  the 
program,  that  it  is  important  for  the  program,  and  with  APH,  it  is 
more  fair  for  the  farmer.  They  are  getting  a  yield  that  more  accu- 
rately reflects  their  rates,  and  it  is  also  more  actuarially  sound  be- 


33 

cause  every  study  that  has  been  conducted  on  this  shows  that 
farmers  with  no  records  tend  to  have  a  disproportionate  share  of 
losses  and  that  is  why  we  have  drawn  a  fairly  strong  line  on  this 
wanting  to  go  with  APH  yields.  We  think  that  it  can  be  done. 

There  is  a  lot  of  experience  that  has  been  developed  in  the  last 
few  years,  in  the  private  sector  particularly,  where  APH  yields 
have  been  calculated  on  a  regular  basis.  There  are  computer  soft- 
ware systems  that  exist  to  help  salesmen  do  it.  These  software  sys- 
tems would  be  available  to  the  USDA  people  as  well  as  to  the  pri- 
vate sector.  We  would  certainly  need  to  work  with  both  sides  in  de- 
veloping clearer  rules  if  need  be  on  what  records  would  be  ade- 
quate, so  we  might  have  to  work  with  the  system  a  little  bit  to 
make  it  go,  but  I  think  it  is  an  important  element  to  this. 

Mr.  POMEROY.  The  final  question  I  have,  Mr.  Chairman,  involves 
whether  there  has  been  any  focus  group  analysis?  I  know  there 
hasn't  been  any  market  analysis  on  what  future  purchasing  trends 
might  be  with  this  program.  I  just  wonder  whether  there  will  be 
a  level  presently  purchasing  at  the  65  percent  level  and  paying  a 
premium  that  will  opt  for  the  virtually  free  catastrophic  level  and 
self-insure  their  exposure  after  that. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  That  particular  question  is  a  very  hard  one  to 
predict  and  we  think  we  have  built  in  a  number  of  incentives  for 
farmers  to  buy  up,  and  I  think  that  particularly  after  this  program 
is  in  place  for  a  year  or  two  and  there  is,  in  fact,  a  disastrous  event 
in  some  part  of  the  country  and  in  fact  Congress  does  not  pass  a 
disaster  bill,  that  will  probably  be  the  single  event  that  prompts  a 
large  number  of  farmers  to  buy  up. 

Mr.  PoMEROY.  Assuming  there  are  some  farmers  left? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Does  the  gentleman  from  Minnesota  have  any  con- 
cluding questions  at  this  point? 

Mr.  MiNGE.  With  an  eye  toward  the  clock,  I  will  defer  any  con- 
cluding comments. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  want  to  thank  you,  Mr.  Ackerman,  as  well  as 
Mr.  Moos,  for  being  with  us  today.  I  find  your  responses  very 
knowledgeable  and  forthcoming.  This  is  an  enormously  complex 
area  but  one  that  will  not  wait,  and  we  appreciate  your  leadership 
in  this  area. 

We  are,  again,  going  to  be  quite  aggressive  in  tr3dng  to  push  this 
legislation  on  the  House  side.  There  are  some  unknowns  at  this 
point  in  terms  of  funding  and  other  factors,  but  nonetheless,  I 
think  we  want  to  push  this  along  quickly,  so  thank  you  for  joining 
us  today.  We  will  all  be  working  very  closely  with  you,  both  for- 
mally and  informally,  as  this  year  goes  on.  Thank  you. 

With  that,  the  subcommittee  is  adjourned. 

[Whereupon,  at  12:30  p.m.,  the  subcommittee  was  adjourned,  to 
reconvene  subject  to  the  call  of  the  Chair.] 

[Material  submitted  for  inclusion  in  the  record  follows:] 


34 

Statement  for  Under  Secretary  Gene  Moos 

Before  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment, 

Credit  and  Rural  Development 

House  Committee  on  Agriculture 

March  25,  1994 


Good  morning  Chairman  Johnson  and  Members  of  the 
Subcommittee.   Thank  you  very  much  for  holding  this  hearing 
today  to  review  the  Administration's  proposed  bill  to  reform  crop 
insurance.   During  last  year's  flood.  President  Clinton  and 
Secretary  Espy  committed  themselves  to  reforming  the  way  in 
which  the  government  provides  producers  economic  assistance  for 
crop  losses  due  to  natural  disasters.   As  a  result  of  our  efforts,  on 
March  2nd,  Secretary  Espy  submitted  to  Congress  a  proposed  bill, 
the  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994."    In  formulating 
this  proposal,  we  met  with  many  of  FCIC's  constituent  groups, 
private  insurers.  Congress,  and  our  most  important  one,  farmers. 


35 

Page  2 

The  Manager  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation, 
Mr.  Kenneth  D.  Ackerman,  is  here  today  to  give  you  all  of  the 
details  of  this  proposed  legislation.    However,  before  I  turn  the 
microphone  over  to  him,  I  would  like  to  take  a  moment  to 
emphasize  the  importance  of  this  bill.    We  clearly  have  a  window 
of  opportunity  to  reform  the  process  of  providing  disaster  assistance 
and  we  should  take  advantage  of  it  before  we  get  embroiled  in  the 
1995  farm  bill  debate  or  faced  with  another  natural  disaster.   The 
logic  behind  this  bill  is  sound.    Right  now  we  have  two  very 
expensive  programs  delivering  crop  disaster  relief.   This 
duplication  is  not  only  upsetting  to  taxpayers,  it  is  unnecessary  and 
costly.    This  bill  merges  the  crop  insurance  and  crop  disaster 
programs,  into  one  program  which  will  be  delivered  by  the  FCIC. 
Mr.  Ackerman  will  explain  why  we  chose  this  course,  but  I  would 
like  to  say  that  our  emphasis  on  this  form  of  risk  protection  stems 
from  the  President's  belief  that  people  need  to  take  on  a  certain 
measure  of  responsibility  for  their  own  futures.    Crop  insurance 
enables  producers  to  do  just  that,  to  insure  their  futures. 


36 

Page  3 

In  closing,  I  ask  the  Subcommittee  and  the  Committee  to  deal 
with  this  issue  swiftly  so  USDA  can  implement  a  new  program  by 
1995  to  take  care  of  fiiture  disasters  in  an  efficient,  timely  way. 
The  Secretary  and  I  thank  you  again  for  your  time  today  and  look 
forward  to  working  with  you  on  this  proposed  legislation. 


37 


STATEMENT  OF 

EUGENE  MOOS,  UNDER  SECRETARY, 

INTERNATIONAL  AFFAIRS  AND  COMMODITY  PROGRAMS, 

UNITED  STATES  DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE 

and 

KEN^NETH  D.  ACKERMAN 

MANAGER,  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION, 

UNITED  STATES  DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE 

BEFORE  THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT,  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 

UNITED  STATES  HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

March  25,  1994 


We  want  to  thank  the  Subcommittee  for  holding  this  hearing  today  on  the 
Administration's  proposed  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994,"  which  was 
first  submitted  to  Congress  by  Secretary  Espy  three  weeks  ago.  We,  and  particularly 
Secretary  Espy,  greatly  appreciate  the  Subcommittee's  attention  to  the  goal  of 
reforming  Federal  crop  insurance  and  very  much  look  forward  to  working  with  all 
Committee  members  in  developing  a  plan  that  will  work  well  both  for  American 
farmers  and  taxpayers. 

As  much  as  any  program  in  Washington,  Federal  crop  insurance  has  long  needed 
change.  The  discontent  with  this  program  from  farmers,  taxpayers,  insurance  industry 
leaders.  Congress,  the  President,  and  others,  has  focused  on  long-standing,  well- 
documented  problems: 

o  Despite  an  annual  crop  insurance  price-tag  approaching  $900  million, 
Washington  has  had  to  step  in  with  crop  disaster  relief  payments  to  farmers  in 
eight  of  the  last  eight  years.  Standing  alone,  crop  insurance,  with  a  nationwide 
participation  rate  of  just  33  percent  in  1993,  simply  has  not  provided  an 
adequate  safety  net.  These  off-budget  crop  disaster  programs  have  cost 
taxpayers  an  average  $1  billion  per  year  over  the  last  decade,  and  more  than 
$1.5  billion  per  year  over  the  last  six  years.  This  conflict  between  crop 
insurance  and  crop  disaster  programs  must  end. 


38 


0  Crop  insurance  has  chronically  lost  money.  Since  1981,  the  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  Corporation's  (FCIC)  insurance  operations  have  produced  an  overall 
"loss  ratio"  of  about  1.47.  That  means  that  we  have  paid  out  about  $1.47  in 
claims  for  every  $1.00  collected  in  premiums  and  premium  subsidies,  not 
counting  overhead  costs.  Any  private  business  posting  these  numbers  would 
have  gone  bankrupt  years  ago.  Taxpayers  are  tired  of  picking  up  the  tab.  The 
program  must  be  made  more  financially  sound. 

o  Farmers  continue  to  complain  that  Federal  crop  insurance  does  not  meet  their 
needs.  The  program  must  be  made  more  farmer-friendly  with  new  products, 
more  flexibility,  and  a  good  attitude  toward  listening  to  customers. 

Last  summer's  disastrous  Midwest  flood  and  Southeast  drought  brought  the 
problems  of  crop  insurance  into  sharp  focus  for  Americans  across  the  country. 
Secretary  Espy  and  President  Clinton  travelled  extensively  in  the  flooded  areas  and 
spoke  directly  with  farmers  about  their  problems  and  experiences  in  dealing  with 
Federal  programs  designed  to  assist  them.  Again  and  again,  they  heard  concerns. 
These  problems  ranged  from  lack  of  coverage  for  prevented  planting,  to  inflexible  price 
elections,  to  uncertainty  about  the  availability  and  timeliness  of  help.  On  March  2,  just 
four  weeks  ago.  Secretary  Espy  announced  a  massive  reform  program  that  grew  directly 
from  last  summer's  experience. 

In  essence,  we  are  recommending  a  two-pronged  program  to  fix  Federal  crop 
msurance:  (I)  reform  from  the  inside  out  -  administrative  steps  to  make  the  program 
more  financially  sound  and  farmer-finendly,  and  (2)  reform  from  the  outside  in  -  the 
new  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994." 

Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  is  the  centerpiece  of  our  reform 
plan.  This  bill  responds  specifically  to  the  central  finding  of  our  review  following  last 
summer's  experience.  Ad  hoc  crop  disaster  bills  over  the  years  have  been  an  effective 
act  of  government  for  people  in  crisis.  These  relief  programs  have  helped  millions  of 
Amencans,  farmers  and  non-farmers  alike,  survive  the  most  difficult  periods  in  their 
lives.  But  the  reliance  on  this  ad  hoc  relief  that  has  developed  as  a  result  of  an  under- 
used crop  insurance  system,  has  created  a  level  of  uncertainty  that  is  bad  both  for 
farmers  and  taxpayers. 


39 


In  fact,  the  repeated  availability  of  ad  hoc  relief  has  been  a  disincentive  for 
many  farmers  to  participate  in  the  Federally  backed  crop  insurance  program. 

In  a  crisis,  a  farmer  without  crop  insurance,  who  depends  on  disaster  relief,  has 
no  way  of  knowing  in  advance  what  his  or  her  protection  will  be.  Farmers  do  not 
know  whether  a  disaster  bill  will  be  approved  or,  if  approved,  what  payment  level  the 
bill  will  provide.  Even  then,  a  farmer  suffering  loss  must  hope  that  other  farmers 
across  the  state,  and  in  ten  or  twenty  other  states,  are  experiencing  similar  losses  in 
order  to  create  the  momentum  for  action.  An  examination  of  history  reveals  that  victims 
of  local  disasters  often  get  less  than  those  of  wider  disasters,  even  though  the  individual 
farmers  may  suffer  similar  losses. 

For  example,  victims  of  1992's  Hurricane  Andrew  in  Florida,  received  aid  at 
50.04  percent  proration  while  victims  of  this  summer's  Midwest  flood  received  aid  at 
100  percent.  Farmers  with  losses  in  states  not  involved  in  the  large  disasters  found  that 
congressional  decisions  affecting  their  livelihoods  were  being  based  upon  factors  totally 
disconnected  from  their  circumstances. 

What  will  happen  if  natural  disaster  strikes  again  next  year?  Farmers  trying  to 
plan  their  operations  in  a  businesslike  manner  simply  have  no  way  to  know. 

Meanwhile,  taxpayers  are  concerned  that  disaster  aid  is  exempt  from  the  budget 
discipline  that  controls  spending  in  virtually  every  other  area  of  government.  At  a  time 
when  deficit  reduction  is  a  paramount  domestic  priority,  the  price  of  these  emergency 
programs  continues  to  rise.  The  public  rightly  questions  the  point  of  having  two 
expensive  programs  trying  to  address  a  single  recurring  problem  --  crop  disaster  aid. 
Americans  are  generous  in  a  crisis,  but  their  patience  has  limits. 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  resolves  this  situation  by 
combining  crop  insurance  and  disaster  aid  into  a  single,  unified,  on-budget  program. 
This  requires  two  steps.  First,  the  legislation  expands  the  crop  insurance  program  to 
protect  farmers,  financially,  when  natural  disasters  ruin  or  damage  their  crops.  Second, 
it  creates  a  legal  barrier  against  future  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  programs. 

We  view  this  proposal  as  being  both  a  vital  budget  reform  as  well  as  a  vital 
agricultural  reform. 

The  legislation  is  built  upon  several  key  pillars: 


40 


4 


1 :  Catastrophic  crop  insurance  coverage:  The  Federal  crop  insurance  program 
is  supplemented  with  a  new  catastrophic  coverage  level  available  to  farmers  of 
insured  crops  for  a  nominal  processing  fee  of  $50  251  crop  ^er  county,  up  to 
$100  Eer  farmer  ger  county.  The  processing  fee  may  be  waived  for  limited 
resource  farmers.  The  idea  is  to  make  this  coverage  very  economical  and 
accessible. 

Policies  will  cover  prevented  planting  as  well  as  actual  crop  losses,  and  will  be 
based  on  actual  individual  farm  yields. 

This  catastrophic  plan  will  protect  against  yield  losses  greater  than  50  percent 
at  a  payment  rate  of  60  percent  of  the  expected  market  price  --  a  level 
comparable  to  disaster  relief  programs  in  recent  years.  The  difference  is  this: 
catastrophic  coverage  is  an  individual  insurance  policy,  not  an  ad  hoc  relief 
payment.  It  is  a  contract  that  a  farmer  can  take  to  the  bank  as  collateral  on  a 
loan.  Even  if  no  other  farmer  in  the  country  suffers  a  loss,  the  farmer  has  the 
security  of  knowing  that  he  or  she  is  covered. 

Under  this  approach,  in  a  future  agricultural  crisis,  farmers  will  know  in  advance 
the  extent  of  their  protection  and  taxpayers  will  know  in  advance  the  limits  of 
their  exposure. 

2:  Buy-Up  coverage:  Most  producers  desire  higher  levels  of  coverage  than  the 
catastrophic  plan  offers  to  protect  their  farm  businesses.  The  legislation  provides 
targeted  subsidies  for  these  higher  insurance  coverage  levels.  The  out-of-pocket 
cost  for  coverage  at  the  65  or  75  percent  yield  levels  will  fall  by  about  10 
percent.  In  addition,  the  bill  gives  FCIC  the  authority  to  offer  policies  covering 
85  percent  of  yield.  The  more  farmers  buy  higher  levels  of  coverage,  the  more 
fiscally  sound  the  system  will  be. 

3:  Linkage  to  farm  programs:  To  ensure  the  widest  participation,  crop  insurance 
coverage  at  the  catastrophic  level  or  above  is  linked  to  participation  in  Federal 
commodity  price  support,  production  adjustment,  and  conservation  programs  and 
Farmers  Home  Administration  loans.  We  expect  that  this  step  will  result  in  crop 
insurance  participation  rising  from  33  percent  to  about  80  percent  of  insurable 
acres. 

The  purpose  of  linkage  is  to  guarantee  that,  if  disaster  strikes,  the  bulk  of  U.S. 
farmers  will  be  protected.  We  understand  that  farmers,  like  other  Americans,  do 
not  like  being  told  what  to  do,  this  is  human  nature.   But  the  linkage  proposal 


41 


is  fair  and  not  onerous  given  the  nominal  cost  of  catastrophic  coverage  to 
farmers.   Farmers  also  gain  security  for  the  future. 

4:  Delivery:  Farmers  may  choose  to  obtain  the  catastrophic  coverage  either 
through  a  private  reinsured  company  or  through  a  USDA  county  office.  Higher 
insurance  coverages  remain  available  only  from  private  insurers.  Our  goal  is  to 
provide  the  most  convenient  and  efficient  means  of  quickly  getting  catastrophic 
crop  insurance  coverage  to  the  largest  number  of  farmers.  The  private  sector's 
insurance  sales  force  will  have  a  full  opportunity  to  compete  for  the  catastrophic 
market. 

5:  Industry  competition:  The  legislation  restructures  premium  rates  to  reflect  both 
direct  premium  subsidies  and  the  expense  reimbursement  allowance  to  reinsured 
companies.  This  provides  a  more  realistic  picture  of  the  cost  of  the  program 
both  to  farmers  and  taxpayers.  More-efficient  companies  will  be  allowed  to  pass 
along  lowered  overhead  costs  in  reduced  rates  charged  to  farmers,  creating  a 
more  competitive  market  environment. 

6:  Uninsurable  crops:  A  standing  disaster  program  is  created  for  crops  not 
covered  by  crop  insurance,  with  payments  triggered  by  area-wide  loss  levels  and 
protection  levels  similar  to  those  under  the  catastrophic  insurance  plan.  This 
way,  no  one  is  left  out  in  the  cold,  the  wet,  or  the  dry. 

7:  Repeal  of  standing  disaster  assistance  authority:  Current  authorities  for 
standing  crop  disaster  relief  are  repealed.  In  the  future,  the  expanded  crop 
insurance  program  will  replace  disaster  bills  as  the  Federal  response  to 
emergencies  involving  widespread  crop  loss. 

As  added  protection,  the  legislation  exempts  appropriations  for  agricultural  crop 
disaster  assistance  from  designation  as  an  "emergency"  for  purposes  of  the 
Balanced  Budget  and  Emergency  Deficit  Control  Act  of  1985,  as  amended.  This 
action  essentially  places  future  crop  disaster  bills  on  budget.  They  must  be  paid 
by  off-setting  spending  cuts,  rather  than  being  allowed  to  proceed  as 
"emergency"  spending.  Therefore,  the  primary  vehicle  for  providing  crop 
disaster  assistance  will  be  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program,  as  its  legislation 
originally  intended. 

We  project  that  the  new  program  created  by  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform 
Act  of  1994  will  cost  about  $8.1  billion  for  fiscal  years  1995  through  1999.  This 
represents  a  five-year  savings  of  some  $750  million  compared  to  the  projected  cost  of 


42 


6 

the  current  Federal  crop  insurance  program  plus  the  average  annual  cost  of  ad  hoc  crop 
loss  disaster  relief  programs  over  the  past  decade.  Essentially,  this  plan  takes  the  $1 
billion  that  Washington  now  spends  each  year  on  off-budget  crop  disaster  programs  and 
re-channels  it  into  a  more-disciplined,  on-budget  insurance  plan. 

We  would  like  to  implement  this  new  program  in  crop  year  1995  so  that  its 
benefits  of  certainty  can  be  felt  by  farmers  and  taxpayers.  This  timetable  is  ambitious, 
and  will  require  Congress  to  do  its  part.  Combining  Federal  crop  insurance  and 
disaster  aid  will  be  a  complicated  process  involving  training  of  personnel,  rewriting  of 
rules,  and  educating  customers.    We  must  do  it  right. 


Achieving  Financial  Soundness 

Resolving  the  conflict  between  Federal  crop  insurance  and  disaster  programs  is 
not  enough.  We  must,  at  the  same  time,  also  make  Federal  crop  insurance  more 
financially  sound.  The  old  way  of  doing  business,  where  Federal  crop  insurance  lost 
excessive  amounts  of  taxpayer  money  year  after  year,  is  simply  no  longer  acceptable. 
The  1993  Omnibus  Reconciliation  Act  (OBRA)  requires  FCIC  to  achieve  an  overall 
projected  loss  ratio  of  1.1  by  the  year  beginning  October  1995.  The  1994  Agricultural 
Appropriations  Act  mandated  additional  cost-saving  reforms.  We  are  committed  to,  at 
least,  meeting  this  loss  ratio  goal  and  obtaining  actuarial  soundness.  American 
taxpayers  will  accept  nothing  less. 

As  part  of  the  March  2  reform  package.  Secretary  Espy  released  the  FCIC's 
"Blueprint  for  Financial  Soundness"  mandated  by  OBRA  1993.  This  document  outlines 
the  specific  steps  that  FCIC  will  take  to  improve  the  program's  financial  soundness  and 
the  savings  we  expect  to  result.   Those  steps  include: 

A  modified-APH  (actual  production  history)  program  to  better  tie  individual 
farmer's  insurance  coverage  to  their  individual  yield  history.  We  will  modify 
this  program  to  permit  a  catastrophic  yield  adjustment  beginning  in  crop  year 
1995; 

An  expanded  non-standard  classification  system  (NCS)  to  identify  those  farmers 
with  unusually  high  loss  histories  and  adjust  their  rates  to  more  sound  levels; 

Greater  emphasis  on  program  compliance  to  prevent  over  payments  based  on 
errors  and  abuses;  and 


43 


7 
Greater  risk-sharing  with  private  insurance  companies. 

Finally,  we  will  work  to  make  Federal  crop  insurance  more  farmer-friendly  by 
introducing  new  products,  more  flexibility,  and  more  responsiveness  to  complaints  and 
ideas  from  farmers,  agents,  companies,  and  all  participants  in  this  program.  Just 
recently,  FCIC  for  the  first  time  used  the  authority  granted  under  the  Food,  Agriculture, 
Trade  and  Conservation  Act  of  1990  to  back  financially  an  innovative  new  insurance 
product  developed  by  the  private  sector.  This  process  of  partnership  will  continue. 

The  challenge  of  reforming  Federal  crop  insurance  is  complex  and  difficult,  but 
we  believe  our  plan  is  a  responsible  one  and  will  be  responsive  to  the  needs  of 
American  farmers  and  taxpayers.  We  hope  that  Congress  will  act  expeditiously  on  the 
legislation  so  that  we  may  implement  the  new  program  for  the  1995  crop  year. 

We  will  be  pleased  to  answer  any  questions  you  may  have. 


(Attachments  follow:) 


f^^ 


44 


CM 

o 
o 


i-    t>- 


I 

w 

00 

o> 


in 

00 


0) 
D) 

CO 

> 
< 

re 

0) 

>• 


^     o 


a> 

O) 

re 

k. 

0) 

> 
< 

re 

>- 


CO 

oo 

I 
O) 
00 


I 
CO 


0) 
O) 

re 

^ 

> 
< 

re 

0) 

>- 

oT 
o 

c 
re 

k. 

3 
M 

C 

Q. 
O 


0) 
O) 

re 

0) 

> 
< 

re 

0) 

>- 


c 

0) 

E 

re 

Q. 


d)  ol 

(/>  ol 

re  E 

M  := 


45 


0) 

■K 

« 

*« 

9 

o 

o 

o 

o 

O 

ID 

o 

o 

o 

o 

in 

0 

1- 

0> 
0) 

0) 
(0 

o 
in 

CO 

00 

C/) 

'" 

O) 

;      —  , 

c 

■  ^1^ 

> 

■ ', ; 

'  ■"  '■'     '.  : 

CO 

B    • 

"D 

(/) 

■a 

■  ■ 

0) 

<1> 

^^ 

■n 

(0 
O) 

c 

■  ^^B 

< 

0 

0) 

u 

c 

(0 

(0 

a 

c 

■  MM 

> 

(0 

ency 

> 

o 

c 

■  ■ 

JC 

o 

CO 
O 

3 
(A 

C 

Q 
o 

3 

o 

■<5 

E 
o 
o 

■  ■ 

E 
re 

0) 

> 
u 

V) 
UL 

•i 

X 
CO 

w 

3 

Q. 
Q. 

Q. 
O 

o 

^ 

0 

2 

Q. 
X 

ns 

c 
E 

O) 

o 

o  < 

o 

^5:  DC 

z 

Q. 

h- 

fl)    c 

:= 

0) 

■  IH^ 

^ 

<o  O 

LLI 

O 

-    ■■ 

O    0 

£  a: 

Q. 
O 

0) 

o 

0) 

■-  - 

o  o 

fl 

o 

qI 

o 
a 

*  3 
II 

46 


UNITED  STATES  CROP  VALUE  SUMMARY 

INSURED  CROPS 
NATIONAL  VALUE  OF  ALL  CROPS  $92,385,311,215 


PERCENT 

REPORTED 

DOLLAR 

OF  TOTAL 

CROP 

ACRES 

VALVE 

VALUE 

Com,  Grain 

66,950,480 

18,008,691,703 

19.493 

Soybeans 

56,498,545 

11,213,520,994 

12.138 

Wheat 

69,353,948 

7,296,722,323 

7.898 

Cotton,  Upland 

11,501,930 

4,884,989,171 

5.288 

Tobacco 

732,740 

2,829,953,119 

3.063 

Potatoes 

1,363,816 

2,396,315,957 

2.594 

Nursery,  Container 

2,375,462,434 

2.571 

Corn,  Silage 

6,124,202 

1,954,333,349 

2.115 

Oranges 

770,214 

1,515,565,984 

1.640 

Apples 

352,114 

1,408,875,579 

1.525 

Peanuts 

1,807,325 

1,256,883,370 

1.360 

Sorghuna,  Grain 

9,086,031 

1,203,379,180 

1.303 

Sugar  Beets 

1,375,468 

1,125,379,300 

1.218 

Rice 

2,812,429 

1,040,085,810 

1.126 

Tomatoes  -  Fresh 

137,578 

924,639,769 

1.001 

Barley 

7,505,000 

906.414,000 

0.981 

Grapes  -  Processed 

408,090 

885,062,003 

0.958 

Sugarcane 

723,840 

813,706,190 

0.881 

Raisins 

266,737 

677.942,810 

0.734 

Beans,  Dry 

2,099,403 

660,075,798 

0.714 

Ahnonds 

413,202 

639,048,900 

0.692 

Tomatoes  -  Processed 

353,911 

617,956,960 

0.669 

Grapes,  Table 

90,343 

494,035,398 

0.535 

Onions 

146,180 

493,421,041 

0.534 

Peaches 

117,823 

482,137,001 

0.522 

Oats 

6,015,517 

412,485,275 

0.446 

Grapefruit 

168,923 

354,979,543 

0.384 

Lemons 

59,816 

347,117,610 

0.376 

Pears 

50,031 

281,428,961 

0.305 

Plums  -  Fresh 

45,199 

265,029,699 

0.287 

Sweet  Corn  -  Fresh 

191,672 

256,059,591 

0.277 

Walnuts,  English 

184,837 

254,412,036 

0.275     ■ 

Sunflowers 

1,854,495 

247,439,110 

0.268 

Peppers 

53,513 

225,972,741 

0.245 

Sovember  5,  1992 


Page:  1 


47 


UNITED  STATES  CROP  VALUE  SUMMARY 

INSURED  CROPS 
NATIONAL  VALUE  OF  ALL  CROPS  $92,385,311,215 


PERCENT 

REPORTED 

DOrjAR 

OF  TOTAL 

CROP 

ACRES 

VALUE 

VALUE 

Sweet  Corn  -  Processed 

476,613 

213,509,890 

0.231 

Nectarines 

25,761 

158,609,100 

0.172 

Cranberries 

27,801 

152,828,500 

0.165 

Beans,  Snap  -  Processed 

214,640 

139,856,244 

0.151 

Prunes 

79,707 

133,203,850 

0.144 

Peas,  Green 

293,750 

109,804,780 

0.119 

Tangerines 

18,922 

69,225,312 

0.075 

Apricots 

20,249 

48,509,599 

0.053 

Peas,  Dry 

274,500 

43,363,600 

0.047 

Macadamia  Nuts 

18,700 

41,720,000 

0.045 

Safflo^ver 

159,073 

37,924,863 

0.041 

Eax 

253.002 

20,858,600 

0.023 

Tangelos 

10,419 

16,897,699 

0.018 

Figs 

13,071 

16,351,600 

0.018 

Beans,  Lima  -  Processed 

21,650 

9,432.000 

0.010 

Temples 

9,199 

7,641,999 

0.008 

TOT.VL 

69,969,260,345 

75.736 

"Nursery,  Container"  crops  are  container  grown  landscape  plants. 

Values  are  not  available  for  the  following  insured  crops:  Popcorn,  Hybrid  Seed  Com,  Hybrid  Seed 
Sorghum. 

Acreage  data  is  incomplete  for  apples,  peaches,  pears  and  plums. 


.Sovembcr  5,  1992 


Page:  2 


48 


CROP  EXPANSION 
FEASIBILITY  STUDY  LIST 


Feasibility  studies  are  currently  underway  on  the 
following  crops  in  anticipation  of  developing  new 
crop  programs: 


AVOCADOS 

ASPARAGUS 

BLUEBERRIES 

BROCCOLI 

CANOLA 

CANTALOUPE 

CARROTS 

CAULIFLOWER 

CELERY 

CHERRIES-SWEET 

HAY-ALL 

HAY-HAYLAGE 

HAY-OTHER 


LETTUCE-HEAD 

LETTUCE-LEAF 

MUSHROOMS 

NURSERY  CROPS 

PECANS 

PEPPERMINT 

PINEAPPLE 

PISTACHIOS 

SEED-FORAGE 

SEED-LAWN 

STRAWBERRIES 

SWEET  POTATOES 

WATERMELON 


49 


.Participation  Under  the  Reform  Proposal 

(with  linkage) 


1995         1996        1997 
Crop  year 


Buy  up  coverage  (X/X  Basic  coverage 


Under  the  reform  proposal,  producers  who  participate  in  price  support  and 
income  support  programs  or  who  have  loans  under  any  program  of  the  Farmers 
Home  Administration  are  required  to  obtain  at  least  the  catastrophic  level  of 
1  insurance  for  aR  crops  of  economic  significance  farmed  in  the  county  in  which 
that  producer  has  an  interest.   The  linkage  with  commodity  programs  will  ensure 
that  participation  in  the  crop  insurance  program  is  80  percent  of  eligible  acreage 
in  1595. 


Requiring  producers  to  obtain  catastrophic  crop  insurance  for  program  crops  only 
would  potentially  lower  the  crop  insurance  participation  rate  as  significant  crops 
(e.g.,  soybeans)  would  be  largely  unaffected.   Participation  rates  would  likely  be 
only  as  high  as  65-70  percent  of  eUgible  acreage. 

IT  crop  insurance  is  not  linked  to  commodity  program  eligibility  it  is  likely 
that  crop  insurance  participation  will  be  only  55-60  percent  of  eligible  _ 
acreage,  at  least  in  the  early  years  of  program  operation.    Lower 
p>articipation  rates  could  encourage  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  which  would 
further  undermine  participation. 


50 


TARGETED  SUBSroiES  FOR  BUY-UPS 
CO^.^ARISON  OF  FARMER'S  OUT-OF-POCKET  EXPENSE 


WTTH  TARGETED  SUBSffiY  FOR  BUY-UPS 


Coverage 
Level 

Current 
Cost 

Cost  Under 
Reform  Act 

Difference 

65%  of  yield 

S296 

S246 

-17  percent 

75  fo  of  yield 

S623 

S574 

-  8  percent 

wriHOUTTAJ<GLlKD  bUl 

JSIDY  FOR  BUY-l 

JPS: 

Coverage 

Current 

Cost  Under 

Level 

Cost 

Reform  Act 
Without  Buy-up 
Subsidy 

Difference 

65  fo  of  yield 

S296 

S282 

-  5    percent 

75%  of  yield 

S623 

S609 

-  2    percent 

Assumptions: 

100  acres  planted/    100  bushel  yield/   SI. 00  price  election 
10  percent  premium  rate  for  75  percent  coverage 

Stated  costs  are  the  farmer's  out-of-pocket  cost  for  the  coverage  after  deducting  the 
subsidy. 


51 


FEDEnAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 
PREMIUM/INDEMNITIES/LCSS  RATIOS 
1981   -  1993  (Crop  Year  Data) 
(dollars  in  Ciousanc^s) 


YEAR 

PREMIUM 

INDEMNITIES 

LOSS  RATIO 

1981 

S379.169 

$408,101 

1.08 

1982 

398.671 

528,157 

1.S2 

1983 

291.353 

587.691 

2.02 

1984 

435.588 

639.969 

1.47 

19  85 

439.733 

684.364 

1.56 

1986 

381.753 

616.993 

1.62 

1987 

366.640 

369.163 

1.01 

1988 

437.654 

1,053.775 

2.41 

1989 

820.763 

1.215.763 

1.48 

19  90 

838.040 

1.023.581 

1.23 

1991 

737.146 

953.257 

1.29 

1992 

758.768 

920.901 

1.21 

1993  (ost.) 

784,652 

1.412,374 

1.30 

TOTAL  1981   -  1993 

$7,069,330 

$10,419,089 

1.47 

AVERAGE  1981-1993 

SS43.841 

S301.468 

1.47 

1992  Figures  —  Actuals  from  Oct.  27,  1993  Summary  of  Business 

1993  Figures  Irom  Damage  Report  of  Oct.  20.  1993. 


CO  MPT.^C  LL£.\-MT,\OTUS  :h-WFTE 


11.'11.'93 


52 


CORN  -  PARTICIPANT 

Comparison  between  Disaster  Assistance  and  MPCI  proposed  Catastrophic  Coverage 

••DOES  NOT  INCLUDE  DEnCENCY  PAYMENTS  RECEIVED** 


Assumptions:  APH  yield  =  1 20  bushels 

ASCS  Yield  =100  bushels 
MPCI  price  =  $2.30/bu 
ASCS  target  price  =  $2.75/bu 
ASCS  deficiency  pymt  =  $0.45^u 
Acres  planted  =  90 


Farm 

Per  Acre 

Disaster  (.5004  pro-rate) 

$3,952.00 

$43.91 

Disaster  (No  pro-rate) 

$7,898.00 

$87.76 

Catastrophic  Protection 

$7,776.00 

$86.40 

53 


FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 


CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  COMPARED  TO  DISASTER  ASSISTANCE 


CORN  NON-PARTICIPANT 


YIELD 

100% 

50% 

REFORM 

LOSS 

PRORATE 

PRORATE 

PLAN 

% 

100 

$  PER  ACRE 

80 

40 

86 

90 

67 

34 

69 

80 

54 

27 

52 

70 

41 

20 

35 

60 

27 

13 

17 

50 

18 

9 

0 

40 

0 

0 

0 

ASSUMPTIONS: 
COUNTY  AVERAGE  YIELD 
DISASTER  ASSIST.  PAYMENT 
APH  YIELD  (REFORM  PLAN) 
PRICE  ELECTION 


120  BUSHELS  PER  ACRE 
SI. 12  PER  BUSHEL 

120  BUSHELS  PER  ACRE 
$2.40  PER  BUSHEL 


54 


FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 


CROP  INSITRANCE  REFORM  COMPARED  TO  DISASTER  ASSIST AJVCE 


SOYBEANS 


YIELD 

100% 

50% 

REFORM       11 

LOSS 

PRORATE 

PRORATE 

PLAN           1 

% 

|| 

100 

S  PER  ACRE 

100 

53 

80 

90 

88 

44 

64 

80 

71 

36 

48 

70 

53 

27 

32 

60 

35 

18 

16 

50 

18 

9 

0 

40 

0 

0 

0 

ASSUMPTIONS: 

COUNTY  a\t:rage  yield 

DISASTER  ASSIST.  PAYMENT 
APH  YIELD  (REFORM  PLAN) 
PRICE  ELECTION 


45  BUSHELS  PER  ACRE 
53.91  PER  BUSHEL 

45  BUSHELS  PER  ACRE 
$5.90  PER  BUSHEL 


55 


COTTON 
Comparison  between  Disaster  Assistance  and  MPCI  proposed  Catastrophic  Coverage 


EXAMPLX#1 
Assximptions: 


APH  yield  =  406  pounds 
ASCS  Yield  =  406  pounds 
MPCI  price  =  $0.5 3 /lb 
ASCS  target  pnce  =  $0.729/lb 
ASCS  deficiency  pymt  =  $0. 1 86/lb 
Acres  planted  =  92.5 


Farm 

Per  Acre 

Disaster  (.5004  pro-rate) 

$3,813.00 

$41.22 

Catastrophic  Protection 

$5,971.25 

$64.55 

Disaster  (No  pro-rate) 

-'     $7,620.00 

$82.38 

EXAMPLE  #2 
Assumptions: 


APH  yield  =  383  pounds 
ASCS  Yield  =  406  pounds 
MPCI  pnce  =  $0.53/lb 
ASCS  target  pnce  =  $0.729/lb 
ASCS  deficiency  pymt  =  $0.1 86/lb 
Acres  planted  =  92.5 


Farm 

Per  Acre 

Disaster  (.5004  pro-rate) 

$3,813.00 

$41.22 

Catastrophic  Protection 

$5,633.00 

$60.90 

Disaster  (No  pro-rate) 

$7,620.00 

$82.38 

56 


COMPARISON  BETWEEN  CATASTROPHIC  RISK  PROTECTION 

AND 
DISASTER  ASSISTANCE 

WHEAT  -  PARTICIPANT 


Bushels 

Catastrophic 

produced  per 

Risk 

With  .5004 

With  No 

acre 

Protection 

Pro-rate 

Pro-rate 

0 

$32.18 

$19.44 

$38.86 

5 

$22.43 

$15.07 

$30.11 

10 

$12.68 

$10.69 

$21.36 

15 

$2.93 

$6.31 

$12.61 

20 

$1.93 

$3.86 

25 

30 

WHEAT  -  NONPARTICIPANT 


Bushels 
produced  per 
acre 

Catastrophic 

Risk 

Protection 

With  .5004 
Pro-rate 

With  No 
Pro-rate 

0 

$32.18 

$16.61 

$33.20 

5 

$22.43 

$12.42 

$24.82 

10 

$12.68 

$8.22 

$16.43 

15 

$2.93 

$4.03 

$8.05 

20 

25 

30 

ASSUMPTIONS: 

33  Bushel/ Acre  ASCS  yield  and  APH  yield 

MPCI  Market  price  of  $3.25 

Target  price  of  $4.00 

Loan  price  of  $2.58 

Flex  acres  calculated  at  65  %  of  target 


57 


Major  Points  of  the  Blueprint  for  Financial  Soundness 

The  Blueprint  for  Financial  Soundness  is  a  structured,  comprehensive  plan  to  achieve 
a  long-term  projected  loss  ratio  of  1.1  by  October  1995,  as  directed  by  the  Omnibus  Budget 
Reconciliation  Act  (OBRA)  of  1993.    FCIC  is  committed  to  achieving  this  goal  because  it  is 
good  public  policy.    A  financially  sound  program  is  essential  to  maintaining  public 
confidence  in  crop  insurance.    Sound  management  to  achieve  the  goal  will  promote  the  long- 
term  stability  of  the  program  and  help  maintain  the  financial  stability  of  American 
Agriculture.  The  1 . 1  loss-ratio  goal  recognizes  that  crop  insurance  differs  from  commercial 
insurance  because  it  also  serves  social  goals,  not  solely  the  business  objective  of  maximizing 
profit. 

The  major  initiatives  outlined  in  the  Blueprint  are  to: 

A.  Develop  More  Accurate  Insurance  Yields 

B.  Develop  a  Catastrophic  Yield  Adjustment 

C.  Implement  the  Group  Risk  Plan  (GRP) 

D.  Implement  a  Data  Base  of  Taxpayer  Identification  Numbers 

E.  Expand  the  Non-standard  Classification  System  (NCS) 

F.  Institute  Premium  Rate  Adjustments 

G.  Improve  Underwriting  of  Crop  Insurance  Contracts 
H.  Emphasize  Program  Compliance 

I.  Assure  that  Adequate  Risk  is  Borne  bv  the  Commercial  Insurance  Industry 

J.  Improve  Loss  Adjustment 

K.  Improve  Marketing 

L.  Expand  Participation  bv  Introducing  New  Products 

M.       Improve  Accuracy  of  Other  Program  Variables;   Unit  division,  Program  dates, 
Staged  guarantees,  De  minimus  yields,  Suspensions  and  debarment.  Price 
elections. 

An  in-depth  discussion  of  each  of  these  points,  is  contained  in  the  Blueprint  for 
Financial  Soundness  (available  from  USDA/FCIC). 


58 

BLUEPRINT  FOR  FINANCIAL  SOUNDNESS 

SCOPE  AND  PURPOSE 

The  Omnibus  Budget  Reconciliation  Act  of  1993  (OBRA  93)  contains  provisions  concerning 
the  Federal  crop  insurance  program.    These  provisions  direct  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Corporation  (FCIC)  to  take  steps  necessary  to  improve  actuarial  soundness  of  the  Federal 
crop  insurance  program  and  to  achieve,  by  the  fiscal  year  beginning  October  1,  1995,  a 
projected  overall  loss  ratio  not  to  exceed  1.10  (110  percent)  (section  1501  (a)). 

Projected  loss  ratio  (dollar  amount  of  losses  paid  as  a  percent  of  the  total  premiums 
collected)  is  intended  to  be  a  performance  standard,  not  an  absolute  ceiling  for  the  operations 
of  any  particular  crop  year.    Congress  recognizes  that  adverse  weather  conditions  (such  as 
extreme  drought  or  flood)  will  influence  the  financial  results  of  each  year's  operations; 
however,  when  good  and  poor  years  are  averaged  over  a  long  period  of  time  (such  as  50  to 
100  years),  the  expectation  must  be  that  the  program  will  operate  with  an  average  loss  ratio 
of  1.10  or  less.    A  period  of  time  at  least  this  long  is  needed  to  observe  a  range  of 
production  conditions  that  are  likely  to  be  encountered  by  farmers.    Short  time  periods,  such 
as  5  to  10  years,  may  encompass  several  favorable  or  unfavorable  years,  the  frequency  of 
which  is  atypical  of  the  longer  term.   This  is  a  primary  reason  that  the  risks  covered  by  the 
Federal  crop  insurance  program  cannot  be  fmanced  in  a  commercial  insurance  environment. 


OBRA  93  directed  FCIC  to  take  the  following  actions  to  achieve  this  required  improvement 
in  the  loss  ratio: 

•  Institute  rules  for  producers  to  demonstrate  actual  production  histories  in  establishing 
yields  for  Federal  crop  insurance  coverage  that  better  reflect  the  associated  actuarial  risks. 

•  Establish  in  appropriate  counties  an  optional  "area  yield"  or  "group  risk"  plan  that  allows 
producers  to  qualify  for  an  indemnity  if  a  loss  occurs  in  a  specified  area  in  which  the 
producer's  farm  is  located. 

•  Create  a  nationwide  database  to  track  producer  participation  using  social  security  account 
and  employer  identification  numbers.    Such  a  tracking  system  would  facilitate  better 
production  documentation,  high-risk  producer  identification,  and  assessment  of  insurance 
providers'  performance. 

•  Take  other  measures  authorized  by  law  to  improve  the  actuarial  soundness  of  the  Federal 
crop  insurance  program  while  maintaining  fair  and  effective  coverage  for  producers. 

FCIC  is  committed  to  achieving  these  actions  because  it  is  good  public  policy.    A  financially 
sound  program  is  essential  to  maintaining  public  confidence  in  crop  insurance.    Sound 
management  to  achieve  these  actions  will  promote  long-term  stability  of  the  program  and 

1 


59 


facilitate  the  overall  economic  stability  of  the  United  States  agricultural  sector.    Crop 
insurance  differs  from  commercial  insurance  because  it  serves  social  goals,  not  solely  the 
business  objective  of  maximizing  profit.    A  stable  crop  insurance  system  never  developed  in 
the  private  sector  without  government  support  because  of  the  unique  and  widespread  risks 
inherent  in  farming. 

Section  1501  (c)  (2)  further  directed  the  Department  to  issue  for  public  comment  a 
comprehensive  plan  or  "blueprint"  that  identifies,  among  other  things: 

•  Steps  FCIC  intends  to  take  to  achieve  a  projected  overall  loss  ratio  of  no  greater  than 
1.10  on  and  after  October  1,  1995. 

•  Additional  steps  if  further  action  is  required,  based  upon  actual  program  experience  or 
unforeseen  external  circumstances. 

•  Modifications  to  be  considered  if  initial  actions  to  improve  actuarial  soundness  work 
better  than  anticipated. 

•  Projections,  assumptions,  and  analyses  which  underlie  the  FCIC  conclusions  that  the 
above  actions  will  achieve  the  required  loss  ratio  within  the  stated  deadline  while 
maintaining  fairness  and  effective  coverage  to  agricultural  producers,  and  which 
thereby  demonstrate  FCIC's  compliance  with  the  performance  standard  identified  in 
section  1501  (a). 

This  document  proposes  a  draft  comprehensive  Blueprint  for  Financial  Soundness,  as 
required  by  OBRA  93  for  discussion  and  public  comment.   The  plan  has  been  developed  with 
the  guidance  of  various  persons  involved  with  crop  insurance  (producers,  insurers,  agents, 
academics,  and  others).   The  plan  will  be  modified  periodically  to  incorporate  resulting 
analyses  of  program  performance  and  the  recommendations  of  interested  parties  as  required 
by  OBRA  93. 

Actions  identified  herein  result  from  internal  analysis  by  FCIC  and  information  previously 
provided  to  FCIC  by  numerous  interested  parties.   These  include  the  Commission  for  the 
Improvement  of  Crop  Insurance  (a  Congressionally  established  work  group  in  1989  and 
1990),  various  crop  insurance  industry  organizations,  members  of  Congress,  agricultural 
producers,  crop  insurance  agents  and  insurance  companies,  the  General  Accounting  Office, 
and  others.   Information  was  not  solicited  specifically  for  this  draft  but  was  compiled  from 
previous  recommendations.    Not  all  of  the  specific  recommendations  made  by  any  or  all  of 
these  groups  are  included  herein.   This  document  establishes  initiatives  to  achieve  the  above 
actions. 

Estimates  of  the  financial  impact  of  an  action,  based  on  available  data  and  professional 
judgment,  are  provided  whenever  possible.    Readers  should  recognize  that  these  estimates  are 
fluid  due  to  the  nature  of  the  data  and  the  ever-changing  program.   In  particular,  since  FCIC 


81-128  0-94-3 


60 


does  not  have  a  single  aggregate  mathematical  or  statistical  model  that  describes  its 
programs,  estimates  of  financial  impact  are  based  on  partial  analysis  which  considers  the 
effect  of  one  particular  action  in  the  absence  of  any  other  action  or  initiative.    Also,  the  exact 
steps  to  be  taken  under  this  Blueprint  depend  in  part  upon  the  public  comment  and 
recommendations  received  before  investing  resources  in  detailed  studies  of  potential  impacts. 
Readers  are  encouraged  to  provide  information,  rationale,  and  where  possible,  estimates  of 
costs  or  potential  savings. 

In  some  cases  the  financial  impact  of  an  action  may  not  be  quantified.   This  does  not  mean 
the  action  is  not  important  or  that  it  cannot  contribute  to  achievement  of  the  goal.   For 
example,  enhanced  management  reporting  systems  do  not  produce  a  measurable  financial 
impact.  However,  such  systems  can  enhance  FCIC's  ability  to  estimate  the  potential  impacts 
of  program  changes  and  assure  that  ongoing  management  decisions  recognize  the  impact  of 
the  decision  on  future  actions. 

This  document  is  divided  into  four  main  sections,  which  describe:    (1)  crop  insurance 
program  to  provide  context  and  background;  (2)  actions  FCIC  proposes  as  part  of  this  plan  to 
achieve  the  target  loss  ratio;  (3)  additional  actions  that  FCIC  may  take  if  those  described  in 
Section  n  are  not  effective  or  that  cannot  be  implemented  due  to  unforeseen  circumstances; 
and  (4)  changes  FCIC  will  consider  once  the  projected  loss  ratio  achieves  the  targeted  level 
of  1.10. 


I.    BACKGROUND  OF  THE  CROP  INSURANCE  PROGRAM 

Overview  of  Program  Operations 

Crop  insurance  is  delivered  primarily  by  commercial  insurance  companies  that  have 
entered  into  a  cooperative  financial  arrangement  (the  Standard  Reinsurance  Agreement 
[SRA])  with  FCIC.   Under  this  arrangement,  the  company  agrees  to  deliver  an  FCIC 
designed  and  priced  product  to  eligible  buyers.   The  company  is  responsible  for  all 
aspects  of  customer  service,  and  guarantees  payment  of  the  insured  person's  share  of 
the  premium  to  FCIC.   In  return,  FCIC  reimburses  the  company  for  administrative 
expenses  and  requires  the  company  (on  a  state  basis)  to  share  in  insurance  experience 
whether  favorable  or  unfavorable.   FCIC  also  provides  stop  loss  reinsurance  that 
limits  the  maximum  loss  the  company  can  sustain. 

A  small  and  decreasing  portion  of  the  total  sales  is  managed  directly  by  FCIC  through 
sales  and  service  contractors.   These  contractors  agree  to  sell  an  FCIC  designed  and 
priced  product  and  to  perform  certain  servicing  functions  related  to  the  sale  (such  as 
determining  the  average  yields).   FCIC  reimburses  the  contractor  for  administrative 
expenses  associated  with  selling  and  servicing  the  product;  however,  FCIC  is  directly 
responsible  for  premium  collection,  loss  adjustment,  and  payment  of  losses.   These 
latter  functions  are  the  responsibility  of  the  reinsured  company  under  that  delivery 


61 


system.    FCIC  intends  to  eliminate  direct  sales  after  the  1994  crop  year  because  this 
system  now  delivers  less  than  10  percent  of  the  total  business,  and  maintaining  a 
nationwide  capability  for  delivery  at  an  acceptable  cost  is  difficult. 

The  crop  insurance  plan  for  most  crops  indemnifies  insured  persons  for  losses  in  yield 
exceeding  a  predetermined  threshold  amount.   To  establish  this  threshold  an  average 
yield  is  determined  based  on  the  individual's  production  history.    The  first  portion  of 
the  loss  (deductible  of  the  insurance),  equal  to  25,  35,  50,  or  65  percent  of  the 
average  yield,  must  be  sustained  by  the  insured  person.   These  are  the  choices  of 
deductibles  now  offered  by  FCIC,  and  typically  are  described  by  the  maximum  loss  in 
yield  covered  by  the  insurance;  e.g.,  75  percent  coverage,  65  percent,  etc.   The  50 
and  75  percent  coverage  levels  are  required  by  the  Act  to  be  available  to  all  persons. 
The  level  of  coverage  is  chosen  by  the  insured  individual. 

The  insured  person  also  must  choose  a  price  at  which  the  yield  is  valued  for  the 
purposes  of  computing  the  amount  of  premium  and  any  applicable  amount  of  loss;  this 
variable  is  called  the  price  election.    FCIC  must  offer  a  price  election  that  is  not  less 
than  the  anticipated  market  price  at  time  of  harvest.   This  determination  is  made  well 
before  the  possibility  of  loss  is  known  during  the  crop  year.    Otherwise,  insured 
persons  would  choose  low  price  elections  if  no  loss  is  sustained  (minimizes  premium 
payments)  the  highest  possible  price  election  if  a  loss  occurs  (maximizes  indemnities). 


FCIC  establishes  premium  rates  for  the  various  coverage  levels,  yields,  crop  types 
and  farming  practices  (e.g.,  irrigated)  for  each  county.     All  planted  acres  of  the  crop 
are  covered  by  the  insurance  policy  unless  for  some  reason  the  acreage  is  uninsurable. 
The  premium  owed  by  the  insured  person  is  determined  by  multiplying  the  average 
yield  per  acre  by  the  coverage  level,  multiplied  by  the  number  of  acres  planted,  the 
price  election,  and  the  premium  rate.    For  example,  if  the  average  yield  is  100 
bushels  per  acre,  the  coverage  level  is  65  percent,  planted  acres  are  50,  the  price 
election  is  $2.25,  and  the  premium  rate  is  5.2  percent,  the  premium  is  equal  to  1(X)  x 
0.65  X  50  x  $2.25  x  0.052,  or  $380.25.   The  potential  indemnity  in  the  event  of  a 
total  loss  is  $7,312.50  (determined  by  multiplying  the  average  yield,  coverage  level, 
planted  acres,  and  price  election). 

A  portion  of  the  total  premium  is  subsidized  to  encourage  participation  in  the 
program.    The  subsidy  is  30  percent  of  the  total  premium  for  coverage  levels  up  to 
and  including  the  65  percent  level.   The  subsidy  for  75  percent  level  of  coverage  is 
equal  to  the  dollar  junount  that  would  be  paid  at  the  65  percent  level  of  coverage. 
The  premium  subsidy  for  the  above  example  would  be  $114.08;  thus,  the  insured 
person  would  pay  $266.17.   The  same  $114.08  subsidy  would  be  paid  if  the  insured 
person  chose  the  75  percent  coverage  level. 


62 


In  the  event  of  a  loss,  the  amount  of  production  that  was  harvested,  or  that  was 
determined  should  have  been  harvested,  is  measured  by  the  insurer.    An  indemnity 
payment  is  made  if  the  determined  production  is  less  than  the  total  guarantee  for  the 
acreage  (yield  multiplied  by  coverage  level  and  acres  planted).   For  example,  if  the 
insured  person  harvests  1 ,000  bushels  from  25  acres  and  does  not  harvest  a  potential 
yield  of  10  bushels  per  acre  from  the  remaining  25  acres,  the  total  of  the 
production  to  count  is  1,250  bushels  (1,000  bushels  harvested  plus  25  acres  multiplied 
by  10  bushels).   This  is  subtracted  from  the  total  bushel  guarantee  for  the  acreage 
(100  X  0.65  X  50,  or  3,250  bushels),  resulting  in  a  loss  of  2,000  bushels.  The 
indemnity  is  equal  to  the  number  of  lost  bushels  multiplied  by  the  price  election.   For 
this  example,  the  indemnity  would  be  2,000  bushels  x  $2.25,  or  $4,500. 

Crop  insurance  does  not  guarantee  revenue.    As  the  above  example  illustrates,  it 
provides  an  insurance  indemnity  only  if  production  is  less  than  the  established 
guarantee.    No  protection  is  provided  if  the  market  price  is  less  than  the  price 
election. 

B.         Legislative  Background  and  Issues 

Federal  crop  insurance  was  established  as  a  pUot  program  in  the  I930's.   Prior  to 
1980,  crop  insurance  was  available  only  on  major  crops  in  major  producing  areas. 
The  coverage  level  often  was  limited  to  60  percent  or  less  of  a  long-term  average 
yield  for  an  area.    Congress  amended  the  Act  in  1980  to  expand  the  scope  and 
coverage  of  the  program  with  the  intent  that  it  be  the  sole  means  of  providing  public 
disaster  assistance  to  U.S.  farmers.    Participation  in  the  program  increased  after  the 
1980  amendments,  but  remains  below  levels  deemed  necessary  to  be  regarded  as  the 
principal  vehicle  for  disaster  assistance.    Insured  acreage  peaked  at  about  40-45 
percent  of  the  total  acreage  planted  to  insurable  crops  in  1988-89,  but  more 
commonly  has  been  in  the  30-35  percent  range.   Losses  also  increased  with  the 
expansion  of  the  program.   The  loss  ratio  has  exceeded  the  break-even  amount  of 
LOO  in  every  year  since  1980.    Cumulative  losses  for  the  years  1980-1992  were 
approximately  $2.9  billion,  with  a  cumulative  loss  ratio  of  about  1.45  for  the  13 
years. 

Program  participation  is  an  issue  influencing  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program. 
Full  participation  (i.e.,  100  percent  of  eligible  acres  insured)  is  the  measure  of 
program  success  that  is  accepted  (at  least  implicitly)  by  some  persons.   This  measure 
may  not  be  the  most  appropriate.   A  rational  decision  to  buy  insurance  of  any  kind 
must  be  based  on  the  magnitude  of  the  financial  difficulties  that  accompany  a  loss. 
For  example,  buying  collision  coverage  on  a  15-year  old  automobile  makes  little 
financial  sense.    Similarly,  buying  insurance  on  a  crop  that  contributes  only  a  small 
portion  of  the  expected  income  of  the  insured  person  may  not  make  financial  sense. 
Full  participation  in  the  crop  insurance  program  may  not  represent  an  efficient  use  of 
the  taxpayer's  resources.    However,  participation  must  be  high  enough  to  minimize  or 


63 


eliminate  perceived  needs  to  legislate  disaster  assistance  funded  under  dire  emergency 
provisions  of  the  Budget  Enforcement  Act.   The  level  of  participation  in  the  crop 
insurance  program  that  maximizes  returns  to  the  public  is  not  known,  and  is  an  area 
needing  further  definition. 

Many  losses  paid  in  the  1980's  and  early  1990's  were  due  to  widespread  disasters,  the 
adverse  financial  effects  of  which  Congress  intended  to  mitigate  under  the  Act. 
However,  continuing  loss  ratios  exceeding  100  percent,  enactment  of  disaster 
assistance  in  nearly  every  year  since  1988,  and  lower  than  desirable  participation 
indicate  that  the  public  policy  goals  of  the  program  have  not  been  fully  realized.    The 
Secretary  of  Agriculture  has  proposed  a  reform  of  the  crop  insurance  program  to: 

•  Achieve  actuarial  soundness. 

•  Increase  participation  to  levels  that  render  ad  hoc  disaster  legislation 
unnecessary. 

•  Eliminate  incentives  to  enact  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  legislation. 

The  proposals  contained  in  this  Blueprint  focus  on  these  three  areas  that  directly  relate 
to  the  goal  of  achieving  the  targeted  loss  ratio.    They  are:    (1)  actuarial  matters  such 
as  premium  rates  and  yield  guarantees,  (2)  underwriting  matters  such  as  terms  and 
conditions  of  insurance  policies,  and  (3)  management  issues  such  as  compliance  and 
risk-sharing  arrangements  with  commercial  insurers. 


n.   MANAGEMENT  ACTIONS  TO  ACHTEVE  A  LOSS  RATIO  OF  1.10 

A.        Develop  More  Accurate  Insurance  Yields 

The  insurance  yield  may  be  the  single  most  important  factor  in  determining  the 
success  or  failure  of  the  crop  insurance  program.    A  yield  that  is  too  high  compared 
to  the  productive  potential  of  the  person  or  land  will  increase  the  number  of  years  that 
a  loss  is  paid.   An  excessively  high  yield  also  increases  the  amount  paid  when  a  loss 
occurs.    A  yield  that  is  too  low  will  not  effectively  protect  fanners  from  loss  and, 
because  it  is  regarded  as  insufficient,  will  not  induce  desired  levels  of  participation. 

From  the  1985  through  1993  crop  years,  insured  yields  were  based  on  a  program 
called  the  Actual  Production  History  (APH)  Plan.   The  goal  of  this  program  was  to 
obtain  10  previous  yields  to  establish  the  insured  yield  for  the  next  crop  year.    Proxy 
yields  largely  based  on  ASCS  farm  program  payment  yields  or  county  averages  were 
allowed  whenever  farmers  would  not  or  could  not  provide  10  years  of  history. 
Analysis  by  FCIC  and  others  determined  the  proxy  yields  were  benefiting  farmers 
whose  yields  tended  to  be  lower  than  average  and  discouraging  fanners  whose  yields 


64 


tended  to  be  above  average.    Consequently,  a  modified  APH  program  that  reduced  the 
influence  of  the  proxy  yields  was  introduced  beginning  with  the  1994  crop  year;  thus, 
a  "ladder"  was  introduced  into  the  proxy  yields.    Only  65  percent  credit  is  given  to 
the  proxy  yield  if  no  actual  yields  are  reported,  80  percent  credit  is  given  if  one 
actual  yield  is  reported,  90  percent  if  two  actual  yields  are  reported,  and  100  percent 
if  three  actual  yields  are  reported.    The  proxy  yields  are  not  used  after  four  actual 
yields  are  available.   The  insured  yield  is  a  simple  average  of  the  4  years  of  actual 
and  modified  proxy  yields  for  the  first  4  years,  and  then  (after  4  years)  is  the  simple 
average  of  the  actual  yields  reported.    Acquiring  10  years  of  production  history 
remains  the  goal  of  the  program.   These  revised  procedures  are  the  core  of  the 
initiatives  to  comply  with  the  mandate  of  OBRA  93  to  institute  rules  to  demonstrate 
actual  production  histories. 

The  revised  rules  are  expected  to  substantially  reduce  losses  of  the  Federal  crop 
insurance  program.    Analysis  performed  by  FCIC  indicates  the  new  rules  would 
reduce  losses  by  15  percent  for  com,  22  percent  for  soybeans,  and  18  percent  for 
wheat.   These  analyses  were  based  on  simulations  of  loss  histories  using  the  rules  for 
the  two  computational  methods—the  previous  APH  and  the  proposed  modified-APH 
plans.   The  analyses  encompassed  nine  states  each  for  com  and  soybeans  and  three 
states  for  wheat.   These  states  and  crops  represented  nearly  60  percent  of  the  total 
premiums  eamed  in  1990.   The  results  indicated  that  the  modified-APH  rules  would 
reduce  losses  by  a  weighted  average  of  19  percent  and  are  believed  to  be 
representative  for  most  crops. 

The  actual  loss  ratio  for  the  1990  crop  year  was  1.23.   If  the  modified  APH  rules  did 
reduce  losses  by  an  average  of  19  percent,  the  loss  ratio  would  have  been  0.996. 
This  would  achieve  significant  compliance  with  the  loss  ratio  target  of  1.10. 

Based  on  these  results,  FCIC  implemented  modified-APH  for  the  1994  crop  year  by: 

•  Promulgating  regulations  for  the  program  during  calendar  year  1994. 

•  Measuring  the  impact  of  the  modifications  upon  net  program  losses  by  calculating 
insured  yields,  premiums,  and  indemnities  of  policyholders  under  1993  and  1994 
rules. 

•  Where  possible,  determining  whether  the  modified  APH  rules  had  the 
intended  effect  of  providing  a  more  accurate  offer  for  farmers  who 
previously  elected  not  to  purchase  crop  insurance. 

•  Determining  whether  the  average  number  of  yields  reported  for  prior  years 
has  changed  under  the  modified  APH  rules  compared  with  APH  rules  for 
1990  through  1993. 


65 


•  Implementing  a  tracking  system  to  assure  that  insurance  experience  remains 
associated  with  a  person  in  future  years  (see  item  D  below). 

•  Developing  reporting  processes  to  assure  that  the  accuracy  of  yield 
determinations  is  continuously  monitored  and  improved. 

•  Actions  requiring  analysis  of  the  effects  of  the  modified  APH  rules  upon  the 
accuracy  of  insured  yields  cannot  be  completed  until  losses  from  the  1994  crop  year 
are  processed.    For  wheat  and  other  fall  planted  crops,  such  availability  will  occur 
by  about  the  fourth  calendar  quarter  of  1994.    For  spring  planted  crops,  this  does 
not  occur  until  about  the  middle  of  the  first  calendar  quarter  of  1995. 

B.  Catastrophic  Yield  Adjustment 

FCIC  recognizes  that  the  average  of  a  series  of  observations  as  short  as  4  years  is 
subject  to  significant  variations  due  to  abnormally  large  or  small  yields  during  that  time. 
For  example,  if  a  major  disaster  year  such  as  1993  is  included  in  the  4  years,  the 
procedure  implicitly  states  that  a  similar  year  will  occur  once  every  4  years.   This  is  not 
likely.   Thus,  FCIC  will  examine  certain  adjustments  to  the  modified-APH  rules  with  a 
goal  to  assign  more  appropriate  probabilities  to  the  individual  observations.   These 
adjustments  commonly  are  called  catastrophic  yield  adjustments.    However,  just  as  the 
yields  for  1  year  may  be  abnormally  low,  they  also  may  be  abnormally  high.   Capping 
the  abnormally  high  years  may  also  be  appropriate  so  that  average  yields  are  not 
excessively  high  due  solely  to  a  few  observations. 

FCIC  will  evaluate  alternative  methods  to  recognize  catastrophic  and  unusually  good 
crop  years,  and  consider  implementing  appropriate  adjustments  to  the  modified-APH 
plan  effective  for  the  1995  crop  year. 

FCIC  believes  that  these  actions  to  implement  modified-APH  will  reduce  the  average 
loss  ratio  over  time  by  10-15  percentage  points  (e.g.,  from  an  average  of  1.40  for 
several  years  to  1.25  to  1.30).   This  estimate  is  based  on  a  conservative  expectation  of 
the  actual  results  of  the  simulations  described  above. 

C.  Implement  Group  Risk  Plan 

FCIC  is  implementing  a  program  of  insurance  that  is  based  on  the  average  yield  of  an 
area,  not  upon  individual  yield  coverage  as  is  offered  under  the  traditional  APH 
program.   The  area  coverage  is  called  the  Group  Risk  Plan  (GRP)  by  FCIC.   GRP  was 
introduced  as  a  pilot  program  for  the  1993  crop  year  for  soybeans  in  96  counties.    It  was 
expanded  for  the  1994  crop  year  to  include  seven  additional  crops  encompassing  1,872 
county  crop  programs  (one  crop  in  one  county)  in  27  states.    Crops  now  included  under 
GRP  are  barley  (three  states),  com  (17  states),   cotton  (seven  states),  forage  (two 


66 


states),  grain  sorghum  (four  states),  peanuts  (four  states),  soybeans  (24  states),  and 
wheat  (eight  states). 

The  GRP  is  intended  to  protect  the  insured  person  against  the  financial  consequences  of 
a  disaster  that  strikes  all  or  nearly  all  fanners  in  an  area.    It  sets  an  expected  county 
yield  for  each  year  based  on  historical  yields,  adjusted  for  any  trends.    Whenever  the 
actual  county  average  yield  for  the  year  is  less  than  the  expected  county  yield  by  a 
predetermined  amount,  an  indemnity  is  paid.   The  principal  differences  of  the  GRP 
compared  to  traditional  individual  coverage  are: 

•  Coverage  is  based  on  a  trend  projected  yield,  which  probably  will  exceed  the 
average  yield  of  all  farmers  insured  under  individual  yield  coverage  if  there 
is  a  positive  trend  in  yields  for  the  area. 

•  Higher  coverage  levels  (deductibles  are  as  low  as  10  percent)  at  affordable  premium 
rates  can  be  sold. 

Thus,  in  the  proper  circumstances,  GRP  will  offer  risk  protection  that  may  be  better 
than  the  individual  coverage,  and  may  do  so  at  a  lower  cost. 

GRP  has  characteristics  that  make  it  unsuitable  for  managing  the  adverse  financial 
consequences  of  crop  loss  in  certain  circumstances.    A  fanner's  yield  each  year  must 
change  in  the  same  direction  and  by  about  the  same  amount  as  the  county  yield  if  it  is  to 
be  fully  effective  coverage  for  the  individual.    For  example,  if  the  county's  yield 
decreases  by  25  percent  from  the  expected  yield  for  that  year,  the  fanner's  yield  also 
should  decline  by  about  25  percent  from  the  yield  he  or  she  would  have  expected.    In 
financial  market  terms,  the  "beta"  of  the  fanner's  yields  and  the  county  yields  should  be 
near  l.(X). 

Adequate  data  are  a  limitation  to  further  significant  expansion  of  GRP.   The  concept  as 
presently  developed  uses  many  years  (30  or  more)  of  county  yields.   These  data  are 
routinely  available  only  for  counties  in  which  the  crop  has  been  grown  in  commercially 
significant  quantities.   Weather  data  and  crop  growth  models  may  permit  expansion  into 
counties  in  which  the  historical  yield  data  are  not  available,  but  research  is  needed  to 
develop  and  test  these  approaches.    Further,  acceptance  of  GRP  by  bankers  as  collateral 
for  loans  is  yet  to  be  determined. 

Significant  expansion  of  GRP  is  not  anticipated  until  its  contributions  to  agricultural  risk 
management  can  be  measured.    No  estimates  of  savings  can  be  attributed  to  GRP 
because  customer  acceptance  is  not  known.    Customer  acceptance  of  the  soybean  GRP 
for  the  1993  crop  year  was  limited.   Fewer  than  500  policies  (of  nearly  700, 0(X)  total  for 
the  crop  insurance  program)  were  sold.   Even  if  the  plan  improves  the  actuarial 
soundness  of  crop  insurance,  the  present  volume  of  business  is  not  sufficient  to  make 
any  noticeable  difference  in  program  results. 


67 


D.    Tmplement  Pata  Rase  of  Taxpayer  Idpntifiration  Number? 

Amendments  to  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  enacted  in  1990  authorize  FCIC  to 
collect  and  use  social  security  numbers  and  employer  identification  numbers  to 
administer  its  programs.   These  regulations  were  appropriately  approved  and  were 
published  in  the  Fe/leral  Register  in  late  1992.   OBRA  93  further  directed  FCIC  to 
implement  a  database  of  these  numbers  for  certain  uses  not  later  than  the  1995  crop 
year. 

FCIC  implemented  the  database  described  above  in  January  1994,  effective  for  the  1994 
crop  year.   This  database  is  used  to  locate  production  history  that  is  not  reported  by  a 
person,  to  assure  that  classifications  assigned  under  the  nonstandard  classification  system 
(NCS  -  see  paragraph  E  below)  are  used  for  both  the  individual  who  accumulated  the 
adverse  history  and  any  person  having  a  significant  beneficial  interest  in  a  crop  produced 
by  that  person,  and  for  other  related  purposes.    In  particular,  further  efforts  will  be 
made  to  accumulate  information  about  persons  involved  in  sales  and  servicing  of  crop 
insurance-agents,  loss  adjusters,  and  other  insurance  providers--so  that  their 
contributions  to  achieving  the  target  loss  ratio  can  be  measured. 

Implementing  this  database  will  make  both  modified-APH  and  the  NCS  more  effective 
by  permitting  FCIC  and  reinsured  companies  to  assure  that  all  appropriate  experience 
and  premium  rating  factors  are  used.   Incremental  improvement  in  the  loss  ratio  due  to 
modified-APH  and  NCS  is  difficult  to  quantify.   The  database  will  enhance  those 
programs  as  weU  as  permit  FCIC  to  systematically  measure  the  performance  of 
insurance  providers  for  the  first  time. 

FCIC  will  also  use  the  social  security  numbers  and  employer  identification  numbers  for 
the  implementation  of  an  Ineligible  FUe  Tracking  System.   This  system  will  be  used  to 
restrict  (through  an  automated  environment)  producers  who  have  been  declared  ineligible 
to  obtain  benefits  provided  by  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program.   The  FCIC  expects 
to  implement  the  Ineligible  File  Tracking  System  beginning  with  the  1995  fiscal  year. 

E.    Expand  the  Nonstandard  Classification  System  (NCS) 

FCIC  instituted  the  NCS  for  the  1990  crop  year  because  evidence  indicated  that  a  small 
percentage  of  insured  persons  had  losses  in  nearly  every  year.   The  losses  paid  to  these 
persons  far  exceeded  paid  premiums.   For  various  reasons,  the  insured  yields  for  these 
individuals  exceeded  their  apparent  capabilities,  and  the  premium  rates  were  not 
representative  of  the  risks  posed  by  these  persons.    NCS  was  intended  to  reduce  the 
insurance  guarantee  and  increase  the  premium  rate  for  such  individuals.   Modified- APH 
eUminates  the  need  to  reduce  insured  yields  because  the  insured  yield  will  be  based 

10 


68 


solely  on  actual  yields  when  a  person  is  selected  for  NCS.   However,  NCS  will  continue 
to  increase  the  premium  rates  as  appropriate  for  those  individuals  who  persistently  have 

The  Agriculture,  Rural  Development,  Food  and  Drug,  and  Related  Agencies 
Appropnation  Act  for  the  1994  fiscal  year  prohibited  FCIC  from  using  any  funds 
appropnated  to  insure  crops  in  certain  counties  unless  an  NCS  program  had  been 
implemented  in  those  counties.    Counties  were  affected  if  the  loss  ratio,  after  applvine 
the  1993  premium  rates,  was  greater  than  1.10  more  than  70  percent  of  the  years  that 
the  crop  had  been  msured  in  that  county.    Approximately  2,100  county  crop  programs 
were  affected  by  this  provision.  j       f  f    a       ^ 

For  the  1994  crop  year,  NCS  has  been  extended  to  11  crops  encompassing  over  90 
percent  of  the  total  value  of  insurance  in  force.    Additionally,  all  of  the  county  crop 
programs  affected  by  the  Appropriations  language  have  been  included  under  the  NCS 
Over  25,000  individuals  (about  3.6  percent  of  all  active  policies  for  the  1993  crop  year) 
were  included  under  this  program.   Not  all  of  these  persons  had  been  insured  during  the 
base  penod.    NCS  also  extends  to  persons  who  participated  in  growing  the  crop  in  some 
way  but  who  may  not  have  been  insured.   These  persons  also  are  classified  under  NCS 
so  that  the  acreage  cannot  simply  be  insured  under  a  different  name  to  avoid  the  NCS 
classification. 

In  1993   FCIC  commissioned  a  study  of  the  NCS  to  determine  its  effectiveness.   A  draft 
report  of  that  study  indicates  that  the  NCS  reduced  the  loss  ratio  by  5  to  10  points    This 
report  is  undergoing  final  preparation  as  this  Blueprint  for  Financial  Soundness  is 
finalized. 

^^}^.^^  f  u^^**  *^  ^^  ^'°^"^  ^°'  ^^  ^995  crop  year.    All  eligible  crops  wiU  be 
included,  although  greater  flexibility  in  selections  may  be  authorized  whenever  program 
factors  that  led  to  poor  experience  have  been  identified.   NCS  is  not  suited  to  certain 
insured  crops  (e.g.,  Texas  citrus  trees)  that  are  subject  to  infrequent  losses  of  great 
seventy.     The  additional  savings  from  NCS  are  Ukely  to  be  small  in  terms  of  the  total 
business  because  the  crops  that  constitute  the  majority  of  premiums  and  losses  already 
are  mcluded.  ^ 

F-     Institute  Premium  Rate  Adjustments 

Premium  rates  are  essential  to  the  success  of  the  crop  insurance  program.   Rates  that  are 
too  low  will  not  produce  adequate  income  and  will  lead  to  persistent  losses.   High  rates 
will,  paradoxically,  likely  lead  to  the  same  outcome.   Excessive  premium  rates 
discourage  participation  by  a  broadly  based  cross-section  of  the  farming  community. 
Instead,  persons  who  are  most  likely  to  collect  indemnities  will  buy,  and  it  is  not  likely 
that  rates  can  be  increased  as  rapidly  as  the  relative  risk  of  the  pool  of  insured  persons 
increases. 


11 


69 


FCIC  has  increased  premium  rates  for  all  crops  in  a  systematic  fashion  beginning  with 
the  1991  crop  year.    Rates  have  increased  as  much  as  70  percent  for  some  crops  in  some 
counties  from  the  1991  to  the  1994  crop  years.    Decreases  of  up  to  20  percent  have  been 
made  for  some  crops  in  counties  with  histories  of  low  losses.    By  an  amendment  to  the 
Act  in  1990,  Congress  limited  general  premium  rate  increases  to  20  percent  annually. 

The  above  statistics  indicate  the  amounts  that  FCIC  has  increased  the  base  premium 
rates.   The  average  premium  rate  actually  earned  (actual  premium  paid  divided  by  actual 
liability)  may  not  have  increased  by  the  same  magnitude  for  various  reasons.    Most 
importantly,  insured  persons  may  choose  a  lower  coverage  level  when  the  rate  increases. 
By  doing  so,  they  accept  a  lesser  degree  of  protection  but  also  pay  a  lower  premium 
rate. 

FCIC  proposes  to  continue  premium  rate  increases  as  needed  to  help  achieve  the 
required  loss  ratio.   The  rate  increases  made  during  1991-1994  have  done  much  to 
enhance  the  actuarial  soundness  of  the  program.    However,  the  premium  rates  for  some 
crops  and  areas  of  the  country  remain  below  the  levels  needed  to  achieve  the  overall 
1.10  loss  ratio  target. 

The  impact  of  premium  rate  adjustments  has  been  evaluated  by  using  data  for  the  20 
years  from  1973-1992.   The  effectiveness  of  the  adjustments  was  measured  by  applying 
the  current  1993  premium  rate  levels  to  the  historical  period  from  1973  and  all 
subsequent  years.    The  loss  ratios  were  recalculated  by  using  the  revised  premium 
amounts. 

This  method  does  not  include  any  change  in  sales  that  may  occur  due  to  a  higher  or 
lower  cost  of  insurance.    It  assumes  the  20-year  base  period  is  adequate  to  measure 
actuarial  performance,  an  assumption  that  may  not  be  the  most  appropriate  definition  of 
actuarial  soundness.    Events  such  as  a  1993  Midwestern  flood  may  or  may  not  be 
appropriate  to  include  in  the  20-year  base  period  for  a  particular  area  of  the  country. 

In  1993,  seven  crops  (barley,  com,  cotton,  grain  sorghum,  oats,  soybeans,  and  wheat) 
constituted  75  percent  of  total  premiums.   The  loss  ratio  for  1980-1992  for  these  seven 
crops  was  1.45,  identical  to  the  loss  ratio  for  all  insured  crops  for  this  same  period. 
Thus,  changes  in  premium  rates  for  these  crops  should  be  representative  of  the  changes 
that  have  been  made  for  all  crops  in  recent  years.   The  premium  rate  changes  for  the 
seven  crops  through  the  1994  crop  year  are  estimated  to  have  been  adequate  to  reduce 
the  1980-1992  loss  ratio  from  1.45  to  1.08.   This  aggregate  result  meets  the  1.10 
standard  required  by  OBRA  93,  but  only  two  of  the  seven  crops  individually  meet  this 
standard.   Within  each  of  these  crops,  many  parts  of  the  country  will  meet  the  standard 
but  others  will  not.   Hence,  additional  rate  changes  in  1995  and  later  years  are 
appropriate. 


12 


70 


FCIC  recognizes  that  premium  rate  increases  are  an  important  component  of  a  viable 
crop  insurance  program.    It  is  also  recognized  that  increasing  premium  rates  to  the  levels 
suggested  by  the  most  recent  20  year  experience  may  not  be  good  public  policy. 
Extremely  high  premium  rates  wall  preclude  realization  of  the  social  benefits  and  public 
policy  goals  of  the  program  because  participation  will  be  discouraged.   If  this  happens, 
experience  indicates  that  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  will  be  enacted.   Such  assistance  is' 
less  likely  to  satisfy  social  objectives  with  regard  to  maintaining  rural  communities  and 
adequate  supplies  of  food  and  fiber  because  it  is  uncertain  for  any  particular  year  or 
region  of  the  country.   Thus,  a  catastrophic  adjustment  process  may  be  needed  to  temper 
the  influence  of  a  year  such  as  1993.   If  the  weather  of  1993  truly  is  a  1  in  100  year 
event  (or,  as  some  have  suggested,  a  I  in  500  year  event),  its  influence  should  be 
tempered  in  terms  of  the  premium  rates  charged  to  insured  persons. 

In  addition  to  changing  premium  rates  as  needed,  FCIC  proposes  to  take  a  number  of 
additional  actions  to  enhance  the  accuracy  and  adequacy  of  its  actuarial  activities.   These 
include: 

•  Develop  computer  software  and  other  tools  to  enhance  the  quality  of  the  data  used 
to  establish  premium  rates  and  perform  actuarial  analyses  ("STATPLAN"  database, 
due  for  completion  in  October  1994) 

•  Plans  to  contract  with  a  major  actuarial  consulting  firm  to  review  all  aspects  of 
FCIC's  actuarial  methods  (targeted  to  be  let  in  1994). 

•  Enhance  staff  skills  by  additional  training  in  analytical  methods  for  existing 
personnel  and  more  emphasis  on  recruitment  of  actuarial  trainees  (ongoing)  for 
appropriate  functional  units. 

•  Continue  to  contract  with  external  specialists  such  as  the  Economic  Research 
Service,  land  grant  universities,  the  Cooperative  Extension  Service,  and  others 
(ongoing). 

•  Develop  models  to  measure  sources  of  change  in  premium  volumes  and  track  the 
effects  of  premium  rate  changes  as  isolated  from  changes  induced  by  factors  such  as 
price  elections,  coverage  level  choices,  insured  crops,  and  other  factors  that  are  not 
controllable  by  the  rate-making  function  (development  to  begin  immediately). 

G.    Improve  Underwriting  of  Crop  Insurance  Contracts 

Underwriting  begins  by  establishing  the  basic  terms  and  conditions  of  the  coverage. 
These  include  defining  conditions  that  result  in  a  covered  loss,  measuring  the  amount  of 
that  loss,  and  defining  the  responsibilities  of  the  insured  and  the  insurer.    Underwriting 
continues  with  proper  classification  of  an  insured  risk.   For  example,  planting  crop  B  the 
year  after  crop  A  was  grown  on  the  same  acreage  may  be  riskier  than  if  other  crops 

13 


71 

were  grown  the  previous  year.    Some  land,  such  as  flood  plains,  is  more  prone  to 
losses     Quality  of  management  also  is  important.    A  farmer  who  is  organized,  plans, 
I^rforms  preventive  maintenance  on  equipment,  and  performs  field  operations  m  a 
timely  manner  may  minimize  losses. 

A  comprehensive  underwriting  system  requires  effective  risk  "^f  ^g^."^^"\^^^'^£"  ^'^ 
2oals   standards   and  documentation.   Initiatives  to  improve  underwnung  that  began  in 
^^ceL^^im'sZl  be  continued  as  part  of  the  strategy  detailed  in  this  Bluepnnt.   The 
following  specific  actions  will  be  pursued: 

.      Fully  automate  the  actuarial  documents  to  faciUtate  more  comprehensive 
underv'riting  at  the  point  of  sale  and  to  verify  the  classificauon  of  nsk  m  an 
automated  environment  (completed  by  the  1996  crop  year). 

.      Develop  standards  and  classification  systems  to  assess  and  classify  individual  risk 
including  completion  of  research  intended  to  develop  a  "sconng  model    for  nsk  that 
is  based  on  measurable  attributes  of  a- person  or  situation  similar  to  a  credit  rating 
model  (for  implementation  by  crop  year  1996  if  this  model  is  feasible). 

.      Continue  to  rewrite  crop  insurance  policies  to  better  describe  the  insurance  coverage 
and  limitations  and  to  reduce  vulnerabilities  to  actuarial  soundness  that  exist  due  to 
imprecise,  unclear,  or  omitted  terms  and  conditions  (ongomg.  with  major  crops 
scheduled  for  the  1995  crop  year). 

.      Encourage  development  of  supplemental  or  alternative  insurance  coverages 
authorized  by  section  508(b)  of  the  Act  so  that  coverage  may  be  improved  with 
most  of  the  risk  remaining  in  the  commercial  sector. 

Improved  underwriting  will  improve  program  performance.   However  meaningful 
misures  to  quantify  possible  benefits  are  not  readily  available.   For  this  reason.  FCIC 
camiot  attribute  a  specific  dollar  amount  to  the  benefits  of  improved  actuanal  systems 
and  crop  insurance  policies. 

H.    Fmphasize  Program  Compliance 

The  FCIC  Compliance  function  is  designed  to  confirm  that  the  Federal  crop  insurance 
program  is  opeiated  and  delivered  as  intended.   Through  internal  reviews  based  on 
generally  accepted  auditing  principles,  it  assures  that  program  controls  are  in  p  ace 
against  excess  losses  due  to  waste,  fraud  and  abuse.   Compliance  emphasis  will  focus 
on: 

1      Program  DeUvery.   Beginning  in  1987,  the  Compliance  staff  conducted   reviews  of 
program  delivery  to  assess  compliance  with  regulations,  policy,  and  procedure. 

14 


72 


That  year,  according  to  GAO  and  OIG  audits,  errors  in  claims  payment  represented 

Smce  that  time  Comphance  efforts  have  reduced  these  errors  to  approximately 
5  percent  of  indemmties  but  still  need  continued  improvement.   Losses  due  to  claim 
payment  errors  are  not  mcluded  in  underwriting  calculations  of  risk  so  this 
reduction  in  excess  losses  has  a  direct  and  immediate  impact  of  lowering  the 
program  loss  ratio  without  increasing  program  cost  or  premium  rates. 

To  further  reduce  claims  overpayment  the  Compliance  Staff  will  review  the  entire 
operaaons  of  each  delivery  company  in  coordinated  nationwide  reviews    The 
review  methodology  was  recently  revised  to  reflect  generally  accepted  auditing 
pnnciples  and  statistically  projectable  sampling  techniques. 

Beginning  with  the  1995  crop  year,  Compliance  requirements  will  be  expanded  to 
define  specific  quality  control  and  performance  measurement  processes  for  each 
deliveiT  company.   Policy  service  error  rates  will  be  monitored.  The  performance 
of  each  company  will  then  be  compared  to  an  established  national  standard. 

Program  Performance.    Compliance  reviews  for  several  years  have  shown  that  a 
propoition  of  the  excess  losses  are  attributable  to  features  in  program  construction 
that  produce  unmtended  results.  The  Compliance  Staff  will  conduct  progrT 
performance  reviews  that  assess  regulations,  policies  and  procedures  designed  to 
prevent  waste,  fraud,  and  abuse  and  that  the  program,  poUcies,  and  proc^ures 
periorm  as  intended. 

As  ^example,  in  1989  GAO  claims  that  construction  of  policy  language  in  the 
?otl°    Tt  f.      r"  ^K?^"""!  "^""^  '""^^^  '"  approximately  $20  miUion  in  excess 
o  ,  n  nJnH  H  ?  ^'''^^%'°  ''^'^™'"«  ^^"^  '""ch  of  FCIC  losses  may  be  attributable 
to  unintended  features  of  program  construction.   However,  recent  program 
performance  pilot  reviews  of  the  peanut  program  and  regional  irrigated  practices 
resulted  m  an  estimated  4  to  10  percent  reduction  in  losses  for  those  areSs  that  may 
otherwise  have  gone  undetected.  ^ 

For  the  past  several  years  Compliance  has  conducted  ad  hoc  program  reviews  on 
topical  issues.  These  reviews  will  be  expanded  to  identify  and  target  reviews  for 
crop  msurance  programs  with  the  greatest  potential  vulnerabiUty. 

Fraud  Prevention.  The  risk  of  fraud  is  particularly  acute  in  the  insurance  industry 
tstimates  for  property-casualty  insurance  indicate  insurance  fraud  may  represent  as 
much  as  15  percent  of  all  losses  paid.  Recent  efforts  at  crop  insurance  fraud 
detecuon  and  subsequent  prosecution  have  been  increasingly  successful.    However 
atter-the-fact  controls  on  program  abuse  are  not  fully  effective.  Compliance  will    ' 
work  with  the  delivery  companies  to  focus  on  practical,  cost  efficient  fraud 
prevention.    Compliance  operations,  program  performance,  and  complaint  reviews 


15 


73 


will  emphasize  identifying  systemic  vulnerabilities  and  assessing  program 
safeguards.    Discrepancies  noted  in  review  findings  will  be  evaluated  to  determme 
the  underlying  causes. 

Emphasis  also  will  be  placed  on  measures  to  control  program  abuse  that  include 
strict  contract  enforcement  and  pro-active  policy  analyses  that  identifies  potenual 
abuse  and  targets  additional  claims  review.   These  measures  will  be  coupled  with 
the  aggressive  implementation  of  civil  sanctions,  agent/loss  adjuster  debarment,  and 
designating  producer  ineligibility  in  findings  related  to  program  abuse. 

I,      A«:«nire  that  AHpquate  Risk  is  Rome  bv  the  Commprcial  Insurance  Industry 

Amendments  to  the  Act  in  1990  directed  FCIC  to  assure  that  adequate  risk  is  borne  by 
the  commercial  insurance  companies  reinsured  by  FCIC,  consistent  with  their  ability  to 
bear  risk  and  the  availability  of  commercial  reinsurance.    For  the  1992  reinsurance  year 
(a  12  month  period  that  began  on  July  1,  1991  and  ended  on  June  30,  1992),  FCIC 
substantially  modified  its  Standard.  Reinsurance  Agreement  (SRA)  with  the  commercial 
insurers  which  participate  in  the  program.   Both  the  amount  and  the  probabiUty  of  losses 
on  the  part  of  the  commercial  insurers  were  increased  in  this  agreement.    Additional 
incremental  changes  in  the  amount  of  potential  gains  and  losses  were  made  for  both  the 
1993  and  1994  SRA's. 

The  GAO  suggests  in  a  report  entitled  Crop  Insurance  Program  Has  Not  Fostered 
■Sipnificant  Risk  .Sharing  hv  In^.irance  Companies  (GAO/RCED  92-25,  January  13, 
1992)  that  the  changes  in  the    1992  SRA  are  not  significant  enough  in  the  area  of  nsk 
bearing  by  the  commercial  insurance  companies.   Still,  the  1992  SRA  fundamentally 
changed  the  manner  in  which  gains  and  losses  are  calculated,  a  subUe  but  effective 
measure  to  increase  risk.   The  amount  of  potential  loss  increased,  but  the  change  in  the 
formula  increased  the  chances  that  the  company  would  lose  in  years  of  poor  expenence. 
As  a  comparison,  the  commercial  industry  lost  approximately  $8  million  in  1988  when 
the  crop  insurance  program  sustained  a  loss  ratio  of  2.45  primarily  due  to  drought  in 
the  Midwest.   If  that  experience  is  restated  to  the  larger  1993  premium  amounts,  the  loss 
still  would  have  amounted  to  only  about  SlO-15  miUion.   Results  from  the  1993  crop 
year  are  not  yet  complete,  but  current  esUmates  indicate  that  commercial  insurers  will 
sustain  losses  of  $80-85  million  although  the  loss  ratio  will  be  less  than  m  1988.   The 
difference  is  caused  by  the  SRA  changes. 

Some  will  argue  that  industry-wide  losses  of  $80-85   million  are  not  significant 
compared  to  overall  program  losses  that  may  be  near  $900  million  in  1993.   Two  factors 
bear  on  this  issue:  (1)  The  ability  of  the  insurance  companies  to  earn  reserves  under  the 
SRA,  and  (2)  The  effect  of  losses  upon  an  insurance  company's  operations  in  future 
years. 


16 


74 


The  commercial  industry  can  bear  a  greater  share  of  the  losses  only  if  there  is 
correspondmg  opportunity  to  achieve  comparable  earnings  in  favorable  years     Over  the 

U  wouw'mat  l^'"'^-  '""^^  '^''""^  a  satisfactory  rate  of  return  on  invested'capital.  or 
It  would  make  economic  sense  for  participants  to  invest  in  other  endeavors    The  SRA 
must  allow  adequate  opportunity  to  earn  this  satisfactory  rate  of  return.   It 'also  mus^ 
permit  accumulation  of  reserves  to  pay  losses  in  years  Lt  disasters  strike    Und^  tie 
present  SRA  and  the  conditions  of  actuarial  soundness  of  the  prograi^TereVs  no 
opportunity  to  accumulate  the  reserves  needed  to  bear  a  large'porton  ^f  a  $9^)  milUon 

Losses  directly  impact  the  capital  structure  of  the  companies.   An  insurance  comoanv 
leverages  Its  capital  (the  term  "surplus"  is  used  by  the  industry)  to  suZrt  the  Xme  of 
business  that  it  writes.    As  a  general  rule,  an  insurance  com^ny  is  Stted  by 
regulators  to  bear  the  risk  associated  with  $2  to  $3  of  premium  per  sTof  su^lus    The 
muo  of  premiums  to  surplus  may  be  lower  for  risky  lines  of  insurance  such  Z  multiple 

Soit^TT.'Tf  •    ^"^'^'^^"^^^^^^"^"rance  company  loses  a  portion  of  its    "^ 
capital,  Its  abihty  to  accept  premiums  in  future  years  is  reduced  by  a  greater  amount 
which  in  turn  reduces  its  ability  to  earn  profits  and  reserves..  Thi  ffcto  s  muTbe 

the  Ac?  ''"'^  °'  "'^  "'"'^  ^°  '^  "^'^ ''  ^^^-»«'>  ^  i^  -rdatol  by 

As  appropriate  given  the  factors  discussed  above,  FCIC  wiU  evaluate  (1)  the  need  to 
increase  nsk  shanng  with  the  commercial  insurance  industry  as  the  progim  achkvls 
greater  actuanal  soundness.  (2)  reducing  cessions  to  the  assigned  risk  funTby  ra.uTnng 

Trovfs  oTof  th??^"  i^r,:^  ^- -^-;^^'  -- d  5  A  (3)  changing  LZ^loss 
^h^rrr^  ^-         ^^  ^ecruiting  additional  commercial  insurers  to  participate  in 

h!  fooVr^K'^  ''?'""'•   "^"^  ^^^Ses  will  be  made  incrementally  beginning  wSi 
the  1995  SRA  that  takes  effect  on  July  1,  1994.  ^  i^cguining  wim 

^'     Improve  Loss  Ad|ii«rtmpnf 

Any  actuarial  and  underwriting  system  can  be  affected  by  errors  in  adjustment  of  losses 
The^  errors  include  both  overpayment  and  underpayment  of  claims.    Underpaymen 
would  not  seem  to  be  a  factor  influencing  actuarial  soundness,  but  failure  to^ay  a  Is 
when  due  wiU  cause  insured  persons  to  question  the  value  of  the  insurance  and 
potentially  reduce  participation.   The  insurance  experience  also  will  not  accurately  depict 
the  nature  of  the  nsk  insured,  leading  to  inaccuracies  in  future  premium  rates. 

Some  problems  in  loss  adjustment  are  directly  related  to  deficiencies  in  underwriting 
For  example,  if  the  crop  insurance  policy  is  not  clear  on  a  particular  point,  the  loss 
adjuster  may  find  it  necessary  to  make  a  determination  in  favor  of  the  insured  person. 
FCIC  will  undertake  the  following  initiatives  to  assure  high  quality  of  loss  adju^ment 
determmations  so  that  results  are  fair  to  insured  persons  and  taxpayers- 


17 


75 


•  Develop  uniform  loss  adjustment  standards  that  clearly  specify  the  requirements  for 
accurate  determinations. 

•  Continue  research  to  improve  loss  adjustment  methods,  such  as  yield  appraisal 
methods  and  techniques  for  unharvested  crops,  and  measurement  techniques  for 
stored  production. 

•  Strengthen  the  quality  adjustment  provisions  of  crop  insurance  contracts  and  develop 
standards  to  prevent  abuse  of  production  determinations  when  quality  losses  are 
claimed. 

The  contributions  of  these  factors  to  achieve  the  1.10  target  loss  ratio  will  be  measured 
by  a  reduction  in  improper  amounts  paid  on  claims  and  a  reduced  error  rate.   The 
potential  impact  of  these  actions  is  difficult  to  quantify  since  the  initiatives  to  improve 
underwriting  also  affect  this  area.   These  actions  are  ongoing.   Loss  adjustment 
standards  for  major  crops  and  changes  to  the  quality  adjustment  provisions  are  targeted 
for  the  1995  crop  year. 

K.    Marketing  Crnp  Insurance 

FCIC  marketing  efforts  for  1994  will  be  directed  by  a  strategic  marketing  plan  based  on 
information  and  data  received  from  market  research  compiled  across  the  country.   The 
plan's  main  objectives  will  be  to  inform  members  of  the  farming  community  about 
changes  in  the  program  and  to  educate  farmers  about  risk  management,  emphasizing  the 
value  of  crop  insurance  to  farming  operations. 

FCIC  will  conduct  a  year-long  media  campaign  targeted  at  publications  and  broadcast 
markets  with  an  agricultural  audience. 

Also,  emphasis  on  outreach  to  minority  farmers,  traditionally  under-represented  in  the 
program   will  be  coordinated  through  a  Minority  Outreach  Marketing  Plan  that 
specific^ly  identifies  minority  farmers  in  each  of  the  10  FCIC  Regional  Service  Offices. 

L.    Expand  Participation  hv  Introducing  New  Products 

Numerous  ideas  for  products  that  will  enhance  the  quality  and  acceptance  of  the  crop 
insurance  program  have  been  suggested.   These  include  cost  of  production  coverage 
(several  different  concepts),  dollar  denominated  coverage,  revenue  insurance, 
replacement  cost  insurance,  and  others.   FCIC  currently  has  contracts  with  the  Economic 
Research  Service  to  evaluate  several  alternatives  in  the  context  of  public  policy 
contributions,  availability  of  data  to  support  the  concepts,  assessments  of  producer 
acceptance,  and  other  factors.   FCIC  proposes  to  continue  such  research  and  seeks 
comments  about  additional  concepts  that  may  be  appropriate.   Implementation  of  a  pilot 
test  of  the  best  alternatives  will  be  pursued. 

-1^- 


76 


^-  to£i:Qve  Accrary  or  Other  Prooram  V.H.h..^ 

T;L:^:I^ZT^:1  tt  ^-^^^^^ ''-  ^^^^--^  ^-  -  -  -^^y  catego^zed  und. 

land  in  a  county  L  is  o3b;  Z  f    ^  '"'""^'^  ^^^'^  ^^^^""  ^  """  ^^  ^1 
insured  crop.    TOs  un    Zt  subd  v  S''  h'  ''"'''■  ^°'  "^'^  ^'^  P^^'^  ^°  ^he 
payment  of'additioni  pre  Jum     Gene^w  7:^ZST  "".'''°"'  ^"'^^"''"^ 
gives  them  greater  flexibility  L  ^e^^  fo   esS^^iS"^  '''°^  t  P^°g^  ^^^ 
indicates  that  size  of  a  unit  may  a^?2rS^s«   i  e      t, ?     ""  ^   ^°'"'  ""^'^^ 

fes^ch^T^  '7T  ^^^^^-^^^^c:::::^^^^:^:^  -^r 

research,  if  venfied,  suggests  that  a  surcharge  may  be  needed  fnr^.^Iu 

.n>pta„,ed.   I.p,e™„.a.o„  of  changes  wi,,  .e  Cedtr  .h"  »96%  y^. 

soundness  of  the  proSm   %Tj  1T°  ■*"'?  ""f  ''"="'>■  ^f'^"  <>"  =""aria] 
be  able  to  predict  ETentS^foS"'  T".  ""/"""='  ""'  "■=  '""""  ^o""" 
by  one  univers  tv  ndiSes  S-  fori,  °  "^^'^  *""S  ''"'=•    "°™'".  =  study 

insunmce  is  grS  a^^ototiLT  ="•  i''-  ""'  '°'=''^' '"  P^'^sing  crop 
encoutaged  Fact  do  S  S'^Fac'n  '"  '  '"","'""•  ''=  °^°  "^ 
crop  year  by  15-30  days  eit  ,^    e  P^ScnSs^FCIC  ™''"  '"  "=  "'' 

regarding  other  actions  u.Uh  r»„    ^         present  dates.    FCIC  requests  comments 

of  the  tafgSed  1  10 TossTdo.  '  ''°'^"^  '''"  ''''  "^"  ''^'''^'^  achievement 

'      crTi^rSe'ha^lf  1"^'"^  ^"^^  the  amount  of  insurance  when  a 

approach  wm  rSucr^^, '?fn     "J        ^"^"^  ^'  ''°P-   ^^'"^  "^^^^^^  ^his 
However  k  the  loot  nf  ?J  '"^emnities  and  help  achieve  actuarial  soundness. 

oSeitTse  nee^t    -^e  T  '°"^^  ^'  '°  ''^'''  P^^'"'"'"  ^^es  from  levels 

otnenvise  needed.   The  impact  of  staged  guarantees  upon  customer  acceptance  of 


19 


77 


crop  insurance  may  be  the  valid  measure  of  this  concept.    FCIC  specifically 
requests  comments  on  this  feature  and  assessments  of  its  potential  contribution  to 
achieving  the  targeted  1.10  loss  ratio. 

De  minimus  yields.   This  term  denotes  a  yield  below  which  any  production  is 
disregarded  for  the  purpose  of  determining  the  amount  of  indemnity.   The  concept 
is  advanced  by  interested  parties  as  an  equity  issue-that  it  costs  the  farmer  more  to 
harvest  the  crop  than  it  is  worth  in  the  market.   If  allowed  by  the  program, 
indemnities  will  increase  compared  to  the  present  provisions  of  the  crop  policies, 
which,  in  turn,  requires  higher  premium  rates  to  achieve  the  goal.   Readers  are 
encouraged  to  comment  on  the  desirability  of  increasing  premium  rates  by  an 
amount  needed  to  permit  this  feature  to  be  included  in  crop  insurance  policies. 


•  Suspension  and  debarment.    Inappropriate  determinations  and  poor  administration 
of  the  crop  insurance  program  is  alleged  about  agents,  loss  adjusters,  and  others 
who  are  involved  with  delivery  of  crop  insurance.   The  SSN/EIN  database  is 
intended  to  help  FCIC  monitor  the  conduct  of  these  persons.   However,  monitoring 
in  and  of  itself  is  insufficient  if  there  are  no  penalties  for  violations  of  program 
rules.    FCIC  proposes  to  develop  clear  and  concise  suspension  and  debarment 
procedures  for  agents,  loss  adjusters,  reinsured  companies  and  others  who  fail  to 
observe  the  highest  standards  of  performance  in  program  delivery  and 
administration. 

•  Price  Elections.   The  GAO  recommended  in  a  1991  report  that  for  the  major  crops, 
FCIC  set  its  price  elections  equal  to  the  forecasts  issued  by  the  World  Agricultural 
Outlook  Board  in  its  semi-annual  estimates.   These  estimates  correspond  to  the  cycle 
used  to  prepare  the  annual  budget  of  the  United  States  Government.   These 
estimates  are  available  only  twice  each  year.    Based  on  a  sampling  of  a  few  years, 
GAO  stated  that  overall  losses  would  be  reduced  if  this  recommendation  were 
adopted.   FCIC  is  committed  to  offering  a  price  election  that  complies  fully  with  the 
requirements  of  the  law.   In  addition,  the  offer  must  be  meaningful  to  farmers. 
FCIC  requests  comments  regarding  this  recommendation  and  assessmenu  by  readers 
of  its  likelihood  of  contributing  to  reduced  loss  ratios  and  improved  participation. 

Readers  are  requested  to  identify  additional  issues  that  they  believe  are  relevant  and 
important  to  assist  FCIC  in  its  actions  to  manage  the  program  to  achieve  the  target  loss 
ratio  while  maintaining  or  increasing  participation  levels. 

m.   MANAGEMENT  ACTIONS  TF  SECTION  n  ARE  NOT  SUCCESSFUL 

The  actions  identified  in  Section  II  of  this  document  represent  a  major  reinforcing  of  FCIC 
efforts  to  achieve  the  important  goal  of  financial  and  actuarial  soundness  in  Federal  crop 

20 


78 


insurance.   FCIC  believes  that  successful  completion  of  these  actions  will  meet  the  objective 
of  achieving  actuanal  soundness  as  required  by  OBRA  93.   Several  years  must  elapse  before 
It  will  be  possible  to  observe  FCIC's  achievement  of  the  objective.   In  the  interim, 
attainment  must  be  measured  by  realistic  models  of  risk  that  adequately  represent  the  crop 
insurance  program.     Flexibility  in  managing  the  program  to  attain  the  objective  while 
simultaneously  achieving  other  important  policy  objectives  must  be  stressed. 

Few  options  that  do  not  adversely  affect  participation  in  a  material  manner  are  available  in 
the  event  the  actions  described  in  this  blueprint  are  determined  to  be  inadequate    One  option 
IS  to  focus  better  on  defining  the  risk  that  is  included  in  the  premium  rates  charged  to  current 
msureds.    Extreme  crop  disasters  (such  as  the  1993  flooding  and  cold,  wet  growing  season) 
tend  to  be  widespread  and  occur  infrequendy.    Crop  insurance  is  not  actuarially  sound  in  a 
commercial  sense  because  the  private  sector  cannot  manage  the  magnitude  of  these  risks  or 
arrange  the  financing  over  the  long  periods  of  time  needed  to  accumulate  reserves  for  a 
major  disaster.     This  characteristic  of  crop  disasters  argues  that  actuarial  soundness  perhaps 
should  be  measured  on  a  basis  that  separates  normally  expected  conditions  from  the  extreme 
disasters.   This  would  serve  to  more  precisely  define  the  risk  included  in  the  premium  rates 
for  cunrent  insureds,  and  the  risk  that  should  be  amortized  over  longer  time  periods. 

If  the  above  is  not  acceptable,  another  action  would  be  to  limit  the  liabUity  of  crop  insurance 
to  specific  areas  and  crops.   This  limitation  could  take  the  form  of  complete  withdrawal  of 
insurance  in  some  cases,  or  limitations  on  the  volume  of  business  that  would  be  accepted  in 
a  year  for  a  crop  or  area.    Commercial  insurers  use  this  process  to  manage  their  exposure  to 
avoid  concentrations  geographically  or  by  product  line..  Crop  insurance  may  need  the  same 
management  of  its  exposures  rather  than  accepting  any  and  all  risk  whenever  farmers  decide 
to  enter  and  exit  the  program.   This  extreme  action  would  indicate  that  the  program  was 
unable  to  completely  fulfill  its  social  and  public  policy  responsibilities,  and  must  be  regarded 
as  an  initiative  of  last  resort. 


^-   MANAGEMENT  ACTTONS  IF  ACTIONS  IN  SECTION  U  ARE  MORF. 
SUCCESSRH,  THAN  NEEDED 

The  greatest  impediment  to  increased  program  participation  will  be  high  premium  rates  that 
might  result  from  the  actions  defined  in  this  plan.  Moderation  of  premium  rate  increases  will 
be  a  pnority  if  more  stringent  program  administration  reduces  the  loss  ratio  below  the  target. 
If  this  occurs,  experience  should  be  examined  to  identify  losses  paid  that  no  longer  should  be 
expected.    Once  the  impact  of  those  losses  is  eliminated  from  the  experience,  some 
improvement  in  premium  rates  would  be  anticipated.   FCIC  believes  that  the  remaining 
management  actions  that  have  improved  administration  of  the  program  or  that  have  better 
defmed  the  coverage  provided  to  U.  S.  agriculture  should  not  be  relaxed  because  these 
generally  represent  good  administration  of  public  policy. 


21 


REVIEW     OF     THE     ADMINISTRATION'S     FED- 
ERAL    CROP     INSURANCE     REFORM     PRO- 


POSAL 


TUESDAY,  APRIL  5,  1994 


House  of  Representatives, 
Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit, 

AND  Rural  Development, 
Committee  on  Agriculture, 

Luverne,  MN. 

The  subcommittee  met,  pursuant  to  notice,  at  9:30  a.m.,  at  the 
Veterans  of  Foreign  Wars,  705  South  Highway  75,  Luverne,  MN, 
Hon.  Tim  Johnson  (chairman  of  the  subcommittee)  presidmg. 

Present:  Representatives  Minge  and  Peterson. 

Staff  present:  Anne  Simmons. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  TIM  JOHNSON,  A  REPRESENT- 
ATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  SOUTH  DAKOTA 

Mr  Johnson.  We  will  bring  this  field  hearing  of  the  Environ- 
ment, Credit,  and  Rural  Development  Subcommittee  of  the  House 
of  Representatives  Committee  on  Agriculture  to  order 

This  is  a  field  hearing  held  here  at  the  V.F.W.  Hall  in  Luverne, 
Minnesota.  It  is  the  one  and  only  field  hearing  on  the  issue  of  fed- 
eral crop  insurance  that  this  committee  will  be  holding  this  year 
prior  to  holding  hearings  in  Washington  and  marking  up  legisla- 
tion on  crop  insurance  later  on  in  the  year. 

I  am  holding  this  hearing  at  the  request  of  my  colleague,  Dave 
Minge,  to  review  the  administration's  comprehensive  proposal,  the 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994,  for  the  reform  of  our 
Nation's  crop  insurance  program.  ..  j 

The  need  for  reform  has  been  apparent  to  me  for  some  time  and 
has  been  dramatized  as  I  toured  the  Midwest  flood  States  this  past 
summer  and  listened  to  the  many  concerns  of  the  producers 
throughout  the  region. 

I  think  there  is  a  growing  awareness  among  producers  all  across 
this  country  that  currently  we  have  a  dual  system  of  crop  insur- 
ance and  sometimes  ad  hoc  disaster  payments,  neither  of  which  is 
working  as  well  as  it  ought.  It  is  time  for  us  to  consolidate  the  two 
into  one  good  risk  management  tool  that,  in  fact,  works,  and  is  not 
subject  to  the  political  whims  of  ad  hoc  disaster  programs. 

The  general  consensus  is  that  the  current  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram is  not  working  as  well  as  it  should.  The  Federal  Crop  Insur- 
ance Corporation  experiences  large  losses  every  year,  pegged  at 
over  $1  billion  this  year  alone. 

(79) 


80 

On  top  of  this,  the  Congress  has  authorized  ad  hoc  disaster  pro- 
grams each  and  every  year  since  1986.  One  goal  of  the  1980  over- 
haul of  the  crop  insurance  program  was  to  eliminate  the  need  for 
ad  hoc  disaster  programs,  inasmuch  as  they  undermine  the  crop  in- 
surance program  itself. 

Clearly,  this  has  not  happened,  and  despite  the  fact  that  the  Fed- 
eral Government  has  spent  an  average  of  $1.7  billion  combined  for 
crop  insurance  and  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  in  each  year  for  the 
past  10  years,  many  producers  are  understandably  not  satisfied 
with  either  program. 

Producer  dissatisfaction  of  the  crop  insurance  program  is  evi- 
denced by  the  fact  that  participation  is  limited.  Only  30  percent  of 
the  eligible  acreage  is  enrolled,  and  when  they  do  experience  crop 
loss  coverage  it  is  often  inadequate. 

Ad  hoc  disaster  programs  are  unpredictable  in  that  they  require 
emergency  appropriations.  They  also  require  the  right  combination 
of  political  circumstances  around  the  country.  Producers  cannot 
budget  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs,  and  it  makes  their  financial 
planning  extraordinarily  difficult. 

We  have  two  programs  purportedly  working  side  by  side  to  help 
producers,  but  in  actually  they  are  working  in  some  respects  at 
cross  purposes.  The  very  existence  of  ad  hoc  disaster  programs 
makes  the  crop  insurance  program  less  effective  and  less  attractive. 

Many  producers  do  not  take  out  crop  insurance  because  they  be- 
lieve, understandably,  that  the  Federal  Government  will  bail  them 
out  by  offering  free  ad  hoc  disaster  payments. 

I  commend  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture  for  taking  a  comprehen- 
sive approach  to  reform,  offering  one  program  that  combines  crop 
insurance  for  program  crops  with  catastrophic  insurance  for  non- 
program  crops,  and  will  help  solve  many  of  the  problems  enumer- 
ated. 

This  subcommittee  must  now  examine  the  details  of  the  adminis- 
tration's bill.  Above  all,  any  crop  insurance  proposal  must  be  fis- 
cally sound  and  within  our  budget  requirements. 

Producers  must  be  convinced  of  two  things.  One,  their  out-of- 
pocket  costs  for  insurance  must  be  commensurate  with  the  poten- 
tial indemnities  they  may  earn,  and  second,  ad  hoc  disaster  pro- 
grams are  indeed  a  thing  of  the  past. 

There  are  many  other  concerns  that  have  been  expressed  to  me 
about  the  administration  proposal,  and  we  will  have  an  opportunity 
to  listen  to  those  concerns  and  discuss  them  in  this  hearing. 

This  hearing  is  the  second  of  three  I've  held  or  will  be  holding 
on  crop  insurance.  On  March  25,  this  committee  held  a  hearing  in 
Washington  with  Under  Secretary  of  Agriculture,  Gean  Moos  and 
Ken  Ackerman,  Manager  of  the  FCIC. 

I  have  scheduled  a  hearing  on  April  21,  back  in  Washington  with 
additional  outside  witnesses. 

I  plan  on  being  as  aggressive  as  possible  in  moving  this  legisla- 
tion through  this  subcommittee.  I  plan  on  holding  a  markup  as 
soon  as  the  schedules  permits. 

I  want  to  thank  Congressman  Minge  for  inviting  me  to  discuss 
a  topic  which  is  of  vital  importance  to  his  district.  I  want  to  wel- 
come everyone  in  attendance.  I  look  forward  to  hearing  today's  tes- 
timony. 


81 

I  want  to  add  as  well  that  the  State  of  Minnesota  is  unusually 
well-served  relative  to  agriculture  and  rural  issues  by  the  presence 
of  Dave  Minge  who  has  established  an  excellent  reputation  on  the 
Committee  of  Agriculture  already,  and  Collin  Peterson  who  is  a 
proven  leader  in  agriculture  as  well. 

Both  of  them  bring  not  only  a  hard  work  ethic  to  the  committee, 
but  a  degree  of  common  sense  that  all  too  often  is  missing  in  delib- 
erations in  Washington.  The  people  of  Minnesota  can  be  immensely 
proud  of  the  service  that  they  have  from  both  Mr.  Minge  and  Mr. 
Peterson. 

I  will  yield  for  any  opening  statement  that  the  more  senior  of  my 
colleagues  has. 

Mr.  Peterson  first. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  COLLIN  C.  PETERSON,  A  REP- 
RESENTATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  MIN- 
NESOTA 

Mr.  Peterson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  will  be  brief. 

I  want  to  commend  your  leadership  on  taking  hold  of  this  issue 
and  moving  aggressively.  It  is  time  that  we  do  something.  The  tim- 
ing is  right.  We  have  the  administration  on  board  for,  I  think,  the 
first  time  that  they  have  really  been  committed.  I  think  we  have 
a  real  opportunity  to  put  this  together.  We  work  on  it  real  hard, 
and  I  understand  that  you  are  going  to  do  that. 

I  held  some  meetings  in  my  district  yesterday  to  talk  about  the 
administration's  proposal.  We  have  a  lot  of  issues  that  we  are  going 
to  have  to  deal  with  as  we  go  through  this.  I  am  sure  you  are  hear- 
ing the  same  sort  of  thing  from  your  constituents. 

I  am  glad  to  be  here  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  it  snowed  last  night. 
We  didn't  get  any  snow  up  North.  We  live  right  up  there. 

But  glad  to  be  in  Luveme.  The  first  time  I've  been  here,  and  it 
was  beautiful  flying  in  this  morning. 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Minge? 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  DAVID  MINGE,  A  REPRESENT- 
ATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  MINNESOTA 

Mr.  Minge.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  appreciate  the  willing- 
ness of  the  committee  to  hold  the  hearing  in  the  Midwest,  and  par- 
ticularly to  hold  the  hearing  here  in  Luveme. 

It  provides  us  with  an  excellent  opportunity  to  not  only  learn 
about  the  proposal  that  is  coming  from  Secretary  of  Agriculture 
Espy  and  President  CUnton  with  respect  to  crop  insurance,  but  also 
to  comment  on  that  proposal. 

Altogether  to  often  we  have  hearings  in  Washington,  and  it  is  ex- 
pensive. It  is  difficult  for  people  throughout  the  country  to  attend 
these  hearings,  and  there  is  a  feeling  of  remoteness  that  Washing- 
ton is  making  decisions  without  considering  or  understanding  what 
is  going  on  in  the  countryside. 

This  is  our  chance  here  in  South  Dakota,  Minnesota,  Iowa,  to 
participate  in  the  formation  of  legislation.  The  fact  that  this  is  the 
only  field  hearing  that  will  be  held  outside  Washington,  DC,  on  this 
important  topic  this  year,  I  think,  gives  added  significance  to  our 
gathering  here  today. 


82 

Many  of  the  comments  that  have  been  made  by  Chairman  John- 
son are  ones  that  I  wish  to  echo.  In  addition,  I  would  point  out  that 
we  have  areas  of  consideration  or  concern  with  crop  insurance  that 
go  beyond  its  relation  to  the  ad  hoc  disaster  programs. 

We  have  had  difficulties  with  the  lack  of  preventive  planting  cov- 
erage, penalties  for  late  planting.  The  policy  for  1994  has  been 
modified  to  try  to  address  those  concerns. 

We  have  had  additional  questions  with  respect  to  yield,  with  re- 
spect to  loss  ratios  in  different  portions  of  the  country,  and  added 
features  of  the  program.  These  are  all  things  I  hope  that  we  can 
take  some  time  to  address  this  morning.  In  addition,  I  know  they 
will  be  addressed  as  this  legislation  moves  through  the  committee. 

I  think  it  is  especially  significant  that  in  attendance  in  Luveme 
this  morning  or  students  from  the  Luveme  Senior  High  School. 
There  are  approximately  110  that  are  including  this  as  a  part  of 
their  educational  program,  and  I  certainly  welcome  them  to  this 
hearing.  Thanks  again  for  coming,  and  I  look  forward  to  the  com- 
ments from  those  of  you  in  the  audience  that  are  not  a  part  of  the 
regular  panel. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  Representative  Minge. 

We  will  proceed  with  three  panels  of  witnesses  in  the  conduct  of 
this  hearing  today.  This  is  an  official  hearing  of  the  U.S.  House 
Committee  on  Agriculture,  and  the  record  and  will  be  shared  with 
our  colleagues  and  staff  back  in  Washington. 

At  the  conclusion  of  the  testimony  from  the  panels  today,  we  will 
have  an  opportunity  for  those  who  are  not  formally  on  one  of  the 
panels  to  express  opinions  or  ask  questions.  We  will  have  an  open 
microphone,  at  least  for  a  reasonable  period  of  time  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing. 

It  will  be  important,  however,  for  you  to  sign  up  on  a  sheet  in 
the  rear  of  the  hearing  room  so  that  our  record  keepers  know  for 
certain  who  it  is  who  is  making  their  statements,  and  you  will  be 
called  based  on  your  sign  up  sheet  in  the  back.  So  please  cooperate 
with  us  in  that  regard  if  you  are  interested  in  your  own  comments 
or  questions. 

The  first  witness  we  have  is  Mr.  Kenneth  D.  Ackerman  who  is 
Manager  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation,  U.S.  Depart- 
ment of  Agriculture  in  Washington,  DC. 

Mr.  Ackerman,  welcome  to  the  subcommittee.  Your  full  state- 
ment is  received  for  the  record  of  the  subcommittee.  You  may 
choose  to  abbreviate  or  to  summarize  however  you  wish,  but  please 
do  proceed. 

STATEMENT  OF  KENNETH  D.  ACKERMAN,  MANAGER,  FEDERAL 
CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION,  U.S.  DEPARTMENT  OF  AG- 
RICULTURE 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Thank  you.  I  want  to  thank  Chairman  Johnson 
and  Congressman  Minge  and  Congressman  Peterson  for  having 
this  hearing  today  in  Minnesota. 

I  agree  with  one  point  that  has  been  made.  It  is  very  importsmt 
in  discussing  proposal  like  this  to  have  hearings  in  the  field. 

When  we  put  our  crop  insurance  proposal  together  within  the  ad- 
ministration, we  made  a  point  to  have  meetings  with  farmers  who 
£ire  affected  by  crop  insurance  in  a  number  of  States:  North  Da- 


83 

kota,  Texas,  Louisiana,  Minnesota,  Iowa,  Maine,  Nebraska,  and 
others,  and  we  hope  to  continue  that. 

Washington,  DC,  is  a  very  nice  city,  but  there  aren't  a  lot  of  peo- 
ple there  who  carry  crop  insurance.  If  we  are  going  to  get  feedback 
on  this  program,  it  is  important  to  discuss  it  here  in  Minnesota, 
and  South  Dakota,  and  Iowa,  and  parts  of  the  country  where  this 
issue  is  very  meaningful,  a  very  part  of  the  way  of  life  of  people 
who  live  there.  So  having  this  hearing  here  in  Minnesota  is  ex- 
tremely useful,  and  I  am  very  glad  to  be  here  this  morning. 

I  made  a  point  to  bring  some  good  weather  with  me  from  Wash- 
ington, so  you  are  welcome. 

Mr.  Johnson.  We  usually  bring  hot  air  with  us,  not  cold  air  with 

us.  [Laughter.] 

That's  usually  what  happens  when  people  from  Washmgton  come 
home,  but  go  ahead. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Well,  we  are  new  Democrats.  [Laughter.] 

As  you  know,  about  a  month  ago.  Secretary  Espy  unveiled  a  very 
major  set  of  changes  in  crop  insurance  covering  a  lot  of  territory. 
We  very  much  appreciate  the  fact  that  this  subcommittee  has  been 
very  prompt  in  holding  hearings  on  this  proposal. 

Crop  insurance  is  one  of  those  programs  that  has  been  the  sub- 
ject of  a  lot  of  criticism  over  the  years,  a  lot  of  call  for  change.  We 
hear  dissatisfaction  from  farmers,  from  taxpayers,  from  Congress, 
GAO,  0MB,  Office  of  Inspector  General  of  the  Media.  Virtually  ev- 
eryone who  has  looked  at  this  program  has  had  problems  with  it. 

As  a  general  matter,  you  can  look  at  the  current  problems  with 
crop  insurance  as  being  a  result  of  it  being  in  the  middle  of  two 
current  trends.  Over  the  past  half  dozen  years  or  so  we  have  seen 
an  unprecedented  parade  of  disaster  affecting  American  agriculture 
starting  with  the  1988  drought  of  the  century,  the  1989  drought, 
the  1992  hurricane  of  the  century,  the  1993  flood  of  the  half  millen- 
nium at  the  same  time  as  a  major  drought. 

Scientists  disagree  as  to  whether  all  these  events  are  related — 
whether  or  not  they  are,  clearly,  the  risk  of  loss  among  American 
producers  is  now  foremost  in  their  mind.  Recent  experience  has  put 

it  there. 

At  the  same  time  while  there  is  increasing  demand  for  ways  to 
address  risk,  we  base  historic  type  budgets  at  every  level  of  govern- 
ment. As  you  know,  the  Federal  Government  in  Washington  is 
dealing  with  a  deficit  in  the  multi  trillions  of  dollars.  Interest  on 
the  national  debt  is  one  of  the  largest  items  in  the  budget,  oyer 
$200  billion  a  year.  Deficit  reduction  has  become  one  of  the  major 
priorities  of  this  period  in  our  history. 

Last  year  the  Omnibus  Reconciliation  Act  took  a  $3  billion  hit 
from  Agriculture.  Whenever  you  talk  about  deficit  reduction,  agri- 
culture has  always  been  front  and  center. 

This  years  budget,  similarly,  has  a  major  reduction  in  agri- 
culture. As  we  go  forward,  we  can  expect  that  trend  to  continue  as 

well. 

The  problems  with  crop  insurance  were  very  much  accentuated 
by  last  summer's  flood,  or  very  much  exposed  by  last  summer's 
flood  and  drought.  The  major  problem  was  the  sheer  magnitude  of 
the  disaster  in  rural  America. 


84 

Just  to  give  you  a  sense  of  the  size  of  the  problem,  for  the  crop 
year  1993,  FCIC  paid  out  a  total  of  $1.64  billions,  $1.6  billion  in 
claims  to  American  farmers  for  losses. 

By  contrast,  in  1992,  the  year  of  Hurricane  Andrew,  we  paid  out 
about  $920  million  in  claims.  That  is  $700  million  less.  The  dif- 
ference being  the  magnitude  of  the  destruction  in  American  agri- 
culture because  of  last  summer's  flood  and  drought. 

To  give  you  a  sense  of  how  this  struck  closer  to  home  in  this  part 
of  the  country,  in  the  State  of  Minnesota,  Minnesota  was  the  State 
with  the  single  largest  number  of  claims  in  dollar  amount  because 
of  destruction  of  last  summer's  flood.  Farmers  in  Minnesota  re- 
ceived claims  of  $353  million  from  last  summer's  flood.  The  State 
of  Iowa,  which  is  very  nearby,  farmers  had  claims  of  $281  million 
South  Dakota,  $54  million. 

So  very  large  amounts  of  money  needed  to  be  paid  out,  and  these 
are  insurance  claims.  This  is  money  that  farmers  paid  for.  Cov- 
erage they  paid  for,  coverage  that  they  earned. 

Because  of  the  simple  magnitude  of  the  problem,  the  amount  of 
loss,  the  size  of  the  demand  to  get  money  out  to  people  quickly  be- 
cause of  the  crises  they  were  facing,  this  exposed  a  lot  of  problems 
in  our  system.  Everything  from  the  lack  of  preventive  planning  cov- 
erage, which,  again,  was  a  very  significant  problem  in  this  specific 
part  of  the  country. 

South  Dakota,  we  estimate  that  about  1.1  million  acres  could  not 
be  planted  last  year  because  of  the  rains  that  hit  early  in  the  year. 
In  Minnesota,  846,000  acres  could  not  be  planted  last  year.  In 
Iowa,  1.2  million  acres  could  not  be  planted  last  year. 

So  the  lack  of  preventive  planning  coverage  as  part  of  our  core 
policy  was  a  very  significant  problem  for  farmers  in  this  part  of  the 
country. 

There  were  problems  with  our  price  selections  being  too  rigid. 
There  were  problems  with  out  placing  some  of  our  offices  too  close 
to  rivers.  Some  of  our  buildings  got  flooded  out  last  year. 

But  one  of  the  major  problems  that  became  evident  during  the 
flood  was  one  which  several  of  you  have  referred  to  and  that  is  the 
fact  that  over  the  past  several  years  in  this  country  we  have  devel- 
oped two  systems,  two  Government  programs  existing  side  by  side 
trying  to  address  the  same  problem. 

We  have  a  crop  insurance  program  which  costs  American  tax- 
payers close  to  $900  million  a  year.  That  is  a  lot  of  money  by  any 
way  of  figuring,  even  by  Washington  standards  that  is  a  lot  of 
money.  Yet,  despite  that  investment  by  taxpayers,  the  leverage  of 
cover  is  very  limited. 

In  1993,  only  33  percent  of  potentially  insured  acres  were  in  fact 
covered  by  crop  insurance.  Only  83  million  acres  out  of  250  poten- 
tial acres  were  covered  by  crop  insurance.  As  a  result,  when  actual 
disasters  have  struck,  major  droughts,  major  floods,  Washington 
has  had  to  step  in  year  in  and  year  out  with  ad  hoc  disaster  pro- 
grams. 

What  has  happened  is  that  even  though  these  disaster  programs 
are  very  important,  we  have  tried  to  stress  in  this  debate  that 
these  disaster  programs  were  very  responsible  actions  by  the  Fed- 
eral Government  to  address  needs  of  citizens,  these  disaster  pro- 


85 

grams  helped  hundreds  of  thousands  of  farmers  and  nonfarmers 
alike  survive  one  of  the  worst  crisis  in  their  adult  lives. 

The  problem  is  that  the  uncertainty  created  by  ad  hoc  disaster 
bills  has  created  a  problem  both  for  farmers  and  for  taxpayers. 

From  the  farmers  point  of  view  the  problem  is  very  straight- 
forward. If  you  do  not  have  crop  insurance  and  you  rely  on  ad  hoc 
disaster  aid,  you  simply  do  not  know  in  any  given  year  whether 
you  are  going  to  have  protection  and  what  your  protection  is  going 

Last  week  I  was  in  the  State  of  Louisiana,  which  was  hit  by  Hur- 
ricane Andrew  in  1992.  If  you  were  one  of  those  farmers  that  was 
totally  wiped  out  by  Hurricane  Andrew,  you  received  a  disaster 
payment  at  50  percent  proration.  That  means  you  go  through  the 
legal  disaster  formula  which  gets  you  down  to  about  40  to  45  cents 
on  the  dollar  to  start  with,  and  then  it  was  cut  in  half  because  that 
was  the  level  of  funding  that  the  appropriations  committees  in 
Congress  were  able  to  provide  that  year. 

A  farmer  who  suffered  a  complete  loss  from  the  1993  flood  re- 
ceived disaster  aid.  Received  this  40  to  45  cents  on  the  dollar,  fully 
funded.  They  got  the  whole  amount. 

The  difference  to  the  individual  farmer,  if  you  are  that  farmer 
suffering  a  full  loss,  it  doesn't  matter  whether  1  State  is  affected 
or  10  States  were  affected;  you  suffered  a  full  loss.  But  because  of 
the  ad  hoc  nature  of  these  disaster  programs,  producers  simply  do 
not  know  year  in  and  year  out  whether  they  are  going  to  get  pro- 
tection or  what  the  protection  formula  is  going  to  be.  That  is  simply 
not  a  good  way  to  run  your  farm  operation  as  a  business. 

From  the  taxpayer  point  of  view,  it  is  the  same  problem:  uncer- 
tainty. .  ,      .V  U 

As  you  can  see  from  the  first  chart  in  my  testimony  to  the  sub- 
committee, over  the  past  10  years,  Washington  has  provided  these 
ad  hoc  disaster  payments  for  the  last  8.  And  the  average  cost  to 
taxpayers  for  these  crop  loss  disaster  programs  has  been  about  $1 
billion  a  year.  Some  years  it  was  zero,  some  years  it  was  way  more, 
but  that  is  the  average. 

However,  disaster  aid  is  not  subject  to  any  of  the  budget  dis- 
cipline rules  that  apply  to  every  other  area  of  Federal  funding.  It 
is  not  subject  to  the  so-called  pay-as-you-go  rules.  It  is  considered 
emergency  funding;  it  is  passed  and  simply  added  to  the  Federal 

deficit.  ,  ,  .1.      •        r 

What  we  have  seen  as  a  result  is  that  over  the  years  the  size  ot 
these  disaster  programs  has  grown.  So  over  the  last  6  years  the  av- 
erage has  risen  to  over  $1.5  billion  a  year,  and  each  time  there  is 
another  disaster  bill,  the  level  of  taxpayer  resistance  gets  more  and 

more  extreme.  mi.-     • 

This  is  not  only  a  phenomenon  involving  agriculture.  This  is  a 
phenomenon  involving  disaster  bills  for  earthquakes,  for  fires,  for 
every  other  area  of  emergency  spending. 

We  saw  it  very  dramatically  a  few  weeks  ago  when  Congress  de- 
bated a  disaster  relief  bill  for  the  Los  Angeles  earthquake  of  about 
$8  billion.  Even  though  everyone  in  the  country  had  seen  the  dev- 
astation from  Los  Angles  and  knew  the  need  of  the  assistance,  the 
bill  was  held  up  for  several  weeks  because  of  amendments  to  tie 


86 

it  to  budget  cuts.  This  phenomenon  is  one  that  we  can  very  much 
expect  to  go  forward  with  or  to  see  it  go  forward. 

The  proposal  that  Secretary  Espy  put  forward  for  crop  insurance 
tries  to  get  at  these  problems  from  a  number  of  directions.  The  cen- 
terpieces is  a  piece  of  legislation  called  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Reform  Act  of  1994.  The  central  premise  of  that  bill  is  to  try  to 
combine  crop  insurance  and  disaster  aid  into  a  single,  unified,  on- 
budget  program. 

To  do  this  requires  two  steps.  First,  we  are  proposing  essentially 
to  create  a  legal  barrier  against  future  ad  hoc  disaster  bills.  Essen- 
tially, we  are  taking  away  their  emergency  status  under  the  Budg- 
et Enforcement  Act.  To  pass  one,  it  has  to  be  paid  for  with  offset- 
ting budget  cuts. 

Then,  on  the  other  side,  to  protect  farmers  in  the  absence  of  an 
ad  hoc  disaster  bill,  we  are  proposing  to  expand  the  crop  insurance 
program.  This  expansion  takes  a  number  of  forums. 

The  most  significant  one  is  the  creation  of  a  new  level  of  protec- 
tion called  catastrophic  coverage,  which  will  be  made  available  to 
all  farmers  of  covered  crops.  The  Government  would  essentially  pay 
the  premium.  It  is  like  a  rainy  day  fund.  The  farmer  would  pay  a 
processing  fee  of  $50  per  crop  per  county  with  a  limit  of  $100  per 
county. 

The  idea  is  that  this  catastrophic  coverage  would  replace  the  dis- 
aster pa3anent.  The  level  of  coverage  provided  would  be  50  percent 
of  yield  at  60  percent  of  price.  A  level  designed  to  be  very  similar 
to  what  farmers  have  gotten  under  disaster  bills  for  the  past  few 
years  falling  between  that  50  percent  and  100  percent  proration 
levels. 

In  my  testimony,  I  have  provided  you  with  some  numerical  ex- 
amples of  a  com  farmer,  and  wheat  farmer,  a  cotton  farmer,  and 
how  this  50/60  coverage  would  protect  them  compared  to  the  disas- 
ter programs.  This  is  the  final  four  or  five  charts  in  the  testimony 
package. 

The  main  difference,  however,  between  catastrophic  coverage  and 
disaster  aid  is  that  it  is  not  ad  hoc.  It  is  an  insurance  contract.  It 
is  a  financial  asset  that  a  farmer  has  at  the  beginning  of  the  year. 
They  can  take  it  to  the  bank  as  collateral  on  a  loan.  If  a  producer 
is  the  only  one  in  the  entire  country  suffering  a  loss,  they  know 
they  are  protected.  They  don't  have  to  worry  whether  farmers  in 
10  other  States  suffer  a  disaster. 

In  order  to  make  sure  that  the  largest  number  of  farmers  in  fact 
get  their  hands  on  this  coverage,  we  are  proposing  to  link  it  to  par- 
ticipation in  farm  programs  and  Farmers  Home  Administration 
loans. 

In  other  words,  to  qualify  for  a  wheat  deficiency  pa5rment  or  a 
com  deficiency  pa3nnent,  a  farmer  must  have  acquired  at  least  cat- 
astrophic level  of  coverage  under  crop  insurance.  We  project  that 
with  this  linkage,  crop  insurance  participation  would  rise  from  its 
current  33  percent  level  to  about  80  percent.  A  very  dramatic  rise. 

I  know  whenever  you  start  to  talk  about  linkages  and  mandatory 
programs  that  raises  a  red  flag.  People  don't  like  mandates.  No- 
body likes  being  told  what  to  do.  That  is  human  nature,  but  we 
think  in  this  case  the  proposal  is  reasonable.  The  fact  that  we  are 
talking  about  a  catastrophic  level  of  coverage  for  which  a  farmer 


87 

pays  $50  or  $100  means  that  this  is  fairly  not  onerous,  and  the  pro- 
ducer is  getting  something  in  return.  J.J   ,^  4.  i.    u 

The  main  problem  we  wanted  to  avoid  was  we  didn  t  want  to  be 
in  a  situation  where  we  go  through  the  process  of  changing  crop 
insurance,  spending  the  money  on  this,  creating  the  legal  barriers 
against  an  ad  hoc  disaster  program  and  then  find  2  years  down  the 
road  we  have  a  major  drought  or  a  major  flood  and  that  a  large 
number  of  farmers  simply  have  not  picked  up  the  catastrophic  cov- 
erage for  whatever  reason.  Either  they  were  skeptical  of  a  new 
Government  program  or  the  word  had  not  gotten  out  to  them  or  it 
was  a  matter  of  simple  inertia.  We  wanted  to  make  sure  that  farm- 
ers would  be  protected.  ,        t^  ,.  c 

We  understand  that  50/60  coverage  is  very  low.  For  most  farmers 
they  really  need  something  better  to  operate  in  a  responsible  way, 
to  operate  as  a  business.  So  we  have  provided  in  this  legislation  for 
farmers  to  get  crop  insurance  at  higher  levels. 

If  they  purchase  crop  insurance  at  a  65  or  75  percent  yield  level, 
they  would  enjoy  an  out-of-pocket  cost  reduction  of  about  10  to  15 

There  are  a  number  of  other  elements  to  this  that  I  will  walk 
through  very  quickly.  In  order  to  make  sure  that  this  coverage  is 
provided  in  the  most  convenient  way,  we  are  proposing  to  alter  our 
delivery  system.  For  catastrophic  coverage  farmers  would  have  a 
choice.  They  could  purchase  it  either  through  a  private  agent  or  a 
county  office  of  USD  A.  i     -u        u 

Higher  levels  of  coverage  would  remain  available  only  througn 

private  agents.  ,     ttt  u 

We  would  provide  price  competition  among  agents.  We  would  say 
that  if  one  company  could  deliver  crop  insurance  more  efficiency 
than  another  company,  they  could  pass  along  the  savings  to  the 
farmer.  We  feel  this  is  a  way  to  cut  down  on  overhead  costs,  and 
to  provide  a  more  economical  product. 

For  those  crops  that  are  not  covered  by  crop  insurance  at  all,  we 
would  provide  a  standing  disaster  program.  Currently,  crop  insur- 
ance coverage  about  50-odd  crops.  I  have  provided  a  list  in  my  tes- 
timony. I  have  also  provided  a  list  of  about  20-odd  crops  that  are 
currently  in  the  pipeline  for  being  added  to  the  system. 

For  those  that  are  not  on  any  of  these  lists,  we  would  provide  a 
standing  disaster  program,  similar  to  the  disaster  programs  that 
exist  today,  providing  coverage  level  at  that  50-60  level  with  an 

area  trisEer. 

The  cost  of  this  program,  the  catastrophic  coverage,  the  subsidies 
for  buyouts,  and  the  standing  disaster  program,  we  expect  to  be 
about  $1  billion  a  year,  slightly  less  than  $1  billion  a  year  on  top 
of  the  current  cost  of  crop  insurance.  So  we  would  go  from  being 
about  a  $900  million  program  to  about  a  $1.85  biUion  program. 

Conceptually,  what  we  are  proposing  to  do  it  to  take  that  bilhon 
dollars  a  year  in  real  money  that  Washington  is  now  spending  on 
ad  hoc  disaster  aid  and  channeUng  it  into  a  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram because  we  feel  that  this  provides  more  certainty  to  farmers 
and  more  certainty  to  taxpayers. 

When  Secretary  Espy  announced  this  program,  we  made  clear  at 
that  time  that  combining  crop  insurance  and  disaster  aid  standing 


88 

alone  is  not  enough.  There  are  other  things  we  have  to  do  to  make 
this  program  workable  and  to  make  this  program  accessible. 

The  second  most  important  thing  that  we  had  to  do  was  to  make 
this  program  fiscally  sound.  As  you  know,  over  the  past  10  to  12 
years,  the  crop  insurance  program  has  lost  billions  of  dollars. 

We  have  had  a  average  loss  ratio  of  about  1.47  going  back  to 
1981.  What  that  means  is  that  in  an  average  year  we  have  paid 
out  $1.47  worth  of  claims  for  every  dollar  we've  taken  in  in  pre- 
mium not  counting  overhead  costs.  If  we  were  a  private  business 
we  would  have  gone  broke  long  ago. 

American  taxpayers  have  sent  the  message  loud  and  clear:  they 
will  not  pick  up  the  tab  for  those  kinds  of  excess  losses  anymore. 

We  now  have  a  statutory  mandate  under  the  reconciliation  bill 
passed  last  year  to  get  our  loss  ratio  down  to  1.1  by  October  1995. 
For  that  reason,  we  are  going  to  be  instituting  a  number  of  man- 
agement changes  to  tighten  up  our  program  financially. 

This  includes  more  use  of  APH  yields,  actual  production  history 
3delds;  expansion  of  the  current  nonstandard  classification  program 
designed  to  identify  high-risk  farmers  and  adjust  their  rates;  an 
emphasis  on  program  compliance;  continued  risk-sharing  with  the 
private  sector;  the  implementation  of  a  participant  tracking  system 
to  back  our  compliance  program;  and  other  steps  of  that  nature  to 
make  the  program  more  financially  sound. 

It  will  mean  that  rates  may  go  up  in  some  parts  of  the  country, 
but  we  are  trying  not  to  rely  on  rate  increases  as  the  major  way 
to  improve  the  financial  soundness  of  the  program.  We  know  that 
that  can  backfire.  We  have  seen  that  backfire  over  the  years. 

We  started  raising  rates  a  number  of  years  ago.  Harshly,  as  a  re- 
sult of  that,  where  5  or  6  years  ago  most  farmers  bought  crop  in- 
surance at  a  75-percent  yield  coverage  level,  today  most  farmers 
buy  it  at  a  65-percent  jdeld  coverage  level. 

I  cannot  trace  that  change  directly  to  rate  increases,  but  it  would 
be  surprising  if  that  were  not  a  major  contributing  factor.  So  that 
is  part  of  the  mix,  but  we  are  trjdng  not  to  make  it  a  major  part 
of  the  mix. 

Finally,  the  other  part  of  our  program  is  we  realize  we  have  to 
make  crop  insurance  more  flexible,  more  useable,  more  farmer 
friendly.  That  concept  implies  a  lot  of  steps.  We  are  hoping  to  put 
a  number  of  additional  options  on  the  table  for  farmers. 

We  are  going  to  try  to  improve  more  private  insurance  products 
developed  by  the  private  sector.  We  are  going  to  make  a  point  to 
listen  better.  We  are  going  to  look  at  bringing  back  a  good  farmer 
discount  that  we  had  in  the  past  that  was  dropped  several  years 
ago  that  was  a  very  popular  element  of  the  program. 

That  is  basically  the  program  that  Secretary  Espy  laid  out  about 
a  month  ago  for  crop  insurance.  We  are  very  glad  that  the  sub- 
committee has  held  prompt  hearings  on  it. 

We  hope  that  over  the  next  several  months  it  will  be  something 
that  farmers  will  look  at,  that  producers  will  look  at,  and  that  will 
be  the  subject  of  a  lot  of  debate. 

These  changes  will  only  work  well  if  everyone  is  comfortable  with 
them.  We  hope  that  all  parts  of  the  agricultural  community,  farm- 
ers, producer  groups,  lenders,  insurance  companies,  will  make  a 
point  to  study  our  plan  closely  and  to  get  involved  in  the  debate. 


89 

With  that,  I  will  cut  off  my  statement.  I  would  be  happy  to  an- 
swer any  questions  that  you  have. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Ackerman  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.!  .,      ,     •  •        e 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Ackerman.  It  was  the  decision  ot 
the  Chair  to  go  ahead  and  allow  Mr.  Ackerman  a  longer  period  of 
time  to  go  over  the  outline  of  the  crop  insurance  reform  proposal 
because  he  is  manager  of  the  FCIC,  and  I  thought  it  was  appro- 

We  will,  hereafter,  however,  abide  by  the  5-minute  rule.  A  red 
light  will  come  on,  and  we  will  limit  our  questions  from  the  panel 
to  5-minutes,  and  future  witnesses  will  also  try  to  meet  the  5- 

minute  rule  as  well.  ,    .  «     ^i.  4.  <- 

Mr.  Ackerman,  would  you  sum  up  for  us  briefly  the  current  fi- 
nancial status  of  this  crop  insurance  reform  proposal.  The  viability 
of  this  entire  proposal  is  dependent  on  our  being  able  to  take  the 
money  that  is  currently  being  used  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs 
and  rechannel  it,  at  least  most  of  it,  into  crop  insurance. 

The  House  has  passed  a  budget  resolution.  The  Senate  has  done 
something  that  does  not  involve  funding  for  this  program.  There  is 
a  conference  committee  going  on,  as  I  understand. 

Would  you  run  through  a  little  bit  about  the  future  of  this  be- 
cause obviously  the  one  thing  that  we  cannot  do  is  pass  a  crop  in- 
surance reform  proposal  and  then  have  it  so  under-funded  that  the 
thing  simply  will  not  work.  ^ 

Mr.  Ackerman.  This  is  a  very  important  point.  As  you  know. 
Congress  is  in  the  process  of  deliberating  on  the  congressional 
budget  resolution.  As  I  mentioned  before  and  as  you  mentioned, 
this  program  is  dependent  on  rechanneUng  that  billion  dollars  of 
ad  hoc  disaster  aid  into  the  crop  insurance  program. 

That  requires  us  to  change  the  budget  baselines.  Since  ad  hoc 
disaster  is  an  off-budget  program  and  crop  insurance  is  aii  on- 
budget  program,  we  need  to  change  the  agriculture  baseUne  in  the 
congressional  budget  resolution  by  about  $1  bilHon  in  order  to 

make  this  change.  . 

The  House  of  Representatives,  when  it  passed  its  version  ot  the 
budget  resolution  several  weeks  ago,  adopted  the  logic  of  our  posi- 
tion but  with  a  different  number.  The  baseline  was  adjusted  to  the 
tune  of,  instead  of  $1  billion  a  year,  it  was  $700  million  a  year  for 
the  four  out  years  and  a  smaller  amount  for  the  first  year.  This 
was  based  on  CBO  taking  a  different  view  of  the  numbers  from  the 

administration.  *,-  i  n- 

In  other  words,  their  total  is  $3  biUion  rather  than  $5  billion. 
However,  we  thought  it  was  a  very  positive  step  because  the  House 
had  adopted  the  logic  of  the  administration. 

On  the  Senate  side,  the  Senate  essentially  did  not  get  to  the 
issue.  As  you  know,  on  the  Senate  side  the  main  issue  and  conten- 
tion on  the  budget  resolution  was  whether  to  cut  an  additional  $26 

billion  in  spending.  ,  „      ,.  r- 

We  did  not  want  this  issue  to  get  in  the  middle  of  a  crosstire  on 
that  larger  spending  issue,  so  the  Senate  is  basically  neutral  on  the 
crop  insurance  baseline  adjustment. 


90 

This  issue  goes  to  a  conference  committee,  I  believe,  starting  the 
middle  of  next  week,  a  House-Senate  conference.  We  are  hoping 
that  conference  committee  will  make  the  full  baseline  adjustment. 

Since  the  House  took  one  position,  the  Senate  took  a  different  po- 
sition, this  is  a  conferenceable  item,  and  we  are  urging  the  con- 
ference to  make  the  full  baseline  adjustment. 

Mr.  Johnson.  At  this  point  it  appeared  to  me  that  neither  house 
had  adequate  funds  to  make  this  reform  viable,  and  it  is  going  to 
be  imperative  that  we  continue  to  work  with  the  conference  com- 
mittee members  in  both  the  House  and  the  Senate  to  give  us  great- 
er access  to  those  ad  hoc  disaster  funds.  Otherwise,  this  reform 
proposal  may,  in  fact,  be  stillborn. 

It  is  going  to  be  necessary  for  producers  to  purchase  buy-up  cov- 
erage, it  would  seem  to  me,  in  order  to  be  adequately  protected. 

Is  there  a  risk  that  too  many  producers  will  take  their  virtually 
free  catastrophic  coverage  and  feel  that  they  are  adequately  cov- 
ered and  not  be  aware,  as  much  as  they  ought,  about  the  need  to 
buy-up  greater  coverage  through  the  private  crop  insurance  indus- 
try? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  There  is  a  risk  of  that.  It  is  a  risk  that  we  try 
to  take  into  account  in  designing  this  program.  We  agree  very 
much  with  your  point  that  the  more  farmers  who  get  higher  levels 
of  coverage,  the  more  sound  the  program  will  be  and  the  better  pro- 
tected those  farmers  will  be. 

Catastrophic  coverage  should  not  be  misunderstood.  It  is  de- 
signed to  provide  a  level  of  payment,  simply  to  replace  a  disaster 
payment.  No  more,  no  less.  That  is  why  it  was  put  like  that. 

We  tried,  in  designing  this  program,  to  create  incentives  for 
farmers  to  buy  up.  That  is  why  we  have  the  targeted  financial  in- 
centives for  farmers  to  go  to  the  higher  levels. 

We  have  also  created  incentives  for  the  private  insurance  compa- 
nies to  sell  up.  Insurance  companies  will  get  a  better  administra- 
tive cost  subsidy  if  they  sell  up.  Agents  will  get  a  better  commis- 
sion if  they  sell  up.  So  the  incentives  are  on  both  sides. 

Yes,  there  is  a  risk.  We  expect  that  in  the  first  year  of  this  pro- 
gram probably  most  of  the  farmers  coming  in  will  get  that  cata- 
strophic coverage  simply  because  it  is  the  easiest  way  to  satisfy  the 
linkage  requirements. 

However,  we  are  hoping  that,  over  time,  once  they  get  into  the 
program,  once  they  go  through  the  mechanics  of  establishing  their 
AHP  yield,  produce  their  records,  and  learn  what  the  program  is 
about,  they  will  go  to  those  higher  levels  of  coverage. 

Particularly,  frankly,  once  we  have  a  year  with  major  losses  and 
Congress  does  not  pass  a  major  disaster  relief  bill,  that  will  prob- 
ably be  the  major  cause  that  gets  this  program  off  the  ground. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  Chair  recognizes  Representative  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Ackerman,  we  had  this  discussion  in  committee  about  the 
pilot  program,  and  you  said  you  were  proceeding  with  that  and 
were  going  to  have  some  kind  of  report  by  June.  Do  I  remember 
right? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  This  is  on  cost  of  production  coverage? 

Mr.  Peterson.  Right. 


91 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  have  asked  the  Economic  Research  Service 
of  USDA  to  do  a  study  on  this.  We  have  gotten  back  some  prelimi- 
nary information  on  that  and  we  are  hoping  to  make  some  decision 
on  that  in  the  near  future. 

Mr.  Peterson.  For  those  folks  that  are  not  aware,  I  have  put 
some  report  language  into  a  bill.  What  was  it,  last  year? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes.  The  reconciliation  bill. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Right.  Which  would  require  the  Department  to 
look  at  a  pilot  program  in  North  Dakota,  Minnesota  and  Mis- 
sissippi, looking  at  some  kind  of  revenue  insurance  based  on  reve- 
nue or  cost  of  production.  Kind  of  like  hail  insurance,  a  different 

concept. 

They  are  moving  ahead  with  that.  If  we  can  get  it  together,  peo- 
ple might  have  the  opportunity  to  opt  into  that  pilot  program  in 
those  three  States,  which  I  think  could  be  useful.  ,     ,.«. 

Yesterday,  I  had  some  meetings  in  my  district  with  different 
folks.  On  this  mandatory  issue,  in  Stems  County,  for  example, 
when  we  didn't  have  a  lot  of  people  proving  yields,  they  have  a  real 
problem  with  their  bases  being  way  down. 

They  think,  at  looking  at  the  preliminary  situation  with  your 
proposal,  that  given  the  circumstance  with  their  bases  and  how 
they  are  participating  in  farm  programs  now,  that  this  might  have 
the  effect  of  driving  people  out  of  the  farm  program  in  Stems 
County.  That  was  pretty  much  consensus  because  their  bases  are 
so  low,  their  com  bases,  that  it  is  not  going  to  be  a  good  deal. 

I  guess  maybe  that  is  backwards  though.  You  can  be  in  the  pro- 
gram and  you  don't  have  to  buy  insurance. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  That's  correct. 

Mr.  Peterson.  But  then  they  are  left  with  no  coverage  is  how 
they  are  looking  at  it. 

I  guess  the  question  I  am  asking  is,  is  there  some  way  that  we 
can  go  in  and  look  at  particular  situations  where  they  have  gotten 
trapped?  A  situation  where  the  basis  is  not  realistic  as  to  what  it 

really  is?  ,        v       r    j      i  4. 

The  other  problem  we  have  in  that  county  is  that  they  teed  a  lot 
of  that  com,  and  there  is  really— from  what  I  can  tell  talking  to 
them  yesterday— there  is  no  mechanism  to  really  account  for  that 
in  a  good  way.  They  are  having  a  lot  of  trouble  accounting  for  the 
com  that  is  fed  and  getting  credit  for  it.  ^   ,         i  •   j 

So  I  think  in  Stems  and  Morrison  Counties,  some  of  those  kind 
of  counties  where  you  have  got  a  lot  of  livestock  and  dairy  and  so 
forth,  I  think  we  have  a  different  kind  of  a  problem  that  we  haven't 
really  focused  in  on.  I  would  like  to  visit  with  you  about  that  or 
your  people  because  I  think  we  are  going  to  cause  some  problems 
out  there  if  we  don't  address  this  some  how  or  another. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Let  me  comment  just  briefly  on  this. 

First  of  all,  as  we  go  through  the  hearing  process  on  this  legisla- 
tion, it  is  very  important  that  we  make— from  our  ppint  of  view  as 
well— that  we  make  sure  that  this  program  works  in  different  parts 
of  the  country,  so  we  very  much  want  to  look  at  these  particular 
counties  to  make  sure  that  the  formula  works,  that  the  program 
works. 


81-128  0-94-4 


92 

So  we  will  be  very  eager  to  talk  to  you  about  that  to  make  sure 
we  are  on  the  same  wavelength,  that  we  will  be  able  to  accommo- 
date that  situation. 

Just  to  be  clear  on  the  bases,  on  the  yields,  the  way  we  are  pro- 
posing to  structure  this  catastrophic  coverage,  it  would  be  based  on 
an  individual's  APH  yield,  actual  production  history  yield. 

So  you  would  bring  in  records,  establish  your  own  yield,  and  that 
would  be  the  basis  for  coverage,  rather  than  using  a  program  yield 
or  a  county  average  yield. 

Mr.  Peterson.  What  do  they  have  to  bring  in?  Can  they  bring 
farm  management  records? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Yes.  There  is  a  fair  amount  of  flexibility  on  what 
they  can  bring  in. 

It  is  true  that  for  the  situations  with  farmer  who  feed  their  com, 
who  raise  com  and  then  feed  it  on  their  property,  who  don't  sell 
it,  it  is  sometimes  more  difficult  to  get  records.  In  those  cases,  we 
have  to  be  more  flexible,  and  we  may  want  to  look  again  within 
FCIC  to  make  sure  that  we  we've  provided  enough  flexibility  for 
that. 

Clearly,  we  want  those  farmers  to  be  using  actual  yields  as  well 
because  they  generally  get  a  better  deal  based  on  actual  yields 
than  program  yields. 

We  have  taken  some  steps  to  allow  farmers  to  use  certain  evi- 
dences of  what  they  have  grown.  For  instance,  the  number  of  bins 
that  they  use,  the  sizes  of  bins.  Things  like  that  to  show  their 
yields.  If  we  need  to  provide  better  avenues  to  show  their  yields, 
we  can  look  at  doing  that,  but  using  actual  yields  generally  pro- 
vides a  better  outcome. 

If  I  could  say  one  more  point  without  going  too  far  into  the  red 
light.  There  are  a  number  of  cases  where  going  to  actual  yields 
does  place  farmers  at  a  disadvantage  because  there  are  some  parts 
of  the  country  where  yields  simply  have  not  been  very  good  the 
past  couple  of  years.  We  have  had  a  disaster  year  this  year  with 
the  flood.  There  have  been  other  recent  disaster  years  as  well. 

One  change  that  we  are  going  to  have  to  make  in  the  APH  actual 
production  history  program  is  a  catastrophic  yield  adjustment  for 
at  least  1  year,  because  there  are  simply  too  many  areas  where 
farmers  have  had  catastrophic  years  and  their  yields  are  inappro- 
priately low. 

The  APH  program  is  designed  to  come  up  with  a  realistic  expec- 
tation of  what  a  farmer  on  a  particular  piece  of  land  is  going  to 
produce.  A  zero  jdeld  for  a  given  year  is  just  as  unrealistic  a  projec- 
tion as  an  inflated  yield  in  an  inflated  year  so  that  is  one  change 
that  we  are  going  to  have  to  make. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Representative  Minge. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I  had  a  couple  of  questions,  Mr.  Ackerman.  First,  I've 
noticed  that  some  farmers  in  1993  were  in  the  0/92  program  which 
meant  that  they  plowed  up  their  com  and  they  had  no  yield,  and 
it  was  not  counted  as  a  base  year  in  calculating  the  average  pro- 
duction on  that  farm. 

Other  farmers  decided  not  to  plow  up  the  crop  and  instead  har- 
vested it,  and  they  may  have  received,  let's  say,  35  bushels  to  an 
acre  and  that  was  then  considered  one  of  the  years. 


93 

Is  there  a  way  that  you  can  reconcile  the  different  ways  that 
farmers  use  the  farm  program  in  a  year  like  we  had  last  year  and 
not  penalize  those  that  tried  to  harvest  a  crop  and  minimize  those 
losses  as  against  those  that  went  into  0/92  and  eliminate  their 
crop? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  It  is  an  interesting  question  on  this.  I  may  say 
I  may  ask  our  chief  actuary  to  comment. 

As  a  general  matter,  yes,  obviously,  we  need  to  do  that.  One  of 
the  things  that  is  going  on  parallel  to  this  reform  is  that,  within 
USD  A,  we  are  in  the  midst  of  a  reorganization  where  we  are  going 
to  be  merged  into  ASCS  to  become  a  single  agency. 

As  we  do  that  we  are  going  to  have  to  align  the  programs  to 
make  sure  that  a  farmer  is  not  disadvantaged  being  in  one  as  op- 
posed to  the  other. 

In  the  particular  situation  of  the  0/92  versus  crop  insurance,  I 
understand  there  has  been  some  confusion  about  how  those  rules 
work. 

Let  me  introduce  Jim  Driscoll  who  is  the  Chief  Actuary  of  the 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation. 

Mr.  Driscoll.  Mr.  Minge,  the  point  you  raised  is  interesting.  It 
is  one  I  think  we  will  have  to  handle  through  our  catastrophic  yield 
adjustment  procedure  that  we  are  now  developing  that  Mr.  Acker- 
man  talked  about  just  a  moment  ago. 

I  am  not  sure  exactly  how  it  will  be  brought  in  at  this  time,  but 
I  think  our  goal  would  be  to  recognize  what  the  crop  would  have 
produced  in  a  normal  year.  That  is  what  we  are  trying  to  do 
through  this  cat  yield  procedure,  not  to  count  the  zeros  or  the  real 
low  yield,  but  with  some  floor  in  there. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  So  the  goal  is  to  look  for  what  is  a  normal  year,  how- 
ever, those  figures  are  developed,  and  not  let  a  catastrophic  year, 
whether  you  are  in  a  program  or  not,  in  a  program  like  0/92,  skew 
the  results? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Correct. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Well,  it  feels  good.  I  hope  that  it  is. 

The  second  question  I  have  deals  with  the  problem  of  farmers 
who,  so  to  speak,  farm  Federal  crop  insurance.  I  haven't  heard  of 
that  as  a  problem  in  our  area  as  much  as  it  is  in  other  States  to 
the  south  and  east  of  here. 

It  concerns  me  that  a  catastrophic  program  where  we  have  50 
percent  coverage  at  60  percent  of  the  projected  price  may  actually 
be  the  type  of  program  that  those  farmers  in  the  Southern  and 
Eastern  States  find  to  their  liking  because  they  can  essentially 
farm  Federal  crop  insurance,  whereas  the  farmers  in  our  area  very 
rarely  would  experience  a  50  percent  crop  loss.  Maybe  last  year 
was  the  first  year  in  the  history  of  many  of  our  counties  that  they 
had  a  crop  loss  at  that  level. 

How  do  you  propose  to  work  with  this  new  proposal  to  avoid  a 
situation  where  certain  sections  of  the  country  will  continue  to 
farm  Federal  crop  insurance,  to  the  disadvantage  of  other  sections 
of  the  country  who  are  trying  to  simply  farm  based  on  what  the 
economy  indicates  is  a  decent  result? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  I  think  your  point  is  a  very  important  one.  If  we 
are  going  to  expand  crop  insurance  from  30  percent  participation 


94 

to  80  percent,  we  have  to  be  able  to  guarantee  this  program  is  run 
with  integrity. 

Program  compliance  has  to  be  one  of  our  paramount  objectives. 

In  the  past  we  have  had  problems  with  program  compliance.  We 
now  have  a  compliance  stsiff  at  FCIC  of  about  80  people  nation- 
wide, which  is  frankly  not  enough.  We  have  a  lot  of  territory  to 
cover. 

In  some  parts  of  the  country  there  have  been  indictments  against 
people  for  not  only  farming  the  program  but  committing  fraud  with 
respect  to  the  program.  This  is  something  that  we  have  to  crack 
down  on. 

We  are  taking  a  number  of  steps  to  do  this,  and  it  is  something 
that  we  have  to  do  more  of.  This  is  one  area  where  our  merger  into 
ASCS  may  turn  out  to  be  very  helpful  because  we  can  share  re- 
sources with  ASCS's  compliance  operation.  We  can  have  access  to 
their  county  offices  on  the  ground  where  they  are  often  closer  to 
the  scene  than  we  are,  in  order  to  help  make  sure  that  people  are 
working  with  this  program  in  the  proper  ways. 

We  are  also  planning  to  sit  down  with  the  crop  insurance  compa- 
nies because  they  have  a  stake  in  this  also.  They  have  a  financial 
stake  in  this.  When  there  are  losses  in  the  program,  they  take 
losses. 

This  year  I  think  that  fact  was  brought  home  more  than  any 
other  year.  Collectively,  the  private  crop  insurance  companies  had 
some  very  significant  losses. 

We  also  intend  to  work  with  the  Inspector  Greneral's  office  of 
USDA. 

Clearly,  this  question  of  program  compliance  is  something  we 
have  to  put  on  a  front  burner  if  we  are  going  to  be  credible  in  this 
proposal. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Thank  you.  The  Chairman  didn't  tell  me  if  he 
wanted  us  to  do  another  round,  but  I  am  going  to  take  the  preroga- 
tive of  the  Chair  and  ask. 

One  of  the  other  things  that  came  up  in  my  meeting  yesterday 
focused  on  this  $50  per  crop  per  county  deal  and  whether  it  would 
make  more  sense  to  base  this  on  so  much  per  acre,  some  small 
amount  per  acre. 

My  question  is  did  you  look  at  that  issue  and  if  you  did,  why  did 
you  opt  for  the  system  that  you've  set  up?  I  assume  you  probably 
did  this  to  try  to  get  the  southerners,  who  are  not  wild  about  this 
idea,  to  come  into  the  program,  but  I  guess  I  would  just  be  curious 
as  to  whether  that  went  through  your  deliberation  or  not. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  did  look  at  that  and  that  is  still  a  point  that 
comes  up  in  quite  a  lot  of  meetings. 

The  reason  we  chose  a  $50  processing  fee  rather  than  a  dollar 
per  acre  amount  was  we  wanted  to  make  it  clear  that  this  is  not 
premium  that  is  being  paid. 

The  government  is  paying  the  premium,  much,  like  I  said,  as  a 
rainy  day  fund.  What  the  farmer  is  paying  is  the  cost  of  filing  the 
papers.  That  is  why  a  processing  fee  of  a  set  amount  makes  sense 
rather  than  trying  to  come  up  with  a  formula  based  on  the  size  of 
the  farm. 


95 

It  is  true  that  if  a  farm  is  big  enough  to  be  in  two  or  three  coun- 
ties the  fee  can  be  raised  to  several  hundreds  of  dollars,  but  within 
a  county  it  is  $50  no  matter  on  the  size. 

The  reason  that  we  wanted  to  pick  a  low  number  like  that  was 
because  of  the  mandatory  linkage.  We  felt  that  the  mandatory  link- 
age was  very  important  for  this  program  to  work  right  and  that  if 
that  was  going  to  be  acceptable  in  a  broad  way  we  needed  to  have 
a  processing  fee  that  was  reasonable. 

Mr.  Peterson.  I  guess  the  Chairman  has  a  couple  of  more  ques- 
tions, so  I  will  just  follow-up. 

I  want  to  visit  with  your  actuary  about  what  the  numbers  are 
and  so  forth.  On  the  top  coverages,  85,  75  and  65,  you  have  some 
buy  down  that  is  going  to  be  made  by  the  government  in  the  pre- 
miums. 

It  is  unclear  to  me — maybe  it  says  in  there  and  I  just  missed  it — 
do  you  have  actual  amounts  on  that?  What  are  the  levels  at  each 
level? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  If  you  buy  65  percent  yield  coverage,  the  way  our 
proposal  is  written  right  now  you  would  get  an  out-of-pocket  dis- 
count of  about  15  to  16  percent. 

If  you  get  75  percent  level  coverage,  you  would  get  an  out-of- 
pocket  discount  of  about  8  or  9  percent. 

Mr.  Peterson.  What  about  85  percent? 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  Eighty-five  percent  we  are  currently  going  to 
offer,  and  under  this  legislation  we  would  have  the  authority  to 
begin  offering  it.  We  have  not  run  the  numbers  on  it  yet  because 
it  is  not  something  that  comes  through  that. 

Mr.  Peterson.  If  you  can  fit  this  in,  would  you  envision  giving 
some  kind  of  discount  on  that  as  well? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Yes.  The  way  the  formula  works  that  downward 
slope  would  probably  continue. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Why  don't  you  discount  the  levels  the  same  as 
the  65  percent  and  75  percent?  Is  there  some  reason  why  you  have 
different  discount  levels? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  The  reason  we  did  that  is  because  of  the  way  the 
formula  runs. 

I  will  tell  you  frankly  that  since  we  have  sent  this  bill  forward 
several  people  have  made  the  suggestion  of  why  not  take  some  of 
the  money  we  are  proposing  to  spend  at  the  65  percent  level,  and 
spend  it  at  the  75  percent  level,  in  order  to  make  that  more  attrac- 
tive. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Yes.  That  is  what  I  was  thinking.  Are  you  looking 
at  that? 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Yes. 

Mr.  Peterson.  Also,  at  the  85  percent  level  the  discussion  came 
up  in  my  meeting  that  there  should  be  some  consideration  given 
there  as  well. 

To  some  extent  I  think  this  ties  into  the  yield  question  and  the 
base  question  because  what  people  are  getting  at  is  trjdng  to  figure 
out  some  way  to  make  a  system  that  works. 

You  can  come  at  it  two  different  ways.  You  can  come  at  it  from 
the  base  or  from  the  premium  level,  so  I  am  glad  to  hear  you  are 
looking  at  that. 

The  chairman  is  back.  I  guess  he  has  some  additional  questions. 


96 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you  for  taking  over,  Representative  Peter- 
son, 

Are  there  any  further  questions  by  members  of  the  panel? 

Well,  Thank  you,  Mr.  Ackerman,  for  your  testimony  and  your  re- 
sponse to  our  questions,  and  we  will  turn  now  to  our  second  panel. 

Mr.  Ackerman.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  second  panel  is  comprised  of  Mr.  Al 
Christopherson  who  is  President  of  the  Minnesota  Farm  Bureau 
Federation  of  Pennock,  Minnesota;  Mr.  Richard  Peterson  who  is 
vice  president  of  the  Minnesota  Com  Growers  on  behalf  of  the  Min- 
nesota corn  growers  and  soybean  producers  of  Mountain  Lake, 
Minnesota;  Mr.  Frances  Buschette  who  is  a  member  of  the  Min- 
nesota Wheat  Growers  of  Renville,  Minnesota;  Mr.  Grerald  Lacey 
who  is  president  of  the  National  Barley  Growers  Association;  and 
Mr.  Dave  Frederickson  who  is  president  of  the  Minnesota  Farmers 
Union  of  Murdock,  Minnesota. 

We  welcome  you  to  this  subcommittee  hearing.  We  are  very 
grateful  for  your  willingness  to  share  with  us  your  insights  and 
where  this  country  should  be  going  relative  to  crop  insurance  and 
disaster  programs  in  general. 

Your  full  statements  are  received  for  the  record  of  the  sub- 
committee, but  you  may  want  to  summarize.  Whatever  you  are 
most  comfortable  with.  Try  to  keep  your  statement  within  5  min- 
utes. 

We  will  proceed  in  order.  We  will  have  each  of  you  testify  first 
prior  to  members  of  the  committee  asking  you  questions. 

We  will  begin  with  Mr.  AI  Christopherson. 

STATEMENT  OF  AL  CHRISTOPHERSON,  PRESIDENT, 
MINNESOTA  FARM  BUREAU  FEDERATION 

Mr.  Christopherson.  Thank  you.  I  want  to  thank  you  for  the 
opportunity  to  comment  on  Federal  crop  insurance  reform  and  its 
impact  on  Minnesota  farmers. 

I  certainly  would  like  to  commend  the  subcommittee  Chairman 
Johnson  and  Representatives  Minge  and  Peterson  for  bringing  this 
important  hearing  to  Minnesota  to  hear  from  farmers  firsthand. 

I  would  also  like  to  commend  the  Clinton  administration  for  rec- 
ognizing the  tremendous  need  for  reform  of  the  Federal  crop  insur- 
ance disaster  programs. 

With  a  national  utilization  rate  of  less  than  30  percent,  the  an- 
nual average  disaster  payments  of  over  $1  billion  a  year,  the  time 
has  come  to  completely  overhaul  a  system  that  isn't  working  for  ei- 
ther farmers  or  taxpayers. 

Secretary  Espy  has  accurately  commented  that  the  current  pro- 
grams high  premiums  and  spotted  coverage  combined  with  a  disas- 
ter program  to  virtually  guarantee  low  participation  in  the  pro- 
gram. 

The  time  to  reform  the  system  in  a  serious  and  comprehensive 
manner  is  long  overdue.  The  existing  combination  of  inadequate 
coverage  in  disaster  programs  satisfy  no  one  who  is  involved. 

The  stated  goal  of  the  Clinton  reform  proposal  is  to  boost  partici- 
pation in  the  crop  insurance  program  by  providing  adequate  cov- 


97 

erage  to  producers  and  thereby  eliminating  the  need  for  emergency 
disaster  assistance. 

The  Farm  Bureau  fully  agrees  with  this  central  goal,  and  are 
committed  to  helping  this  restructuring  occur. 

Farm  Bureau  policy  states  that  crop  disaster  programs  and  crop 
insurance  should  be  combined  into  a  single  voluntary  program  de- 
signed to  obtain  the  greatest  amount  of  participation.  We  can  all 
agree  that  today's  pattern  should  be  replaced  with  a  more  common 
sense  and  responsible  model. 

As  you  know,  the  Clinton  plan  compels  farmers  to  purchase  the 
minimum  amount  of  Federal  insurance  on  eligible  crops  before  par- 
ticipating in  any  USD  A  program. 

This  mandatory  part  of  the  program  is  our  most  fundamental 
and  practical  and  philosophical  objection  to  the  reform  plan.  An  un- 
attractive crop  insurance  policy  cannot  be  made  to  look  pretty  to 
farmers  simply  by  mandating  programs  participation. 

This  avoidance  of  the  crop  insurance  program's  basic  inadequa- 
cies will  not  result  in  a  long-term  solution  to  the  problem.  We  need 
a  program  that  makes  crop  insurance  a  good  idea  in  the  free  mar- 
ketplace. 

TTie  shortcut  provided  by  mandated  coverage  virtually  assures 
that  budgetary  and  other  pressures  will  continue  to  force  a  Federal 
crop  insurance  program  that  simply  does  not  make  sense  economi- 
cally to  the  typical  farmer.  This  is  precisely  why  participation  is  so 
low  nationwide  today. 

The  mandatory  provisions  combined  with  a  cost  that  is  bound  to 
grow  with  time  and  budgetary  pressures  also  establishes  a  state 
control  mechanism  that  could  become  extremely  costly  to  farmers. 

Although  the  fees  for  catastrophic  coverage  are  very  limited  in 
the  initial  proposal,  fiscal  reality  suggests  that  this  pricing  system 
may  not  remain  inexpensive  very  long. 

Our  policy  has  consistently  opposed  mandatory  linkages  between 
crop  insurance  and  farm  program  eligibility.  The  most  cross-compli- 
ance restriction  and  mandatory  conditions  we  add  to  Federal  pro- 
grams, the  less  basic  business  decisions  are  left  up  to  the  farmer 
in  the  marketplace. 

In  addition,  our  members  oppose  the  programs'  continued  reli- 
ance on  yield  as  the  trigger  mechanism  for  insurance  payout.  Cov- 
erage based  on  dollars  per  acre  to  us  seem  to  make  more  sense.  Re- 
liance on  yield  as  a  determinant  tends  to  skew  the  program  in 
favor  of  high-risk  production  acres,  and  makes  it  much  more  likely 
that  gaps  in  coverage  will  exist. 

Although  we  recognize  that  full  consideration  of  crop  instance  re- 
form may  not  occur  until  the  1995  farm  bill,  we  pledge  our  commit- 
ment to  work  with  the  administration  and  Congress  to  design  a 
workable  program  that  meets  all  of  our  goals. 

I  am  convinced  that  all  psirties  can  come  together  to  fix  a  system 
that  is  clearly  broken.  Again,  however,  in  order  to  do  that  we  must 
design  an  insurance  program  that  good  business  people  will  want 
to  purchase,  and  we  don't  feel  that  wider  mandated  coverage  will 
eliminate  the  possibilities  and  further  complicates  the  maze  of  Grov- 
emment  requirements. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Al  Christopherson  appears  at  the 
conclusion  of  the  hearing.] 


98 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Christopherson. 
Mr.  Peterson. 

STATEMENT  OF  RICHARD  PETERSON  ON  BEHALF  OF  THE  MIN- 
NESOTA CORN  GROWERS  ASSOCIATION  AND  THE  MIN- 
NESOTA SOYBEAN  GROWERS  ASSOCIATION 

Mr.  Peterson.  I  am  Richard  Peterson.  I  am  representing  the 
Minnesota  Com  Growers  and  the  Minnesota  Soybean  Growers  here 
today. 

I  want  to  thank  the  committee  for  coming  to  southern  Minnesota 
to  hear  our  concerns  regarding  Federal  crop  insurance  reform, 

I  farm  just  east  of  here  in  Jackson  County. 

I  would  also  like  to  introduce  the  State  director  of  the  Minnesota 
Soybean  Association  who  is  here  today  in  the  audience,  Leroy 
Kellenberg  from  Beaver  Creek. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Welcome  to  the  subcommittee. 

Mr.  Peterson.  We  have  put  our  written  statement  together  and 
you  have  that. 

Our  main  concern  would  be  the  top  end  coverage.  I  have  had 
Federal  crop  insurance  over  the  years.  From  1986  to  1992  we  have 
had  the  1988  drought  and  also  1991,  which  was  an  extremely  wet 
year. 

The  65  percent  coverage  just  doesn't  do  it.  We  come  up  with  a 
65  percent  crop,  but  with  toda3^s  prices  it  is  just  not  enough  to 
cover  expenses. 

What  we  would  really  like  to  stress  is  that  we  can  get  that  75 
percent  coverage  for  at  least  what  it  costs  us  today  for  the  65  per- 
cent coverage,  and  that  the  85  percent  coverage  should  be  available 
to  farmers. 

There  is  another  concern  we  have  with  the  group  risk  plan.  The 
problem  with  that,  using  county  averages,  is  that  the  soil  types 
from  one  farm  to  another  let  alone  from  one  side  of  the  county  to 
the  other,  varies.  And  I  don't  think  that  it  would  be  a  fair  program 
for  the  farmers. 

The  production  needs  to  be  based  on  the  yields  coming  off  of  the 
particular  farm  that  is  insured. 

Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Richard  Peterson  appears  at  the  con- 
clusion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Peterson. 

We  will  turn  now  to  Mr.  Buschette. 

STATEMENT  OF  FRANCIS  BUSCHETTE  ON  BEHALF  OF  THE 
MINNESOTA  ASSOCIATION  OF  WHEAT  GROWERS 

Mr.  Buschette.  Thank  you.  My  name  is  Francis  Buschette  and 
I  farm  near  Renville,  Minnesota  and  raise  wheat,  sugar  beets,  com 
and  soybeans. 

I  am  testifying  on  behalf  of  the  Minnesota  Association  of  Wheat 
Growers.  We  appreciate  this  opportunity  to  express  our  views  on 
the  proposed  Federal  crop  insurance  reform  and  whether  it  could 
adequately  replace  the  disaster  program. 

Let  me  begin  by  sa5ring  that  the  Minnesota  Association  of  Wheat 
Growers  would  support  a  significantly  improved  better  crop  insur- 
ance program  over  the  disaster  programs  we  have  had  in  the  past. 


99 

We  recognize  the  funding  problems  associated  with  having  both 
an  improved  crop  insureince  program  and  a  standing  disaster  pro- 
gram. However,  we  believe  an  adequate,  affordable  and  proven  new 
insurance  program  should  be  operational  before  all  disaster  author- 
ity is  abandoned. 

A  strong  basis  for  development  of  a  viable  new  program  is  on  the 
drawing  board,  but  until  such  a  time  that  a  new  regime  of  jdeld 
and  price  risk  protection  is  proven  to  be  effective,  we  urge  contin- 
ued standby  authority  for  disaster  relief  programs. 

On  the  specifics  of  crop  insurance  reform,  we  strongly  support 
the  actual  production  history  based  on  4  years.  However,  a  high 
priority  for  FCIC  should  be  to  develop  and  implement  a  cata- 
strophic yield  clause.  This  would  stop  the  actual  production  history 
yield  reductions  for  producers  in  a  region  that  has  experienced  ab- 
normally high  losses  during  the  4  years  of  the  APH. 

This  need  is  very  evident  in  Minnesota  when  you  consider  that 
the  loss  is  due  to  a  100-year  flood  will  account  for  25  percent  of  an 
individual's  APH. 

On  the  positive  side,  the  decision  to  use  individusd  APH  as  a 
base  for  catastrophic  yield  coverage  instead  of  an  average  or  ASCS 
3deld  is  very  important  and  it  is  a  welcomed  improvement  over  the 
disaster  program. 

In  another  comparison,  we  find  that  the  disaster  program  has  ad- 
vantage over  Federal  crop  insurance  when  it  comes  to  de  minimus 
yields.  The  lack  of  a  de  minimus  yield  for  crop  insurance  has  been 
a  glaring  negative  factor  for  growers,  especially  in  light  of  ASCS 
implementing  a  de  minimus  jdeld  in  last  year's  disaster  program. 
This  inequality  needs  to  be  corrected. 

For  many  wheat  producers,  the  catastrophic  coverage  will  not  be 
adequate  to  meet  their  risk  management  needs,  so  they  will  want 
to  purchase  additional  insurance.  The  reform  proposal  with  addi- 
tional funding  should  provide  reductions  in  premiums  at  the  higher 
coverage  levels. 

This  would  be  very  important  for  long-term  crop  insurance  cus- 
tomers who  will  want  to  see  benefits  from  reform. 

One  possible  benefit  could  be  reduced  premiums  at  the  65  and 
75  percent  coverage  levels  under  the  proposed  reforms.  Neverthe- 
less, what  effect  this  reform  proposal  will  actually  have  on  pre- 
miums for  increased  coverage  is  something  we  will  want  to  know. 

Finally,  we  believe  that  additional  premium  subsidies  should  be 
extended  to  the  65  and  75  percent  coverage  levels,  which  would 
help  make  this  reform  package  adequate  enough  to  replace  disaster 
programs. 

Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  express  our  views. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Buschette  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Buschette.  You  are  hearing  evi- 
dence that  our  part  of  the  country  is  not  exclusively  Johnsons, 
Christophersons,  Petersons  and  Fredericksons.  It's  good  to  have 
you  here. 

Mr.  Lacey. 


100 


STATEMENT  OF  GERALD  LACEY,  PRESIDENT  OF  NATIONAL 
BARLEY  GROWERS  ASSOCIATION 

Mr.  Lacey.  Good  morning.  My  name  is  Gerald  Lacey  and  I  grow 
barley,  wheat  and  sugar  beets  with  my  son  on  a  farm  near  Camp- 
bell. 1  m  currently  serving  as  president  of  the  National  Barley 
Growers  Association  It's  an  honor  for  me  to  be  here  this  morning 
and  testify  in  front  of  this  subcommittee. 

We  as  farmers  understand  that  reform  is  needed  to  keep  abreast 
with  the  ever-changing  world.  We  also  understand  the  difference 
between  meaningful  reform  and  budget-driven  poHtical  reform.  It's 
ditlicult  for  me  to  testify  on  this  proposal  when  the  Senate  just 
voted  to  reduce  expenditures  for  crop  insurance. 

I  would  hope  that  you,  as  elected  officials,  would  put  aside  the 
political  bickering  and  assist  us  producers  in  estabUshing  a  Federal 
crop  insurance  policy  that  would  adequately  protect  us  from  the 
whimsical  ways  of  Mother  Nature.  I  would  Uke  to  address  three 
main  concerns  in  my  testimony  this  morning. 

4.u^^al^  ni^^'}  ^°^^*^  ^^^®  ^°  address  the  percentage  of  subsidy  for 
the  65,  75  ^d  the  85  percent  price  protection;  second,  consider  al- 
lowing AbCS  to  possibly  sell  the  coverage;  third,  to  support  a  gross 
xT^^^^^  insurance  pilot  program  for  Minnesota,  Mississippi  and 
North  Dakota. 

We  agree  that  catastrophic  coverage  must  be  offered  to  producers 
m  order  to  get  participation  up  to  the  level  where  everyone  will  feel 
comfortable  that  there  will  be  no  more  ad  hoc  disaster  bills  We 
would  suggest  increasing  the  rate  of  the  subsidy  provided  for  en- 
rollment in  the  65,  also  the  75,  and  in  the  85  percent  level  of  price 
protection  Producers  are  being  pushed  into  higher  price  selections 
becaoise  of  the  constant  increase  in  the  cost  of  production;  also  as 
It  effects  our  yield,  our  yield  history  in  these  losses  that  we've  had 
over  the  last  few  years. 

iolr?^i^®  taken  out  Federal  crop  insurance  from  my  agent  since 
1989.  During  this  time,  I  had  no  way  to  shop  around,  as  I  do  for 
hail.  For  hail  insurance,  there  seems  to  be  some  competition  and 
there  is  no  Government  guaranteed  commission.  I  would  like  to 
suggest  that  we  allow  the  ASCS  offices  to  opportunity  to  sell  Fed- 
eral crop  insurance  policies.  This  is  not  new  or  unique,  but  some- 
thing they  have  handled  in  the  past. 
I  would  also  suggest  that  the  ASCS  offices  be  allowed  to  charge 

^  ■^?j^u^^  j^^  ^®®  ^°  ^°^^^  ^^^^^  ^°^^^  °^  ^°^^S  business.  Perhaps  this 
could  be  done  on  a  pilot  project  basis  and  perhaps  even  on  a  bid- 
ding basis  by  the  private  insurance  industries  to  compete  with  the 

ASCS. 

I  make  this  suggestion  in  the  hopes  that  the  insurance  compa- 
nies will  be  challenged  to  make  their  money  competitively  in  the 
market,  not  through  a  controlled,  guaranteed  system.  The  burden 
of  balancing  the  budget  should  not  have  to  be  borne  solely  by  the 
producers  and  not  by  the  rest  of  the  industry. 

Third,  a  pilot  program  that  has  been  mentioned  already  this 
morning.  As  a  representative  of  the  Minnesota  Barley  Growers  As- 
sociation, I  would  like  to  speak  in  support  of  introducing  a  gross 
revenue  insurance  program  on  a  trial  basis  in  Minnesota,  Mis- 
sissippi, and  North  Dakota.  My  thoughts  behind  this  are  fairW  sim- 
ple. 


101 

Lenders  are  not  at  all  concerned  about  how  many  bushels  a  pro- 
ducer grows  on  an  acre,  but  rather  how  many  dollars  per  acre  that 
farmer  produces.  We  would  like  to  see  if  we  couldn't  devise  a  pro- 
gram that  would  have  a  farmer  insure  his  gross  revenue. 

Although  many  of  the  technical  points  would  have  to  be  worked 
out,  I  envision  a  program  whereby  a  producer  would  be  able  to  in- 
sure his  minimum  gross  income  based  on  perhaps  his  last  5  years 
average  gross  income  as  shown  on  his  individual  tax  form. 

I'd  like  to  thank  the  subcommittee  for  allowing  us  to  testify  this 
morning.  I'd  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Lacey  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Lacey.  Finally,  Mr.  Frederickson. 

STATEMENT  OF  DAVE  FREDERICKSON,  PRESIDENT, 
MINNESOTA  FARMERS  UNION 

Mr.  Frederickson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  want  to  point 
out  that  even  though  Mr.  Buschette's  name  is  different  from  the 
rest  of  us,  he  has  been  influenced  by  the  Scandinavians  in  his  area. 
I  also  want  to  thank  you.  Chairman  Johnson,  and  members  of  the 
subcommittee  for  your  willingness  to  come  into  Representative 
Minge's  district,  one  of  the  hardest  hit  districts  by  the  flooding  in 
1983. 

I've  spent  the  last  few  days  reading  about  Federal  crop  insur- 
ance, to  the  point  where  my  eyes  have  started  to  glaze  over,  most 
recently  about  10:00  last  night.  Normally,  all  I  do  is  buy  it.  When 
I  started  to  farm  in  1974,  which  is  coming  up  on  20  years  now,  I 
asked  my  dad  if  it  would  be  a  good  idea  if  I  buy  this  stuff  called 
Federal  crop  insurance  and  he  informed  me  that  it  probably  wasn't 
such  a  good  idea  because  he  had  farmed  all  of  his  life  and  he  never 
got  a  red  cent  out  of  them. 

All  he  had  to  do  was  pay  the  premium  and  being  a  smart-aleck 
kid,  I  thought,  well,  maybe  I  should  try  to  buy  some  of  this  stuff, 
and  I  have  over  the  years  bought  it  on  and  off  again.  I  chose  a 
rather  smart  move,  I  thought,  in  1993  to  drop  the  coverage.  I 
laughed  a  little  bit  about  that,  too,  when  I  dropped  it,  but  then  I 
got  pretty  panicky  about  halfway  through  the  summer. 

But  then  as  it  turned  out,  even  with  the  worst  flooding  in  my 
history  and  I'm  sure  the  history  of  many  of  the  people  in  this  room, 
we  in  Swift  came  in  with  about  half  a  crop.  So  at  the  50  percent 
level,  I,  with  the  jdeld  I  had  of  about  52  bushel  an  acre,  still  would 
not  have  ended  up  receiving  the  cost  of  that  premium,  and,  in  this 
case,  that's  something  in  excess  of  $3,000  had  I  gone  in  last  year. 

My  point  here,  I  guess,  is  that  if  you  can  provide  the — and, 
again,  to  the  questions  that  you  asked.  Chairman  Johnson,  in  your 
letter.  The  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage,  I  think,  is  a  wonder- 
ful idea,  because  I  could  take  that  $3,000  that  I  would  have  spent 
last  year  or  $4,000  or  whatever  it  might  be  and  buy  up.  I  think 
that's  what  this  whole  issue  is  getting  to,  the  opportunity  for  us  to 
take  the  money  that  we  normally  would  have  invested  in  a  Federal 
crop  program  and  give  us  the  opportunity  to  buy  up,  thus  making 
this  program  actuarially  sound,  hopefully. 

You  have,  Mr.  Chairman  and  members,  a  copy  of  the  testimony 
in  front  of  you.  For  the  sake  of  brevity,  I'll  just  try  to  quickly  sum 


102 

up  the  points  that  I  tried  to  address  in  response  to  the  letter  of 
March  17. 

The  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage — and,  by  the  way  I  also 
want  to  take  the  opportunity  to  thank  you  for  the  hard  work  that 
you  put  into  the  ad  hoc  disaster  program  of  1993.  We  hear  a  lot 
of  talk  about  the  fact  that  we  don't  want  those  again.  I'll  tell  you 
what.  In  my  home  county  and,  frankly,  in  the  State  of  Minnesota 
without  that  ad  hoc  program,  several  farmers  would  have  been  in 
deep  trouble  as  we  move  into  the  1994  planting  season. 

So  I  want  to  personally  thank  you  and  I  know  from  the  members 
of  the  Minnesota  Farmers  Union  for  the  hard  work  that  I  know  all 
of  you  put  into  that  program. 

We  think,  if  funding  permits,  it  would  be  helpful  to  increase  the 
60  percent  to  a  figure  closer  to  100  percent  of  target  price  still 
using  the  50  percent  deductibility.  The  processing  fee;  we  find  the 
processing  fee  to  be  very  reasonable  and,  again,  it  addresses  the 
issue  of  processing  and  not  anything  other  than  that. 

Mandatory  coverage;  the  National  Farmers  Union  and  the  Min- 
nesota Farmers  Union  supports  making  the  coverage  mandatory  to 
farm  program  participants.  However,  the  farmers  and  certainly  I 
may  have  a  different  position  if  the  processing  fee  were  to  be  in- 
creased. The  dual  delivery  system  offers  producers  the  option  of 
where  to  obtain  the  catastrophic  coverage.  We  support  that. 

A  key  point  here,  the  use  of  actual  production  history;  the  use 
of  actual  production  history  would  make  crop  insurance  a  better 
product  for  producers  who  are  above  the  coimty  average  and  would 
also  help  in  preventing  the  farmers  from  farming  the  program,  an 
issue  that  you  and  Mr.  Ackerman  addressed,  and  Mr.  Minge  and 
also  Mr.  Peterson  early  on. 

The  requirement  to  insure  all  land  in  the  county  for  a  particular 
crop.  It  is  appropriate  to  require  a  producer  to  include  all  land  in 
a  county  for  a  particular  crop.  However,  the  dryland  crops,  such  as 
wheat,  should  not  be  averaged  with  irrigated  crops.  These  should 
be  a  separate  unit. 

Adequacy  of  the  buy-up  coverage  for  insurable  crops.  The  buy-up 
coverage  should  extend  higher  than  the  75  percent  election  rate,  we 
feel.  Provisions  for  noninsured  crops.  My  sense  of  this  is  the  ques- 
tion might  have  been  a  little  unclear.  Does  noninsured  mean  no  in- 
surance is  available  or  that  the  producer  chooses  not  to  purchase 
insurance?  We'd  recommend  that  the  producer  be  required  to  estab- 
lish production  history  before  being  allowed  to  insure  a  crop  that 
had  never  been  planted  in  the  previous  years.  This  would  guard 
against,  again,  producers  farming  the  program. 

The  amount  of  premium  subsidies  at  different  levels  of  coverage. 
If  the  goal  is  to  encourage  producers  to  purchase  adequate  cov- 
erage, then  subsidy  should  be  offered  as  a  percent  of  the  premium 
instead  of  just  a  flat  dollar  amount  for  current  subsidy,  which  is 
the  same  whether  the  producer  purchases  coverage  at  65  or  75  per- 
cent level  and  encourages  producers  to  purchase  only  the  65  per- 
cent level  of  coverage. 

I  see  the  light  is  on.  You  have,  again,  in  your  packet  the  testi- 
mony of  the  Minnesota  Farmers  Union.  Thank  you  for  the  oppor- 
tunity. ^ 


103 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Frederickson  appears  at  the  con- 
clusion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Frederickson,  for  your  testimony. 
I  appreciate  the  insights  of  all  members  of  this  panel.  I  think 
they're  very  useful  to  us  and  to  our  subcommittee. 

Mr.  Christopherson,  I  think  a  lot  of  us  share,  to  one  degree  or 
another,  your  concern  about  mandatory  programs.  Whenever  the 
word  "mandate"  comes  up,  I  think  all  of  us  sit  up  a  little  straighter 
because  it's  not  something  that  we  are  ever  very  enthusiastic 
about. 

I  think  you  can  understand  the  balancing  act  that  necessarily 
has  to  go  on  here.  The  crop  insurance  is  mandatory  only  if  you  take 
taxpayer  subsidies  in  the  first  place  because  you  belong  to  the  farm 
program,  and  the  taxpayers  are,  in  effect,  insisting  that  if  you  take 
their  dollars,  then  you  also  must  participate  in  a  program  that  will 
free  them  of  the  pressures  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  in  the  fu- 
ture. 

The  other  concern  is  that  if  we  have  too  little  a  sign-up,  it  may 
destroy  the  viability  of  the  entire  system  because  it's  going  to  cre- 
ate tremendous  pressures  than  to  step  back  and  do  something  to 
help  all  these  people  out. 

So  the  bad  news  is  it's  mandatory.  The  good  news  it's  virtually 
free.  But  I  would  agree  with  you  that  if  we  do  this,  we'd  better 
keep  a  close  eye  on  the  tendency  to  start  with  a  $50  sign-up  charge 
and  then  have  it  inflate  and  get  out  of  hand  and  after  a  while  be- 
come a  very  substantial  cost. 

I  guess  that's  more  a  comment  than  a  question.  There  has  been 
some  discussion  about,  well,  taking  away  the  mandatory  nature  of 
it,  making  people  come  in  with  a  waiver  statement  or  something 
of  that  kind,  I  don't  know  if  that  would  have  any  interest  to  you. 

Mr.  Christopherson.  Let  me  comment  just  a  little  bit  about  the 
mandatory  portion.  You  probably  alluded  to  a  clue  to  the  problem 
when  you  made  the  comment  about  the  Scandinavian  heritage  of 
this  table  here.  We  tend  to  be  somewhat  obstinate,  some  of  us  more 
than  others. 

Certainly,  the  mandatory  portion,  I  guess,  bothers  us  to  the  ex- 
tent that  it  does  take  away  one  more  of  the  decisions  that  farmers 
have  to  make.  And  while  I  recognize  the  consequences  are  not 
great,  I  guess  as  the  principal  of  it,  we  are  not  required  to  buy  hail 
insurance,  we  are  not  required  to  buy  fire  insurance,  et  cetera,  but 
they  are  prudent  economic  decisions  that  most  farmers,  I  think, 
make. 

So  I  guess  that  is  where  we're  coming  from  with  regard  to  the 
mandatory  aspect  of  it.  I  would  be  hard  pressed  to  make  a  very 
strong  argument  against  it,  other  than  on  principal. 

Mr.  Johnson.  The  remaining  members  of  the  panel,  I  think,  all 
raised  a  very  legitimate  point  about  the  concern  that  there  has  to 
be  some  support  there  for  people  to  buy  up,  to  get  more  than  the 
catastrophic  coverage.  Otherwise,  it's  going  to  remain  to  be  an  in- 
adequate risk  management  tool. 

Again,  the  balancing  act  we  have  is  how  much  money  do  we 
have.  It's  going  to  require  a  substantial  amount  of  the  money  to 
provide  that  virtually  free  catastrophic  coverage.  That  leaves  only 


104 

a  modest  amount  of  money  to  help  subsidize  the  higher  levels  of 
coverage. 

A  ^nM*^^^^  ^^^  °^y°"  ^^^^®  ^  ^®^  good  point  that  we  need  to 
ao  all  that  we  can  to  encourage  the  higher  signup. 

Mr.  Peterson,  do  you  have  any  particular  problem  with  the  dual 
delivery  system,  where  you  can  buy  the  whole  thing  from  your  in- 
sm-ance  agent  or  you  can  buy  just  the  catastrophic  from  the  ASCS 
oiiice.'^ 

Mr.  Richard  Peterson.  I  guess  the  only  problem  we've  got  is 
^  AoU^^'^'ll  K''''^^  *^®  Government  to  train  these  employees  in 
the  ASCS  or  the  Farm  Service  offices  and  then  how  much  more  pa- 
perwork it  s  going  to  create  for  them. 

Maybe  what  we  should  do  is  instead  of  training  them  to  do  what 
the  private  agents  are  doing  already  is  to  use  that  money  to  sub- 
sidize that  75  or  85  percent  coverage 

Mr.  Johnson.  That's  a  possible  tradeoff".  Part  of  the  problem  is 
that,  at  least  initially,  in  many  parts  of  the  country,  as  Mr.  Acker- 
man  has  noted,  there  simply  are  not  enough  agents  out  there  Our 
part  of  the  country  tends  to  be  fairly  well  served  with  a  lot  of  well 
trained  professional  crop  insurance  agents.  There  are  some  parts  of 
the  country  where  that  simply  is  not  true. 

If  we're  going  to  go  from  a  30  percent  sign-up  to  an  80  percent 
sign-up  in  one  huge  leap,  we  may  need  the  resources  of  both  ASCS 
or  the  FSA  and  the  crop  insurance  industry  to  deliver  that.  But  I 
think  you  raise  a  good  point  about  how  we're  going  to  have  to  look 
very  carefully  about  how  to  best  utilize  each  additional  dollar  avail- 
able, because  to  the  degree  possible,  we  want  to  spend  it  delivering 
a  quality  product,  not  in  reinventing  or  creating  more  bureaucracy 
and  administrative  expense.  That's  a  good  point. 

I  will  honor  my  own  red  light  promises  and  recognize  Mr.  Peter- 
son. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  Mr 
Lacey,  you  were  suggesting  in  here  raising  the  subsidy  rates  on  the 
65,  75  and  85.  Do  you  have  an  idea  how  we  would  do  this  where 
the  money  would  come  from?  Have  you  folks  thought  that  through 
at  all?  ^ 

Mr.  Lacey.  First  of  all,  we  need  that  money  that  comes  from  the 
disaster.  That's  the  first  piece  that  we  need  in  order  to  make  this 
thing  work.  Then  I  think  we  need  to  go  back  to  the  disaster  part 
of  It,  the  free  part  of  it.  I  don't  see  that  as  being  fair,  and  I  will 
tell  you  why.  The  person  with  100  acres  of  barley  and  the  person 
with  2,000  acres  of  barley  are  going  to  be  paying  the  very  same  ad- 
ministrative expense,  so-called,  for  a  whole  lot  more  coverage. 

I  don't  think  that's  needed  nor  fair.  I  think  that  that  large  farm- 
er producer  can  afford  to  pay  something  to  subsidize  that  higher 
coverage  that  we  all  need  in  the  first  place.  So  I  guess  that's  where 
I  would  attack  that,  putting  some  kind  of  a  fee,  and  I  think  that 
will  have  to  be— that's  the  reason  we've  got  all  the  expertise  that 
we  ve  got  in  the  Department  and  that  can  be  figured  out. 

But  whatever  it  takes  to  make  a  more  level  percentage  of  subsidy 
to  the  65,  75  and  the  85,  I  truly  believe  that  there's  a  lot  of  us  out 
there  that  do  need  the  85  to  satisfy  our  bankers. 


105 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  How  do  the  rest  of  you  feel  about 
that  idea?  I  think,  Mr.  Frederickson,  you  were  pretty  clear  that  you 
don't  think  much  of  that  idea,  I  gathered  from  your  testimony. 

That  you  pay  so  much  per  acre  or  something  like  that.  That's 
what  Mr.  Lacey  was  alluding  to.  But  using  that  money  to  buy  down 
the  higher  levels.  I  sense  that  you  folks  don't  think  that's  a  good 
idea. 

Mr.  Frederickson.  Mr.  Chairman,  Representative  Peterson,  we 
didn't  necessarily  see  that  as  a  problem.  We  recognize  it  as  a  proc- 
essing fee.  However,  I  will  say  that  some  of  our  members  up  in  Mr. 
Lacey's  area  have  indicated  a  concern  on  the  large  farm  versus  the 
small  farm,  sa3dng  why  is  it  that  the  large  operator  would  get  the 
benefit  of  this  for  $50  or  $100  and  I  would  get  the  same  thing  if 
I  only  raised  100  acres  of  wheat. 

So  I  would  be  remiss  if  I  didn't  point  that  out.  But  in  the  main, 
the  Minnesota  Farmers  Union  has  not  seen  that  as  a  huge  prob- 
lem, understanding  it  as  a  processing  fee.  So  I  guess  we  don't  have 
a  problem. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Do  any  of  the  rest  of  you  have  any 
ideas?  Are  you  for  or  against  the  idea  of  charging  so  much  per  acre 
and  then  using  that  money  to  buy  down  the  top? 

Mr.  Buschette.  Speaking  for  myself  and  not  for  the  Minnesota 
Wheat  Growers,  I  would  have  no  problem  with  a  small  fee  and 
helping  to  do  that. 

Mr.  Richard  Peterson.  I  guess  the  Minnesota  Com  Growers 
and  the  Soybean  Growers,  we've  felt  that  it  should  be  no  hardship 
for  somebody  to  be  paying  $100  for  the  coverage.  We  don't  have  a 
problem  with  it  the  way  it  is. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  What  about  if  we  put  a  50-cents-an- 
acre  charge  on,  then  what?  And  then  use  that  money  to  buy  down 
the  top  prices. 

Mr.  Richard  Peterson.  That  would  be  all  right,  too.  I  have  had 
comments  when  I  brought  this  up  to  farmers  and  there  has  been 
some  of  that  feeling  that  the  large  producer  is  getting  by  cheaper 
than  the  small  one.  I  don't  think  that  would  be  a  problem,  either, 
that  way  if  it  was  at  a  low  enough  rate. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Do  you  think  that  would  force  peo- 
ple out  of  the  system? 

Mr.  Richard  Peterson.  I  really  think  what  we  need  is  if  we're 
going  to  t£ike  the  ad  hoc  disaster  away  from  the  farmer,  he's  not 
going  to  make  any  money  if  he  has  a  crop  loss  at  50  or  even  65 
percent.  I  could  testify  for  that.  Since  1986,  my  brother  and  I  took 
insurance  up  until  1992.  We  spent  $27,000  for  Federal  crop  insur- 
ance and  we  had  a  65  percent  crop  in  1988  with  the  drought  and 
then  1991  was  wet,  and  we  got  $2,100  back  out  of  Federal  crop  in- 
surance. 

I  must  say  that  65  percent  of  the  crop  didn't  pay  the  bill. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Could  I  get 

Mr.  Johnson.  Follow  that  up,  Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  No.  I  just  wanted  to  get  Mr. 
Christopherson's  reaction. 

Mr.  Christopherson.  We  would  have,  I  guess,  no  position  on 
that  at  this  point.  It's  something  that  we  have  not  discussed,  other 
than  I  suspect  we  would  lean  on  the  side  of  fiscal  and  sound  under- 


106 

writing.  So  I  guess  maybe  from  that  standpoint,  we  might  be  sup- 
portive of  that  type  of  thing. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  The  actuary  of  the  Department  is 
here  someplace.  Could  you  run  the  numbers  of  how  much  we  would 
raise  if  we  charged  50  cents  an  acre  versus  what  we  would  raise 
with  this  $50  processing  fee  and  get  that  to  my  office  sometime 
when  you  can  in  the  next  couple  to  three  weeks?  I'd  just  be  inter- 
ested in  how  much  money  that  is  and  just  for  my  own  curiosity, 
if  you  can  do  that.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  You  gentlemen  recognize  that  you  make  a  change 
away  from  a  processing  fee  to  a  different  kind  of  concept,  but  it  is 
something  the  Committee  should  consider.  Mr.  Minge. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I'd  like  to  certainly  welcome  the  panel  here  since  sev- 
eral of  them  are  people  that  I've  known  for  an  extended  period  of 
time.  Mr.  Frederickson,  at  one  point,  represented  me  and  I  guess 
what  comes  around  goes  around.  Well,  we're  still  evaluating  your 
representation. 

We  have  talked  here  this  morning  about  the  interplay  between 
crop  insurance  and  disaster  programs  and  the  mandatory  fee, 
things  such  as  that.  I  would  like  to  shift  the  focus  a  little  bit  to 
the  problems  that  we've  had  with  Federal  crop  insurance,  espe- 
cially as  they  were  highlighted  in  1993  and  possibly  problems  that 
you  identified  earlier. 

We've  had  preventive  planting  or  the  lack  of  preventive  planting 
coverage.  That  has  been  corrected.  Some  of  the  harshness  of  late 
planting  penalties  have  been  lifted. 

I'd  like  to  ask  each  of  you  to  just  give  what  you  think  are  the 
most  significant  or  what  is  the  most  significant  surviving  problem 
with  the  mechanics  or  the  policy  for  Federal  crop  insurance  that 
have  not  been  touched  upon  in  this  otherwise  fairly  general  discus- 
sion about  disaster  and  Federal  crop  insurance.  Start  with  Mr. 
Christopherson. 

Mr.  Christopherson.  I  guess  just  offhand,  the  overriding  issue, 
as  I  see  it,  is  the  5delds  and  the  evidence,  I  guess,  given  by  several 
of  the  panel  members  here  that  really  what  it  boils  down  to  is  not 
a  sound  economic  decision.  And  while  we  have  touched  upon  that, 
that  is  the  overriding  issue  and  that  is  the  overriding  issue  along 
with  the  fact  that  we  have  the  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  that  come 
along  that  I  think  make  the  program  not  what  it  ought  to  be. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Richard  Peterson.  I  guess  as  far  as  your  test  on  late  plant- 
ing or  preventive  planting  and  then  the  planting  dates,  the  im- 
provements that  were  made  to  the  1994  crop  season  is  going  to  be 
helpful.  But  I  still  think  we  need  higher  coverage.  Mr.  Ackerman 
said  that  the  Federal  Government  wants  to  have  80  to  90  percent 
participation.  The  only  way  you're  going  to  get  that  is  get  that 
higher  coverage  affordable. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Are  you  suggesting  that  if  we're  going  to  subsidize 
Federal  crop  insurance  to  the  tune  of  more  than  $1.5  billion  a  year, 
rolling  disaster  and  Federal  crop  together,  that  instead  of  providing 
catastrophic  policy  that's  essentially  free,  just  a  sign-up  fee,  that 
we  ought  to  look  at  subsidizing  Federal  crop  insurance  throughout 
the  levels  of  coverage  and  charging  a  substantially  higher  fee  for 


107 

the  catastrophic  coverage  that  would  reflect  the  cost  for  that  cata- 
strophic coverage? 

Mr.  Richard  Peterson.  There  is  one  thing.  Being  we're  getting 
that  catastrophic  coverage  basically  for  just  a  fee,  it  should  help 
some.  It's  just  that  the  whole  problem  with  the  crop  insurance  now 
is  what  I  just  told  you,  that  it's  not  hard  to  see  why  a  farmer 
wasn't  taking  it.  The  65  percent  is  the  only  one  you  could  really 
afford.  The  75  was  too  expensive. 

And  when  it  got  right  down  to  it,  it  was  poor  in  terms  of  cov- 
erage. That's  why  I  stress  that  we  need  a  hagher  coverage  avail- 
able. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you.  Mr.  Buschette. 

Mr.  Buschette.  Mr.  Minge,  I  guess  I  would  have  to  follow  along 
the  same  lines  as  Mr.  Christopherson.  When  you've  had  2  or  3 
years  of  disaster  in  a  row,  your  yields  get  so  low  that  even  covering 
insurance,  you're  not  protecting  anything  as  far  as  your  banker  is 
concerned. 

You  get  down  to  where  your  total  package  isn't  much  at  all.  So 
there  has  to  be  some  way  of,  when  there  is  a  disaster,  maybe  to 
go  back  to  a  county  yield  or  something  for  that  year  to  plug  that 
in  instead  of  going  down  to  a  65  percent.  Otherwise,  you're  not  get- 
ting enough  coverage  for  what  you're  buying. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you.  Mr.  Lacey. 

Mr.  Lacey.  I  think  one  of  the  real  hangups  with  the  program,  at 
least  in  my  area,  is  now  we're  going  to  have  our  Social  Security 
number  attached  to  the  application  so  that  they  can  find  all  those 
bad  apples.  I  think  we're  going  to  find  that  those  bad  apples  that 
are  costing  the  system  so  much  are  in  bunches.  Every  one  of  those 
bunches  is  being  fostered  by  a  bad  apple  agent. 

It  takes  cooperation  in  order  to  make  that  thing  work.  We're 
finding  that  and  I  hear  rumors  that  there's  going  to  be  more  inves- 
tigation back  up  the  line.  There's  a  percentage  that  want  to  work 
the  system  and  it's  costing  us  all  dearly. 

Mr.  Minge.  Mr.  Frederickson. 

Mr.  Frederickson.  Mr.  Chairman,  Mr.  Minge,  what  was  the 
question? 

Mr.  Minge.  What  feature  of  Federal  crop  insurance  do  you  feel 
needs  to  be  improved  in  order  to  make  the  product  a  more  attrac- 
tive product  for  farmers  and  a  better  product  to  serve  your  needs? 

Mr.  Frederickson.  Mr.  Chairman,  Mr.  Minge,  I  commend  the 
administration  on  the  work  that  they  have  done  on  this  reform 
package.  I  think  they're  right  on  the  money.  Again,  not  to  belabor 
the  point,  but  the  points  that  are  being  referenced  around  this 
table — make  it  affordable  and  when  you  buy  insurance — when  I 
buy  car  insurance,  I  want  it  to  be  there  even  when  my  daughter 
runs  into  a  post. 

And  you  know  what?  It's  been  there.  And  I  want  the  same  re- 
sults from  Federal  crop  insurance.  If  I  pay  the  money  for  the  buy- 
up  provision,  I  want  it  to  be  there  when  I  need  it.  I  recognize  that 
the  50  percent  coverage  ought  to  create  peace  of  mind  and  I  think 
it  does.  But  I  think  our  job  and,  again,  your  job  is  to,  again,  make 
it  actuarially  sound,  whatever  that  might  be. 

To  provide  that  incentive  for  buy-up  is  probably  the  key  critical 
thing  and  using  the  yields  that  we've  established  on  our  individual 


108 

farms  as  opposed  to  county  averages.  I  commend  the  administra- 
tion for  recognizing  that.  I  find  it  difficult  to  tear  this  proposal 
apart.  I  think  it's  probably  98  percent  sound. 

Again,  it  certainly  has  something  to  do  with  how  much  money 
that  you're  going  to  be  able  to  garner  to  put  it  together.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  want  to  thank  the  members  of  the  panel.  I  think 
their  discussion  and  their  response  to  the  questions  has  been  excel- 
lent and  will  be  a  real  benefit  to  the  members  of  this  committee. 
So  thank  you. 

We  will  call  now  the  third  panel.  That  panel  is  comprised  of  Mr. 
Mike  Crowley,  who  is  with  the  Crop  Agency,  Inc.  of  Worthington, 
Minnesota;  a  special  welcome  to  Mr.  Don  Marin,  who  is  with 
Marin/Biel  Insurance,  Inc.  of  Selby,  South  Dakota,  a  constituent  of 
mine;  Mr.  Steve  Lindholm,  president  of  F&M  State  Bank/F&M  In- 
surance Agency  of  Clarkfield,  Minnesota;  and,  Mr.  Eugene 
Smestad,  branch  manager/insurance  director.  Farm  Credit  Services 
of  Fargo,  Valley  City,  North  Dakota. 

We'll  proceed  in  order,  going  through  the  panel,  and  only  then 
going  to  questions  from  the  committee.  We'll  begin  with  Mr.  Crow- 
ley. 

STATEMENT  OF  MIKE  CROWLEY,  AGENT  CROP  AGENCY,  INC. 

Mr.  Crowley.  I'd  like  to  thank  the  chairman  and  Congressman 
Johnson  and  the  rest  of  the  committee  for  this  opportunity  today 
to  speak  here.  I've  been  an  agent  in  Nobles  County,  Worthington 
area,  for  the  past  several  years. 

The  crop  insurance  offers  our  farmers  the  opportunity  to  protect 
themselves  from  financial  disaster.  The  existing  program  does  need 
some  changes  and  that's  why  we  are  here  today. 

As  we  look  at  the  existing  program  in  our  area,  the  APH's  pro- 
gram has  worked  fairly  well.  The  problem  is  then  that  we've  had 
a  number  of  years,  1988  and  1993,  for  example,  as  catastrophe 
years.  When  those  two  years  are  figured  into  the  APH's  calcula- 
tions, the  farmer's  ability  to  insure  at  an  adequate  level  is  reduced. 

A  key  factor  for  the  program  to  work  for  the  farmer  is  that  it  be 
set  up  so  that  an  adequate  amount  of  protection  can  be  purchased. 
Due  to  bad  weather  conditions,  the  farmer  may  be  placed  in  a  high 
loss  situation  which  he  has  no  control  over.  The  farmer  certainly 
does  not  choose  the  bad  weather  and  the  loss  has  nothing  to  do 
with  his  farming  practices. 

I  would  like  to  see  the  catastrophe  years  removed  from  the  1.1 
loss  ratio  that  is  being  calculated.  If  a  farmer  goes  over  the  1.1  loss 
ratio  today,  he  is  subject  to  the  non-standard  classification.  This  re- 
sults in  a  higher  cost  to  him. 

In  the  past  few  years,  we  have  seen  a  lot  of  changes  in  the  farm 
sizes.  One  farmer  increases  his  number  of  acres,  another  decreases 
his,  another  one  quits  all  together.  This  presents  another  problem 
for  the  crop  insurance  program,  that  there's  problems  with  existing 
new  farmers  and  the  beginning  farmer.  The  new  farmer,  in  increas- 
ing his  operation,  is  limited  to  the  T-yield  factor.  I'd  like  to  see  this 
T-5deld  factor  removed  from  the  calculation,  replaced  with  a 
straight  ASCS  yield. 


109 

This  should  apply  for  a  2  to  3-year  period,  allowing  the  farmer 
to  have  adequate  protection  until  he  can  improve  his  normal  yield 
up  to  a  limit  that  he  should  be  insured  at.  The  program  should 
allow  the  new  land  brought  into  the  program  to  a  little  flexibility 
to  be  insured  at  the  level  three  in  order  to  build  up  an  appropriate 
year  of  protection. 

I  have  several  concerns  about  the  new  proposed  program,  as  has 
been  discussed  much  earlier  here  about  the  50  percent  coverage 
and  the  cost.  I  believe  the  50  percent  coverage  could  be  a  false 
sense  of  security  to  a  farmer  out  there  if  they  do  not  buy  these  ad- 
ditional buy-ups.  With  the  additional  buy-ups  on  there,  I  don't 
know  how  exactly  they  would  work  as  far  as  cost  and  things  like 

this. 

As  discussed  earlier  here,  just  putting  additional  money  in  there, 
I  agree  with  that  very  much.  But  at  the  50  percent  level,  I  beUeve 
this  could  be  a  false  sense  of  security  to  the  farmer  and  he  may 
not  purchase  the  buy-ups  that  are  available. 

This  program  also  has  a  dual  delivery  system,  which  concerns  me 
as  far  as  cost  and  it  may  be  confusing  to  the  farmer.  Under  the  cur- 
rent system,  a  farmer  pays  for  his  coverage  on  a  subsidized  basis, 
which  is  being  proposed  to  use  the  disaster  dollars  now  to  give  ad- 
ditional coverage.  It  seems  that  it  makes  sense  to  take  these  cur- 
rent dollars,  disaster  dollars,  to  move  into  our  new  protection  pro- 
gram. 

I'd  like  to  see  the  subsidies  on  the  other  programs  brought  up  to 
the  75  percent  level  so  the  farmer  can  insure  at  a  higher  proper 
rate  and  have  the  proper  protection  he  needs. 

I  believe  the  producers  in  our  area  would  rather  have  a  higher 
level  of  coverage  at  a  fair  rate.  If  we  could  get  more  producers  to 
purchase  the  75  percent  level  of  coverage  with  higher  subsidies,  I 
believe  we  can  make  this  program  more  cost-effective  for  the  farm- 
er and  the  government. 

The  farmer  will  receive  a  higher  level  of  coverage.  To  make  this 
actuarially  sound,  we  would  need  to  have  every  farmer  participate 
in  the  crop  insurance  program.  With  every  producer  using  crop  in- 
surance, all  additional  disaster  programs  would  be  eliminated. 

In  summary,  what  I  really  feel  we  need  to  accomplish  with  the 
crop  insurance  the  increase  of  guarantees  and  the  use  of  subsidized 
dollars  to  improve  the  current  program.  Today's  farmer  is  wiUing 
to  pay  his  fair  share  if  he  is  getting  adequate  protection.  He  doesn't 
want  a  free  program  that  still  leaves  him  with  a  great  deal  of  un- 
certainty. 

He  deals  with  uncertainty  every  day  when  he  checks  the  weath- 
er. We  need  to  provide  these  valuable  business  people  with  guaran- 
teed protection  at  a  reasonable  premium  with  a  workable  system. 

I  ask  for  your  support  in  creating  not  another  Federal  bureauc- 
racy, but  to  increase  the  present  program  that  we  have.  This  will 
help  the  farmer  and  all  the  U.S.  citizens  that  we  have.  I'd  like  to 
thank  you  for  allowing  me  to  speak  to  you  today  on  this  very  im- 
portant issue. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Crowley  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Crowley.  Mr.  Marin. 


110 

STATEMENT  OF  DONALD  R.  MARIN,  AGENT  AND  OWNER, 
MARIN-BIEL  INSURANCE,  INC.,  ON  BEHALF  OF  THE  NA- 
TIONAL ASSOCIATION  OF  PROFESSIONAL  INSURANCE 
AGENTS 

Mr.  Marin.  Thank  you,  Chairman  Johnson  and  members  of  the 
subcommittee.  It's  a  pleasure  for  me  to  be  here  to  testify  before  you 
today.  My  name  is  Don  Marin  and  I'm  an  independent  and  co- 
owner  of  a  small  agency  in  Selby,  South  Dakota.  I've  been  in  the 
crop  business  for  over  13  years. 

I'm  here  today  representing  the  National  Association  of  Profes- 
sional Insurance  Agents.  We  serve  some  180,000-plus  agents  across 
the  United  States  of  America  and  virtually  all  of  them  are  involved 
in  multiple  lines  of  insurance  coverage,  some  65,000  of  them  being 
in  multiperil  crop  insurance. 

We  want  to  commend  the  subcommittee  and  we  want  to  com- 
mend Secretary  Espy  for  seeing  fit  to  come  up  with  a  reform  pro- 
posal which  has  been  badly  needed  for  many  years.  I  just  want  to 
touch  basically  on  the  14  points,  and  2  or  3  of  them  I'm  going  to 
highlight  a  little  more,  that  Chairman  Johnson  asked  that  we 
touch  base  on. 

The  catastrophic  level  is  probably  better  than  no  coverage  at  all. 
But  as  we've  heard  testified  on  the  prior  panel,  it  just  does  not  cut 
it.  It  does  not  meet  the  farmer's  needs  in  virtually  all  cir- 
cumstances. As  far  as  the  $50  processing  fee,  I  don't  know  that 
that  covers  the  cost  of  paperwork.  After  hearing  some  of  the  per 
acre,  if  they  are  nominal  per  acre  charges,  I  think  that  we  would 
support  that  concept  even  maybe  more  so  than  the  processing  fee 
of  so  many  dollars  per  crop  per  county,  especially  with  maximums 
put  on. 

I  share  some  of  the  same  concerns  as  some  of  the  farmers  that 
they  addressed  earlier  here.  On  the  requirement  that  producers  ob- 
tain catastrophic  coverage,  I  think  it  has  to  be  tied  in  in  order  for 
this  program  to  succeed.  On  the  dual  delivery  system,  this  is  near 
and  dear  to  our  hearts,  of  course,  I  did  recommend  to  Secretary 
Espy,  at  the  meeting  that  we  had  with  him,  and  he  seemed  to  favor 
the  idea.  It  did  not  get  into  the  proposal  somehow.  That  was  that 
the  farmer  first  go  to  the  independent  agent  to  get  a  total  overall 
picture  of  what  the  cost  would  be  of  the  entire  program  for  every 
level  of  coverage  to  that  farmer,  get  a  certificate. 

If  he  elected  not  to  buy  any  level  of  coverage  from  the  agent  or 
just  wanted  to  get  the  catastrophic  level  from  the  FSA,  he  could 
take  that  certificate  to  his  FSA  office  and  do  so.  This  the  Secretary 
seemed  to  be  very  receptive  to.  Somehow  it  did  not  get  in  the  pro- 
gram, not  into  the  bill  as  submitted.  I'm  not  sure  why. 

On  the  use  of  actual  production  history  for  four  years,  we  have 
a  little  bit  of  a  problem  there.  Brand  new  producers  that  have  been 
farming  before,  when  they  get  cut  65  percent  of  their  T-yield  be- 
cause they  can't  come  up  with  actual  production  history,  it's  not  an 
incentive  for  them  to  get  involved  in  the  program.  And  we  do  need 
participation. 

On  the  requirement  for  producers  to  insure  all  land  in  the  coun- 
ty, that  would  be  no  change  from  what  we  have  and  I  think  we 
need  to  continue  that. 


Ill 

On  the  provision  for  noninsured  crops,  we  do  need  a  subsidy  for 
those  that  aren't  available  to  buy  crop  insurance  through  the  FCIC. 

On  the  amount  of  premium  subsidy  levels,  I  want  to  hit  a  little 
hard  on  this.  As  we've  heard  over  and  over  and  over  again  today, 
that  we  need  higher  levels  of  coverage — subsidies  for  the  higher 
levels  of  coverage  in  order  to  make  the  farmer  a  better  cash  flow 
situation  for  his  farming  operation  and  a  total  better  management 
program  for  himself. 

In  my  written  report,  I  have  even  recommended  dropping  the 
CAT  level  as  low  as  25  to  35  percent  and  putting  more  coverage 
of  the  subsidy  dollars  from  the  50  percent  level  into  the  higher  lev- 
els. I  was  not  aware  until  today  that  they  were  looking  at  taking 
some  of  the  subsidy  of  the  65  percent  for  more  of  the  higher  levels 
of  coverage.  I  was  not  aware  of  that. 

But  hearing  the  testimony  today,  I'm  not  so  sure  we  shouldn't 
eliminate  the  catastrophic  coverage  entirely,  fully  subsidize  limits 
of  what  we  hear  the  farmers  saying  they  need,  65,  75,  85  on  up 
or  whatever,  and  subsidize  them  greater  and  forget  the  CAT  level. 
That  might  be  something  that  we  should  take  a  look  at. 

On  the  expense  reimbursement  formula  for  the  private  insurance 
companies,  on  the  average,  it  cost  an  insurance  company  25  to  35 
percent  to  do  business,  just  their  expense  factor.  The  31  percent 
that  is  now  currently  being  reimbursed  to  the  companies  for  han- 
dling this,  the  private  companies,  I  don't  think  we  can  afford  to  cut 
any  more  or  we're  going  to  jeopardize  the  financial  soundness  of 
some  of  these  companies,  I  feel. 

On  the  provision  to  allow  insurance  companies  to  lower  the  rates 
charged  to  producers,  while  we  advocate  cost  through  market 
forces,  I  don't  think  this  will  work.  The  principal  may  look  good, 
but  in  the  long  run  it  could  limit  competition  in  the  marketplace, 
to  the  disadvantage  of  smaller  companies.  Selective  marketing  and 
cherry-picking  could  easily  result,  and  we  don't  want  that. 

In  summary,  I  would  just  say,  in  conclusion,  our  major  concern 
at  this  time  is  to  get  the  crop  insurance  program  adequately  fund- 
ed. We  believe  the  program  is  designed  first  and  foremost  to  pro- 
tect the  American  farmer.  Farmers  participating  in  the  program 
enhance  the  stability  of  the  economy  in  their  given  agricultural 
area. 

We  also  believe  that  major  improvements  to  the  Federal  insur- 
ance program  have  been  possible  because  of  the  private  insurance 
industry  and  the  FCIC  agencies  to  work  together.  We  continue  to 
stand  ready  with  Congress  and  the  U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture 
and  any  other  agencies  necessary  to  protect  the  stability  of  our 
local  and  national  economy. 

Mr.  Chairman,  we  need  your  help.  We  support  the  crop  insur- 
ance program.  While  it  isn't  perfect,  it  does  work.  Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Marin  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 
Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Don.  Mr.  Lindholm. 

STATEMENl  OF  STEVE  LINDHOLM,  PRESmENT,  FARMERS  & 
MERCHANTS  STATE  BANK  OF  CLARKFIELD,  CLARKFEELD,  MN 

Mr.  Lindholm.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  am  really  happy  to 
be  here  and  really  pleased  that  Congressman  Minge  saw  to  it  to 


112 

bring  this  session  here  to  the  part  of  the  country  where  it  really 
makes  a  big  difference. 

I  would  echo  Dave  Frederickson's  thank  you  regarding  the  1993 
disaster.  It  was  essential  to  my  customers.  Really  it  holds  primary 
responsibility  for  the  fact  that  we  were  able  to  finance  most  cus- 
tomers for  1994.  So  we  do  appreciate  that. 

I  am  President  of  a  bank  and  we  do  business  primarily  with 
farmers.  We  also  have  an  insurance  agency  that  sells  crop  insur- 
ance. I  support  the  administration's  crop  insurance  proposal,  the 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  of  1994.  I  believe  it  is  essential  that 
the  House  and  Senate  Budget  Conference  Committee  adopt  the  Ad- 
ministration's recommendation  to  transfer  $1  billion  to  budget  for 
crop  insurance  reform. 

Inadequate  funding  of  crop  insurance  reform  would  be  a  case  of 
killing  the  goose  that  lays  the  golden  egg,  in  my  opinion.  There  is 
a  direct  relationship  between  a  sound  crop  insurance  program  and 
the  availability  of  plentiful,  low-cost  food  for  the  American  public. 
The  ability  to  insure  crops  is  fundamental  to  farmers'  ability  to  ob- 
tain substantial  credit  necessary  to  grow  and  harvest  crops  that 
are  vulnerable  to  natural  disaster. 

Please  carefully  consider  all  suggestions.  I  know  you  are.  I'd  like 
to  comment,  also  specifically,  like  Don  did,  on  some  of  your  ques- 
tions. I'll  probably  skip  over  some  that  I  feel  have  been  covered 
quite  well. 

As  far  as  the  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage,  I  also  believe 
that  every  effort  should  be  made  to  provide  counseling  and  incen- 
tive to  buy-up  the  coverage.  It  is  simply  not  adequate  for  most 
farmers. 

I  would  say  that  the  dual  delivery — that  ties  right  into  the  dual 
delivery  system.  I  think  that  private  agents  are  in  a  much  better 
position  to  counsel  people  on  what  coverages  are  needed.  I  think 
there  needs  to  be  an  education  process  that  takes  place  that  the 
Government  is  not  in  a  position  to  provide,  private  agents  are  in 
a  position  to  provide. 

I  think  that  ASC  is  having  difficulty  administering  the  programs 
it  already  has.  It's  being  cut  back  on  personnel  and  it  has  an  in- 
creasing workload.  I  think  there's  a  duplication  of  services  that 
would  take  place  since  we  already  have  a  private  system  in  place. 

My  recommendation  is  that  we  use  government  offices  to  issue 
crop  insurance.  Those  Cjovemment  offices  that  issue  crop  insurance 
should  be  limited  to  areas  where  they  don't  have  insurance  agents. 
My  understanding  is  there  are  some  areas  who  don't.  That's  not 
the  case  here.  But  if  there  is  some  way  to  make  it  available  only 
in  areas — through  the  Government  offices,  only  in  areas  where 
they  don't  have  private  agents. 

Regarding  actual  production  history,  it  should  be  used  whenever 
possible.  However,  T-3delds,  I  feel,  are  simply  too  great  of  a  dis- 
count to  encourage  participation.  It  puts  beginning  farmers,  farm- 
ers who  are  taking  on  new  land,  and  livestock  producers  at  a  dis- 
advantage. 

The  T-yield  is  actually — I  did  a  calculation.  If  you  took  the  T- 
yield,  not  the — I  think  that  we  could  go  with  the  ASC  yield.  That's 
already  lower  than  what  my  customers  produce.  Average  corn  yield 
in  Madison  County  in  an  average  year  is  probably  110  to  115  bush- 


113 

els.  That's  probably  fairly  conservative.  The  ASC  yield  is  probably 
92,  93  bushels  and  a  T-yield  would  be  85  percent  of  that. 

Well,  if  you  take  level  2  coverage  and  you  have  no  history,  really, 
at  level  2,  the  65  percent  level,  you're  getting  40  percent  coverage, 
not  65  percent  coverage. 

And  I  don't  think  you  can  cheat  the  program.  It's  simply  too  ex- 
pensive. Your  investment  in  equipment  and  inputs  and  so  on,  even 
if  you  did  the  minimum  farming  practices,  you  still  couldn't  profit 
by  using  crop  insurance. 

There  are  situations  where  buy-up  coverage  may  be  inadequate. 
Beginning  farmers  who  are  highly  leveraged  and — also,  the  pro- 
posal allows  up  to  85  percent  coverage.  I  would  like  to  see  that 
used.  I  hope  the  FCIC  will  give  farmers  the  opportunity  to  buy 
higher  coverage  at  an  affordable  cost. 

Also,  today,  farmers  have  more  coverage  than  they  would  under 
the  proposal  because  of  the  combination  of  crop  insurance  and  dis- 
aster payments.  I  believe  that  private  industry  could  supply  a  sup- 
plement to  their  policies  that  would  provide  for  an  increasing  pay- 
ment at  a  relatively  low  cost,  if  the  FCIC  would  reinsure  that  pro- 
vision. 

The  amount  of  premium  subsidy  at  the  different  levels.  In  Yellow 
Medicine  County,  it  costs  between  $6  and  $7  an  acre  to  insure  com 
at  level  2  coverage  and  it  costs  about  $14  an  acre  to  insure  com 
at  level  3  coverage.  Mr.  Ackerman  mentioned  that  at  level  2,  the 
premiums  would  go  down  by  about  16  percent  possibly  and,  in  level 
3,  the  premiums  go  down  about  8  percent.  I  don't  believe  that 
change — ^you  won't  get — it's  simply  too  costly  to  go  up  to  the  75  per- 
cent level  even  at  those  subsidy  levels. 

I  think  that  farmers  are  satisfied  at  the  level  2  with  what  they're 
paying.  I  believe  if  somehow  you  could — if  they  could  pay  the  same 
premium  at  level  2  and  take  all  as  much  subsidy  as  possible,  if  you 
get  that  premium  down  around  the  ten  dollar  area,  you  start  get- 
ting participation  at  the  level  3  area.  If  you're  not  around  that  $10 
dollar  area,  I  think  you're  going  to  have  the  same  as  in  the  past. 
It's  £dl  going  to  be  at  level  2  or  virtually  all  coverage  will  be  at  level 
2. 

The  adequacy  of  the  expense  formula  for  private  companies.  I 
think  the  program  needs  to  be  simplified  for  the  expense  formula 
to  be  adequate.  Whatever  administrative  shortcuts  can  take  place 
would  be  critical. 

I  guess  my  time  is  up  here.  I  hear  comments  from  Washington 
and  at  home  that  the  crop  insurance  program  is  not  working  very 
well.  I  do  not  share  that  view.  I  think  it  works  relatively  well,  but 
can  be  improved  in  terms  of  increased  available  coverage  and  re- 
ducing administrative  costs. 

It  would  be  very  wrong,  in  my  opinion,  to  think  of  crop  insurance 
subsidies  as  a  give-away  program.  I  believe  the  amount  by  which 
crop  insurance  program  costs  exceed  premiums  paid  represents  a 
very  small  investment  of  tax  dollars  for  a  very  substantial  return. 

Thank  you  for  inviting  me  here. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Steve  Lindholm  appears  at  the  con- 
clusion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Lindholm.  Finally,  Mr.  Smestad. 


114 

STATEMENT  OF  EUGENE  C.  SMESTAD,  BRANCH  MANAGER/IN- 
SURANCE DIRECTOR,  FARM  CREDIT  SERVICES  OF  FARGO, 
VALLEY  CITY,  ND 

Mr.  Smestad.  Chairman  Johnson,  Congressman,  thank  you  for 
being  here  today.  My  name  is  Gene  Smestad  and  my  remarks  will 
be  representing  Farm  Credit  Services.  I  am  going  to  highlight  a 
part  of  the  written  testimony  that  you  have  before  you.  I  will  bullet 
in  on  some  of  the  key  issues  that  we  think  are  areas  of  concern. 

One,  dual  delivery  system.  History  clearly  demonstrates  the  in- 
ability to  lace  marketing  and  servicing  incentives  into  a  govern- 
mental delivery  system.  Only  private  agents  will  have  the  incentive 
to  provide  the  product  counseling  necessary  to  assure  good  risk 
management  participation. 

Additionally,  when  the  agent's  personal  success  is  based  upon 
farmer  participation,  there  will  exist  an  automatic  incentive  to  im- 
prove product  value  so  that  the  sales  materialize.  Greater  partici- 
pation is  an  expectation  of  this  reform  and  increasing  product 
value  is  the  only  path  toward  increased  participation. 

Efforts  should  be  made  to  increase  the  industry's  role  and  re- 
sponsibility in  the  delivery  and  marketing  system  rather  than  pay 
the  Government  to  come  back  in  as  a  player. 

Two,  the  group  risk  plan.  This  is  clearly  another  attempt  to  pro- 
vide something  less  than  value  to  save  budget.  All  of  us  buy  insur- 
ance and  we  buy  individual  coverage  to  match  our  risk  manage- 
ment needs.  The  present  APH  approach  provides  for  individual  cov- 
erage which  can  be  measured  in  specific  dollars  of  protection. 

GRP  cannot  be  measured  until  the  year  is  over.  It  can  be  a  bonus 
or  a  ticket  out  of  farming.  It  is  a  dangerous  option  to  promote  if 
we  are  truly  concerned  about  protecting  risk  management  insur- 
ance to  farmers. 

The  implication  of  not  having  individual  coverage  will  shrink 
some  operators'  credit  limit  with  their  respective  lender.  Buying  a 
product  which  provides  no  measurable  protection  value  is  like 
shooting  craps.  It  simply  does  not  reconcile  with  sound  business 
judgment. 

Under  a  dual  delivery  system,  I  wonder  what  incentive  an  ASCS 
office  employee  would  truly  have  to  evaluate  this  option  with  a 
farmer. 

Three,  the  APH  calculation.  This  is  a  good  approach  to  individual 
protection  and  the  1994  enhancement  was  good  to  see.  However, 
further  enhancements  would  increase  product  value.  Enhancement 
one  would  be  to  limit  catastrophic  loss  years  to  either  the  T-3deld 
or  an  ASCS  yield.  Enhancement  two  would  be  to  keep  that  cata- 
strophic loss  from  the  rate  base  data. 

The  purpose  of  these  two  enhancements  would  be  to  protect  prod- 
uct value  or  prevent  product  value  deterioration  and  prevent  in- 
creased product  price.  Without  these  enhancements,  it  is  doubtful 
that  product  value  will  increase  to  the  desired  levels.  A  farmer  can 
by  $100  of  hail  coverage  per  acre,  incur  a  total  loss,  and  the  next 
year  he  can  again  buy  $100  of  protection. 

However,  with  MPCI,  the  total  loss  will  diminish  the  amount  of 
insurance  coverage  he  can  purchase  the  following  year.  This  identi- 
fies a  product  deficiency,  as  his  expenses  and  risk  protection  needs 
will  not  diminish. 


115 

Four,  the  cheaper  theory.  Proponents  of  this  reform  are  saying 
that  the  additional  insurance  the  farmer  buys  above  what  I  call  the 
"something-for-nothing"  line  could  be  less  expensive  as  a  result  of 
more  participation.  This  is  doubtful.  We  must  increase  product 
value  to  get  participation.  We  heard  that  as  a  common  theme  for 
the  first  group  that  was  up  here  today. 

Product  value  will  have  added  price  if  it  is  to  be  actuarially 
sound.  Let's  get  away  from  believing  we  can  sell  a  poor  product  just 
because  it's  cheap.  History  proves  this  is  not  possible.  Instead,  let's 
improve  the  product  and  price  it  according  to  value.  Farmers  are 
very  large  buyers  of  value  products.  They  will  make  good  business 
decisions  if  the  product  options  are  available. 

Five,  adverse  selection  is  thought  to  be  a  function  of,  and  I  quote, 
"knowing  disaster  legislation  will  be  available."  As  a  farm  owner 
who  buys  MPCI  and  as  a  lender  who  sets  up  farm  operating  lines 
of  credit,  I  see  adverse  selection  as  a  direct  function  of  perceived 
product  value.  That  is  why  participation  varies  by  crop  and  geo- 
graphic area.  If  product  value  is  increased,  the  size  of  the  risk  pool 
will  increase  and  adverse  selection  will  decrease. 

Six,  the  role  of  FCIC.  Simply  stated,  they  must  not  be  a  road- 
block to  private  industry's  attempt  to  develop  and  market  products 
of  increased  value.  Allowing  them  to  establish  a  presence  at  the 
county  level,  as  proposed,  would  be  a  mistake.  This  would  be  build- 
ing another  cost  structure  that  would  defer  dollars  away  from  en- 
hancing product  value. 

FCIC  must  move  faster  in  both  approving  and  reinsuring  added 
products  so  as  to  be  a  more  accommodating  player  in  program  en- 
hancements. Private  industry  needs  this  type  of  cooperation  if  re- 
form expectations  are  to  be  accomplished. 

In  conclusion,  we're,  again,  standing  at  the  gate  of  opportunity 
in  regards  to  improving  this  risk  management  tool  for  agriculture. 
If  this  reform  gets  caught  up  strictly  in  the  emotion  of  cutting 
costs,  it  will  fail  everyone.  The  focus  must  be  to  bring  business 
principals  to  an  enhanced  risk  management  product  which  can 
measurably  protect  production  agriculture. 

If  we  promote  a  single  delivery  system  by  private  enterprise,  if 
we  promote  the  development  of  products  with  true  and  measurable 
value,  if  we  enhance  the  APH  formula  to  limit  product  value  dete- 
rioration and  if  we  promote  an  American  free  enterprise  spirit  to 
the  above  process,  we  may  have  a  chance  at  achieving  reform  ex- 
pectations. 

Grood  luck  in  your  continued  efforts  and  it's  been  my  pleasure. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Smestad  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you  to  all  the  members  of  this  panel. 
Again,  I  think  your  insights  are  very  helpful  to  us.  Mr.  Crowley, 
in  your  area,  do  you  have  any  idea  what  level  of  crop  insurance 
sign-up  you  have  in  the  area  that  you  serve? 

Mr.  Crowley.  We'd  be  in  the  area  of  the  upper  70  percent  area. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Is  that  just  in  a  disaster  year  or  year-in/year-out, 
you  do  continue  to  have  sign-up  at  that  level? 

Mr.  Crowley.  It's  year-in/year-out.  There  are  farmers  who  have 
followed  the  program  quite  closely  £ind  stayed  with  it  on  a  consist- 
ent basis. 


116 

Mr.  Johnson.  So  you're  in  an  area  where  the  history  is  that  crop 
insurance  has  been  relatively  popular. 

Mr.  Crowley.  Yes.  We're  more  the  exception  to  the  rule  than  the 
rule  as  far  as  the  numbers  are  concerned. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  appreciate  your  observations  about  APH  and 
some  of  the  challenges  we  have  relative  to  new  land  and  changing 
farm  methods  and  repeat  disaster  years  and  so  on.  I  think  your  in- 
sights are  very  helpful. 

Mr.  Marin,  part  of  the  theory  of  the  crop  insurance  reform  is  that 
there  is  going  to  be  increasing  competition  among  crop  insurance 
companies.  Do  you  think  that  is,  in  fact,  going  to  occur?  How  com- 
petitive out  there  is  the  sale  of  crop  insurance  going  to  be,  do  you 
think?  Are  companies  going  to  be  out  there  competing  vigorously 
or  is  this  not  that  helpful? 

Mr.  Marin.  I  think,  Tim,  to  answer  your  question,  the  competi- 
tion factor  is  out  there.  There  are  many,  many  companies  vying  for 
the  business,  to  add  to  their  portfolio  of  products  that  they  can  give 
to  their  agents  to  sell.  The  fear  that  I  have  is  if  we  go  to  cost-cut- 
ting. If  the  company  can  do  it  for  a  less  amount,  they  will  pass  that 
saving  on  to  the  farmer. 

As  I  mentioned,  it  looks  good  in  theory,  but  it  seems  like  always 
someone  comes  up  that,  well,  we'll  lose  money  a  little  bit  to  get  the 
majority  of  the  business.  We'll  wind  up  with  limited  competition, 
which  is  not  good  for  the  farmer,  it's  not  good  for  the  agent,  it's  not 
good  for  the  program.  I  think  we  need  to  keep  that  reimbursement 
at  an  adequate,  but  not  over  level,  and  I  don't  think  we  dare  go 
much  below  this  31  percent  in  order  to  keep  it  that  adequate. 

But  the  competition  is  there,  Tim.  We've  just  got  to  be  careful 
how  we  use  it. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Don.  Mr.  Lindholm,  do  you  require 
borrowers  to  take  out  crop  insurance  or  is  it  on  a  case-by-case  basis 
that  you  make  that  determination  as  a  lender? 

Mr.  Lindholm.  Well,  we  look  at  the  map.  It  takes  about,  in  our 
county,  approximately  $240  an  acre  to  raise  an  acre  of  com.  At 
level  2  coverage,  it  will  vary,  of  course,  among  customers,  depend- 
ing on  what  their  actual  production  history  is.  But  they'll  be  within 
$70  to  $80  short  of  covering  their  costs. 

So  we  multiply  whatever  that  shortfall  is,  the  difference  between 
their  crop  insurance  protection  and  what  it  costs  them  to  raise  the 
crop,  and  multiply  that  times  the  number  of  acres  and  then  we 
know  what  their  potential  loss  could  be  in  the  event  of  a  disaster. 
We  compare  that  to  the  reserves  the  customer  has. 

If  they  have  sufficient  reserves  to  cover  a  disaster  without  crop 
insurance,  we  don't  require  it.  If  they  don't  have  sufficient  reserves 
to  cover,  then  we  do  require  it. 

Mr.  Johnson.  If  your  borrowers  are  getting  free  catastrophic  cov- 
erage, in  effect,  I  would  assume  that  for  many  of  them  there  are 
some  significant  savings,  financial  savings,  that  they  can  then  use 
to  buy  up  coverage,  that  they  would  have  greater  ability  to  buy  up 
coverage  than  they  would  have  had  in  the  past.  Would  that  not  be 
true? 

Mr.  Lindholm.  I  had  some  estimates  done — I  think  the  average 
premium  cost  in  Yellow  Medicine  County  at  level  2  is  about  $6.70. 
With  the  16  percent  potential  reduction  in  premium  cost  under  the 


117 

program's  proposal,  that  would  bring  it  down  to  $6.20  or  something 
like  that. 

So  there  is  some  savings  there.  The  real  savings  would  be  if  they 
didn't  carry  it  at  all.  But  the  fact  is  that  very  few  can  get  along 
without  higher  coverage  than  the  catastrophic  level. 

So  there's  a  small  savings  and  it's  my  opinion  that  they  would 
still  pay  that  $6.70  if  it  would  be  helpful  to  get  a  lower  cost  on  that 
$14  coverage.  It's  just  no  way  that  you're  going  to  get  a  lot  of  peo- 
ple who  would  love  to  have  75  percent  coverage,  but  they're  not 
going  to  double  their  premium  to  do  it. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Smestad,  I  gather  there  isn't  much  in  the  re- 
form proposal  that  you  like  at  all. 

Mr.  Smestad.  I  don't  want  you  to  take  it  that  way.  The  issues 
that  I  brought  up  are  issues  of  concern  and  the  one  theme  is  prod- 
uct value,  because  if  it's  going  to  work,  we  have  to  increase  that 
which  we  presently  have.  Thirty  percent  or  33  percent  of  the  acres 
are  insured.  There's  a  message  in  there.  Some  say  the  message  is 
that  people  rely  on  a  disaster  program  taking  place.  Some  of  us  do 
not  buy  into  that.  Some  of  us  say  that  the  product  value  is  not 
there. 

When  you  asked  the  question  whether  we  require  our  borrowers 
to  carry  that  coverage,  it  is  a  case-by-case  basis  not  only  on  their 
cash  flow,  but  on  what  their  yields  are.  Some  individuals  have 
yields  that  are  so  far  superior  to  what  this  coverage  can  offer  them 
that  we  presently  have  and  if  our  buy-up  in  this  reform  is  going 
to  be  similar  to  where  we  are  today,  getting  to  that  80  percent  is 
just  going  to  be  a  Martin  Luther  King  dream.  We're  not  going  to 
get  there. 

There  has  to  be  a  product  of  value  there  before  a  good  operator 
will  buy  it.  In  the  1989  hearings,  that  was  a  common  theme 
throughout  the  country.  People  asked  for  more  product  value.  In 
the  first  group  up  here  today,  they  concluded  with  that  same 
theme,  that  we  have  to  have  more  of  a  product. 

So  I'm  not  against  the  reform.  I  think  it's  the  path,  the  gateway 
to  an  opportunity  to  do  something,  but  if  the  emotion  of  cross-cut- 
ting is  going  to  override  it,  then  I'm  real  concerned  that  we'll 
achieve  it. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Understanding  that,  obviously,  we  have  a  finite 
fiscal  pie  to  deal  with.  In  fact,  there  are  a  great  many  people  in 
Washington  right  now  in  the  Senate  and  in  the  House  who  don't 
want  us  to  have  even  this  amount  of  money  for  crop  insurance  and 
who  resent  spending  nickel  one  to  subsidize  any  sector  of  the  econ- 
omy. 

So  we  have  that  challenge  ahead  of  us.  One  good  point,  I  think, 
raised  on  this  panel  that  I  think  has  been  neglected  by  myself  a 
bit  is  that  while  we've  talked  about  the  shortcomings  of  crop  disas- 
ter programs  and  how  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  programs  should  not  be 
the  strategy  of  the  future. 

Nonetheless,  I  think  it  has  been  well  pointed  out  that  those  pro- 
grams were  criticsdly  important  in  recent  years  across  much  of  our 
part  of  the  country.  I  know  that  Mr.  Peterson  and  Mr.  Minge,  as 
well  as  many  others  from  our  part  of  the  country,  worked  very 
hard  to  come  up  with  the  crop  disaster  programs  that  we  had. 
Given  the  circumstances  that  we  had,  I  think  they  were  essential. 


118 

They  had  their  shortcomings  and  their  faiUngs,  but  given  the 
overall  environment,  they  were  essential.  So  we  shouldn't  trash 
those  past  efforts  too  badly.  There  are  a  lot  of  people  who  are  still 
farming  today  because  of  the  benefits  of  those  programs. 

The  question  now,  however,  is  that  approach  is  probably  not  sus- 
tainable into  the  future  and  what  new  strategies  are  we  going  to 
be  able  to  adopt  in  order  to  provide  a  more  efficient,  more  predict- 
able, less  political  risk  management  tool  for  individual  producers, 
and  that's  the  challenge  that  we  have. 

So  that's  not  to  say  that  our  efforts  on  disaster  programs  in  the 
past  were  all  bad.  I  think  they  were  essential  in  many  ways. 

Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  don't 
want  to  dwell  on  this  too  much,  but  this  discussion  I  had  with  the 
previous  panel  in  terms  of  the  catastrophic  end  of  things,  I  would 
like  your  opinion  on  what  you  think  about  that. 

I  sense  that,  if  I  listened  to  one  of  you  at  least  correctly,  you'd 
just  as  soon  maybe  say  we  don't  even  need  the  catastrophic  level 
and  we  should  put  the  whole  thing  into  the  higher  coverage,  which 
I  may  agree  with.  But  I  think  politically  we  almost  have  to  put  it 
there  so  we  say  that  we've  got  some  coverage  so  we  c£in  avoid  dis- 
aster bills. 

Mr.  Marin.  Yes.  I  guess  I  was  the  one  that  mentioned  that.  I 
think  that  the  responsibility  lies  with  us  all  to  be  prudent  business 
people,  and  our  farmers  are  prudent  business  people.  Every  one  of 
them  I  know  of  up  in  our  area  does  not  want  anything  for  nothing. 
I  think  if  we  give  them  an  adequate  buy-up  coverage,  they  wouldn't 
even  look  at  the  CAT  coverage. 

I  agree  with  my  friend  to  the  left  over  here  at  the  far  end  of  the 
table  that  the  product  has  to  be — if  it's  a  good  enough  product,  the 
farmer  will  buy  it  to  better  manage  his  operation.  So  I  really  do 
believe  that  that  could  be  eliminated  if  the  funding  was  good 
enough  with  the  high  enough  levels. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  I  think  there's  no  question  that 
that's  a  big  problem  with  the  program.  It's  that  it's  just  not  a  good 
business  decision  to  buy  this  stuff.  How  you  get  there  is  the  ques- 
tion. 

Southerners  have  had  a  pretty  good  situation.  They've  had  all 
the  committee  chairmen  and  they've  been  getting  coverage  without 
paying  for  it  for  years.  If  they  can  continue  that  kind  of  a  program, 
I  think  that's  what  they're  going  to  opt  for. 

It's  one  thing  to  talk  about  what  we  here  in  the  Midwest  thinks 
makes  sense,  but  when  you  get  to  California  and  you  get  to  the 
South,  they've  sometimes  got  some  different  ideas.  They've  been 
taken  care  of  very  well  without  having  to  pay  an3rthing.  So  that's 
one  of  our  challenges,  trying  to  figure  out  how  we  get  everybody 
into  the  tent. 

Do  you  think,  those  of  you  that  sell  insurance,  that  it's  going  to 
drive  anybody  out  of  the  system  if  we  charged  them  so  much  an 
acre  rather  than  that  $50  fee  per  crop — whatever  the  number 
would  be?  Do  you  think  that  would  make  a  whole  lot  of  difference? 
It  would  probably  make  more  difference  what's  on  the  top  end,  I 
hear  you  sa3dng. 


119 

Mr.  Crowley.  Yes.  Our  concern  on  that  50  percent  catastrophe 
level  there  is  that  a  lot  of  farmers  may  just  take  that  and  we  could 
have  a  year  like  we  did  last  year  and  that  would  not  be  adequate 
coverage.  Therefore,  there  would  be  more  pressure  put  on  Congress 
to  bring  out  a  new  disaster  program. 

The  buy-ups,  I  think,  would  be  more  beneficial  to  the  farmers  as 
long  as  they  were  priced  reasonably  and  we  put  our  subsidies  in 
that  particular  area.  The  cost  of  that  $50  fee  per  crop  or  $100  per 
county  is  not,  in  my  opinion  or  a  lot  of  people's  opinion,  probably 
fair  where  we  have  a  160-acre  farmer  versus  a  large  farmer.  I 
think  each  farmer  wants  to  pay  his  own  fair  share.  But  I  think 
some  consideration  needs  to  be  given  on  this  fee  for  those  acres. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  If  I  could  just  make  a  comment.  I 
guess  I'm  interested  because  of  my  background.  They  say  the  only 
people  that  are  more  boring  than  CPA's,  which  I  am,  are  actuaries. 
I  don't  know  if  that's  true  or  not.  But,  anyway,  I  would  be  inter- 
ested in  having  some  information  about  what  this  looks  like  if  we 
go  to  a  system  like  Mr.  Smestad  has  been  talking  about  here, 
where  we  allow  people  to  buy  the  coverage  based  on  what  they've 
actually  produced,  and  then  what  the  actuarial  numbers  look  like 
in  order  to  make  that  happen  without  any  Government  subsidy. 

Do  we  have  that  information?  I  guess  I'm  just  saying  to  you  I'd 
like,  in  addition  to  this  other  information  I  asked  for,  I'd  like  you 
to  make  that  available  in  more  detail,  at  least  to  me,  because  I'd 
be  interested  in  taking  a  look  at  that,  because  I  think  that  really 
is  the  crux  of  the  problem. 

Some  of  us  that  are  going  to  have  to  make  these  decisions,  I 
think,  are  going  to  have  to  understand  the  actuarial  aspects  of  this 
in  order  to  be  able  to  figure  out  whether  it  makes  sense  or  not.  It's 
pretty  complicated  stuff.  But  I,  for  one  at  least,  would  like  to  try 
to  take  a  shot  at  it  and  try  to  understand  this  better. 

So  when  we  get  back,  if  we  could  do  that,  I'd  appreciate  it. 

Mr.  ACKERMAN.  We  can  provide  that  kind  of  information.  We  can 
run  those  numbers  on  a  couple  of  different  sets  of  assumptions,  so 
you  can  see  what  they  look  like. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Thank  you.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chair- 
man. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Minge. 

Mr.  Minge.  I  just  have  a  couple  of  questions.  Several  of  you  have 
talked  about  value,  particularly  the  question  of  having  a  value  pol- 
icy or  value  product  to  sell.  If  the  product  is  being  subsidized  by 
the  Federal  Government  to  the  extent  that  we've  talked  about,  this 
product  is  a  much  better  investment  of  money  than  anything  that 
one  could  do  by  going  to  a  casino. 

The  odds  are  stacked  in  favor  of  the  farmer  when  you  have  a 
subsidy  that  not  only  covers  the  underwriting  costs  and  the  admin- 
istration costs  of  the  program,  but,  in  addition,  has  a  fairly  sub- 
stantial subsidy  on  the  premium. 

I'm  wondering  if  the  policy  terms  are  written  so  that  they  cover 
the  losses  in  an  adequate  way  and  if  the  premium  then  reflects  the 
cost  of  that  tjrpe  of  a  policy,  because  the  better  coverage  you  have, 
obviously,  the  higher  the  premium  has  to  be,  and  then  if  that  pre- 
mium is  discounted  to  the  extent  of  the  Government  subsidy,  do 
you  think  farmers  are  actually  willing  to  purchase  up  to  the  75  or 


120 

85  percent  level?  Because  you're  really  talking  about  a  pretty  sub- 
stantial premium  there  for  a  good  quality  policy, 

Mr.  Crowley,  I  pose  that  question  to  you. 

Mr.  Crowley.  Yes.  I  think  the  farmers  in  our  area  have  shown 
that  in  the  past  that  they  will  purchase  this  crop  insurance.  But 
if  we  can  get  those  levels  up  there  at  the  75  and  this  85  percent 
level  and  the  rating  system  is  adequate,  I  do  believe  they  will  pur- 
chase this,  providing  that  we're  not  coming  back  with  disaster-tjrpe 
programs  all  the  time. 

This  is  always  a  problem  of  a  person  making  the  decision  of  buy- 
ing the  crop  insurance  because  he  feels  that  Uncle  Sam  basically 
is  going  to  come  back  in  and  help  him  out  in  a  year  of  a  catas- 
trophe. 

So  we  have  to  eliminate  that  first,  I  feel,  and  get  the  coverages 
up  there  and  make  sure  that  they're  at  an  adequate  level.  The 
farmers,  I  do  believe,  will  buy  this  and  we'll  have  enough  farmers 
in  the  program  to  make  it  actuarially  sound. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  I'd  like  to  follow  up  with  another  question.  We  have 
some  counties  in  Minnesota  which  are  receiving  back  in  terms  of 
program  payments  approximately  35  cents  for  every  dollar  they 
pay  in,  and  one  of  them  is  very  close  to  your  home.  It's  over  in 
Jackson  County. 

We  have  other  counties  in  Minnesota  that  are  receiving  back 
more  than  a  dollar  for  every  dollar  they  pay  in,  and  we  have  entire 
States  in  the  South  that  receive  back  like  $2.50  for  every  dollar 
they  pay  in.  So  we  have  quite  a  disparity  in  the  program  not  only 
within  a  State,  but  across  the  Nation. 

Have  you  seen  in  your  area,  and,  Mr.  Crowley,  I'm  most  familiar 
with  the  rates  in  the  Nobles  and  Jackson  Counties  area,  a  reluc- 
tance to  purchase  crop  insurance  because  of  concern  that  the  bene- 
fits coming  back  in  are  significantly  less  than  the  payments  that 
are  going  out? 

Mr.  Crowley.  Yes,  there  are  some  problems  in  there.  One  of 
them  is  when  they  purchase  the  crop  insurance,  most  of  them  stay 
at  that  level  2  coverage  because  of  the  pajonent  limitations  that  we 
run  into  against  the  disaster  program.  There  has  been  a  cap  put 
on  that.  So  in  many  cases,  the  farmer  has  not  purchased  the  higher 
level  of  coverage  for  the  fear  of  running  into  this  cap  that  they 
have.  So  it  limits  them  on  the  amount  of  money  that's  been  avail- 
able. 

So  he  pays  a  premium  throughout  these  years  and  when  a  disas- 
ter does  come  along,  this  money  is  made  available  to  everyone, 
whether  they  have  crop  insurance  or  not,  although  there  are  dif- 
ferent percentages  for  an  individual  with  insurance  and  without. 
But  there,  again,  the  farmer  that  has  insurance  is  limited  on  the 
amount  of  money  that  is  available  to  him  on  that. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  We've  had  questions  raised  about  the  administration 
of  the  crop  insurance  program  in  a  time  of  loss,  like  we  experienced 
in  1993.  Mr.  Marin,  I'd  like  to  ask  you  if  you've  seen  problems  the 
way  different  crop  insurance  agents  £ind  companies  are  handling 
claims  and  if  that's  given  rise  to  a  certain  awkward  situation  and, 
if  so,  how  you  think  we  could  improve  the  administration  of  the 
program  to  avoid  that. 


121 

Mr.  Marin.  I  don't  know  that  we  really  need  to  change  it  at  all, 
Representative  Minge.  You  could  send  40  adjusters  out  there.  They 
could  be  all  Government  adjusters  or  they  could  be  40  different  pri- 
vate companies  or  they  could  be  a  mix  of  each,  and  you're  probably 
not  going  to  get  two  of  them  to  come  up  with  the  exact  same  kernel 
count  and  figure  and  determination  of  exactly  what's  left  standing 
there. 

The  way  in  which  it's  handled  now  in  our  agency,  every  year  for 
the  last  3  or  4  years,  we  get  spot  checked.  We  get  files  pulled  on 
us  and  they're  checked,  loss  files  pulled  on  the  adequacy  of  the  in- 
formation, the  farmer  is  gone  out  and  checked  on,  and,  fortunately, 
we've  always  been  all  in  line  and  everything  and  never  had  any 
problem. 

So  if  there  are  problems,  like  Mr.  Ackerman  alluded  to,  and  per- 
secution takes  effect,  which  it  well  should,  I  don't  see  any  problem 
with  the  way  we're  doing  it  right  now. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you.  I  see  my  time  is  up. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Any  further  questions,  Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  No. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Minge,  do  you  have  any? 

Mr.  Minge.  Again,  I  would  just  like  to  thank  the  panel.  I  think 
that  you  made  excellent  presentations.  It's  very  helpful  to  hear 
from  you.  Mr.  Lindholm,  were  you  going  to  add  a  comment? 

Mr.  Lindholm.  Could  I  make  one  more  comment  here? 

Mr.  Minge.  Yes. 

Mr.  Lindholm.  I  always  look  at  the  statistics.  From  1980  to  1989 
in  Minnesota,  for  com,  for  every  dollar  premium  paid  in,  only  55 
cents  of  losses  were  paid.  On  soybeans  for  the  period  of  1980  to 
1989,  only  64  cents  of  loss  payments  were  made  for  every  dollar  of 
premium  paid  in.  Sugar  beets  was  82  cents  and  wheat  was  $1.16. 
So  for  that  10-year  period,  wheat  was  the  only  crop  where  the 
losses  exceed  premiums  paid  in. 

Of  course,  that  statistic  is  much  higher  now  because  of  the  last 
couple  of  years.  I  think  it's  at  137  percent  overall  for  the  period  of 
1980  to  1993.  However,  I  think  over  a  long  period  of  time,  the  Mid- 
west really  does  show  some  pretty  good  actuarial  numbers,  and  you 
pointed  that  out.  There  are  some  inequities  between  where  we  live 
and  other  parts  of  the  country. 

Is  there  any  way  that  there  could  be  some  underwriting  matters 
addressed  to  make  that  more  equitable? 

Mr.  Minge.  I  do  know  that  between  the  Agriculture  Committee, 
the  Appropriations  Committee,  and  then  in  consultation  with  the 
FCIC,  there  is  a  concerted  effort  to  try  to  redress  that  inequity.  So 
hopefully  we'll  see  improvements  in  those  ratios. 

Mr.  Smestad.  Congressman,  one  last  statement.  We've  been  dis- 
cussing Plan  A  this  morning.  Plan  A  is  funding  of  $1.9  billion  to 
make  this  proposed  reform  work.  All  of  us  here  are  grateful  that 
you're  in  support  of  this  direction.  But  let's  say  we  don't  achieve 
plan  A. 

In  the  discussion  of  whatever  plan  B  may  be,  there  will  be  pro- 
posals that  will  say  let's  save  money  by  eliminating  units,  let's  save 
money  by  expanding  the  GRP  concept,  and  let's  save  money  in 
those  types  of  areas.  What  we'll  end  up  with  is  less  of  a  product, 
again,  and  we  won't  achieve  any  of  these  expectations  of  reform. 


122 

So  whatever  we  get — if  we  should  fail  with  plan  A  and  get  to 
plan  B,  we'll  have  to  draw  a  line  in  the  sand  sind  label  product 
value  as  being  the  important  thing  to  maintain  and  then  maybe 
scrapping  the  free  disaster  or  catastrophic  level  and  some  of  those 
type  of  things  to  build  that  value. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  agree  that  if  we  come  in  with  less  than  the  $1.9 
billion,  we're  going  to  have  to  lay  out  a  menu  of  policy  options  that 
would  be  available  to  us,  with  the  understanding  that  if  we  get  too 
far  below  that,  we  may  just  see  the  viability  of  reform  destroyed 
all  together. 

I  would  suggest  that  there  are  a  great  many  people  on  and  off 
the  Agriculture  Committee  who  would  be  very  reluctant  to  create 
a  legislative  prohibition  on  future  crop  disaster  programs,  ad  hoc, 
if  catastrophic  coverage  is  lost.  I  think  that  may  be  part  of  the  po- 
litical dynamic.  If  you're  going  to  trade  off  the  ability  to  do  crop  dis- 
aster programs  in  the  future,  they're  going  to  be  very  reluctant  to 
give  up  very  much  on  the  catastrophic  coverage. 

So  it's  a  fine  balancing  act  that  goes  on  here.  The  best  answer, 
of  course,  is  to  have  the  administration's  recommendation  on  the 
full  $1.9  billion,  which  still  says  it's  the  taxpayers'  money,  by  the 
way,  over  5  years,  but  does  give  us  at  least  the  resources  to  signifi- 
cantly enhance  our  crop  insurance  program. 

So  thank  you,  again,  to  members  of  this  panel.  We  are  very  ap- 
preciative of  your  insights.  We'll  go  now  to  an  open  mike  portion 
of  the  hearing.  There  are  six  individuals  who  have  thus  far  ex- 
pressed an  interest  in  expressing  comments  to  the  committee  for 
the  record. 

It  would  be  helpful  if  you  would  come  down  to  the  witness  table 
to  use  the  mike  so  that  everybody  can  hear  you.  You  must  fill  out 
our  witness  card  pursuant  to  Ag  Committee  rules,  and  it's  provided 
by  the  staff. 

We  will  have  to  follow  the  5-minute  rule.  When  you  begin  to  talk, 
the  green  light  will  be  on.  When  it  goes  to  red,  it  will  be  important 
for  you  to  wrap  up  your  comment.  Otherwise,  we  won't  have  time 
for  everybody  who  wants  to  speak. 

So  we  have  six  individuals.  I  will  simply  call  them  in  the  order 
that  they  signed  up  and  see  if  they're  still  interested  in  expressing 
their  views.  The  first  would  be  Mr.  John  Keister.  Is  Mr.  Keister 
here?  Here  we  go.  If  you  would  come  down  and  use  the  mike  by 
the  witness  table,  that  would  be  very  helpful.  You  can  stand  or  sit 
or  whatever  you're  most  comfortable  with. 

STATEMENT  OF  JOHN  KEISTER,  BLUE  EARTH,  MN 

Mr.  Keister  Mr.  Chairman,  members  of  the  committee,  I'd  like 
to  express  my  strong  support  for  the  program,  first  of  all.  I'm  going 
to  leave  you  a  copy  of  written  testimony  and  I  will  summarize. 

You  are  asking  for  comments  that  could  strengthen  the  program. 
My  first  comment  would  be  to  appoint  a  permanent  manager  ver- 
sus a  political  appointee.  My  comments  here  have  no  bearing  on 
Mr.  Ackerman,  but  there  has  been  quite  a  window  of  rollover  the 
last  15  years  of  Manager  and  I  believe  that  this  has  added  a  lot 
of  problems  with  continuity  in  the  program  and  decisions  have 
been  made  or  put  off. 


123 

I  believe  that  the  relationship  between  the  companies,  the  Grov- 
emment  and  the  farmer  would  be  better  served  if  there  wasn't 
such  a  revolving  door  at  the  top.  A  case  in  point  of  this  is  the  deci- 
sions that  were  made  or  not  made  on  the  1993  coarse  grain  quality 
adjustment  procedure. 

My  second  recommendation  would  be  instead  of  a  dollar  amount 
coverage,  you  simply  let  the  price  per  bushel  float.  Instead  of  using 
a  market  price  election  under  our  current  system,  where  you're  al- 
lowing both  collection  under  Federal  crop  insurance  and  ad  hoc  dis- 
aster, in  effect,  that's  what  you're  doing  anjrway. 

The  farmer  needs  coverage  that  is  higher  than  the  $2.40  com 
election  would  allow.  Why  can't  he  choose  a  $3  election?  That  $3 
election  does  not  change  the  probability  of  loss.  There  are  numer- 
ous adjustment  procedures  out  there  that  can  guard  against  abuse 
in  the  system.  That  is  the  biggest  single  comment  that  is  against 
that,  is  abuse  in  the  system.  My  point  is  that  it's  already  there  be- 
cause he's  collecting  the  $2.40  and  the  disaster  anyway. 

The  third  recommendation  would  be  to  expand  actuarial — first  of 
all,  to  change  actuarial  to  rely  on  true  rating  in  a  given  area.  The 
gentleman  here  at  the  end  of  the  table  led  into  this.  I'm  not  exactly 
sure.  It's  been  a  year  since  I've  seen  the  figures.  But  in  the  north- 
em  com  belt,  it  seems  to  me  that  com  was  overpriced  by  25  per- 
cent. 

If  the  true  premiums  in  true  areas  were  given,  then  maybe  some 
of  these  problems  of  trying  to  grow  dry  land  corn  in  west  Texas 
won't  happen.  They're  simply  going  to  have  to  pay  the  rate  that's 
down  there. 

The  other  portion  of  that  is  the  actuarial  division  can  expand 
their  reinsurance  portfolio.  I  believe  that  the  actuarial  division  has 
a  lot  of  expertise  in  it.  The  world  market  reinsurance  because  of 
the  hurricanes,  floods  and  what  have  you  has  left  a  tremendous 
dent  in  that  availability  of  reinsurance  and  there  has  not  been  a 
consistent  market  for  the  companies  to  go  to. 

If  that  would  be  expanded,  that  alone,  bringing  out  new  pro- 
grams, would  add  tremendous  competition  in  the  industry.  And 
what  the  heck,  the  Government  might  even  make  a  buck  or  two  on 
the  end  of  it. 

The  last  thing  I  have  is  a  comment.  It  seems  to  me  that  the 
farmers  whose  organizations  object  to  a  mandatory  program — I  be- 
lieve it  is  already  mandatory.  That  comes  in  that  it  is  mandatory 
for  you  to  pass  the  bill  if  it  happens  by  their  political  pressure.  I 
think  that  your  time  is  better  spent  if  the  program  is  there  without 
going  through  the  fashions  of  it. 

So  I  believe  that  it  is,  in  a  sense  mandatory  or  society  is  request- 
ing that  when  it  happens.  If  it's  incorporated  in  where  the  farmer 
has  it  automatically  at  the  current  levels  he  has,  then  he  has  to 
choose  which  levels  he  wants  to  go  up  to. 

But  I  really  think  the  time — we've  followed  this  argument  for  16 
years  and  the  argument  was  the  same  16  years  ago.  From  a  cost 
accounting  standpoint,  I  believe  that  it's  time  to  get  the  argument 
over  with,  choose  one  system  or  the  other,  but  do  something.  Thank 
you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  John  Keister  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 


81-128  0-94-5 


124 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Keister.  Mr.  Bruce  Kleven.  Again 
tor  each  of  you  who  happen  to  have  augmented  your  statements 
with  a  written  statement,  your  written  statements  are  received  for 
the  record  of  the  committee  and  we  will  take  those  back  to  Wash- 
ington with  us.  Mr.  Kleven. 

STATEMENT  OF  BRUCE  M.  KLEVEN,  STAFF  ATTORNEY 
FARMERS'  LEGAL  ACTION  GROUP,  INC. 

Mr.  Kleven.  Mr.  Chairman,  members  of  the  committee,  my 
name  is  Bruce  JQeyen.  I'm  a  staff  attorney  at  Farmers'  Legal  Ac- 
tion Group,  FLA.G  for  short,  located  in  St.  Paul,  Minnesota  I  also 
tarm  with  my  family  up  in  Milan,  Minnesota,  a  stone's  throw  from 
Kepresentative  Minge's  hometown. 

I  have  written  testimony  that  has  been  submitted.  I  will  just 
summarize  here.  Much  of  my  work  this  past  year  has  focused  on 
analyzing  existing  disaster  programs  and  answering  phone  calls 
from  disaster-stricken  farm  famihes.  As  you  know,  a  lot  of  people 
had  trouble  and  when  they  needed  a  legal  hand,  they  called  us 

My  comments  this  morning  are  directed  at  some  of  the  legal  is- 
sues that  were  raised  m  the  heat  of  the  disaster  last  summer  and 
how  they  fit  into  the  proposed  crop  insurance  reform  legislation 

Before  turning  to  that,  I  want  to  focus  on  some  statutory  lan- 
guage that  s  in  the  bill.  If  my  colleagues  in  the  legal  profession  get 
hold  of  some  of  this,  they  can  twist  it  into  interesting  contortions. 

Ihe  one  Im  talkmg  about,  of  course,  is  the  $50  per  crop  per 
county,  and  that  s  been  talked  about  quite  a  bit  this  morning  The 
hrst  issue  that  we  had  over  that  was  the  payment  if  someone  with 
800  acres  of  corn  paid  the  same  $50  as  someone  with  80,  and  that's 
been  discussed  quite  a  bit  this  morning.  But  one  that  hasn't  is 
number  two  that  I  have.  What  happens  when  a  farmer  has  more 
than  two  crops? 

The  language,  as  it  stands,  provides  that  catastrophic  insurance 
can  be  purchased  at  $50  per  crop  per  county,  not  to  exceed  $100. 
Ihis  clearly  allows  for  two  crops  to  be  covered  at  the  catastrophic 
level  Yet,  there  is  no  statutory  mechanism  for  covering  third  and 
fourth  and  fifth  crops. 

On  one  hand,  from  Washington  we're  hearing  that  we  should  di- 
versity and  go  into  sustainable  practices  which  will  probably  re- 
quire five  crops  for  rotation.  Yet,  our  catastrophic  coverage  is  clear- 
ly only  allowed  for  two. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  think,  Mr.  Kleven,  the  goal  here  is  to  allow  cov- 
erage for  all  your  program  crops,  regardless  of  how  many  you 
might  have,  but  that  you  would  not  have  to  pay  more  than  $100 
in  processing  fees.  I  would  certainly  share  your  view  that  we  need 
as  much  diversity  as  possible  and  we  would  not  want  to  do  any- 

i^^  S-^^  ^°"^^  ^^^^*  *^^*  diversification.  But  a  good  point 

Mr.  Kleven.  That's  just  something  that  stood  out  when  we  read 
the  language,  could  somebody  construe  that  in  a  weird  way   and 
ot  course,  I  did.  But  that  would  cover  my  question  there. 

Second,  then  $50  per  crop  meaning  crop  raised,  meaning  all 
fields  or  per  field.  Again,  this  has  to  do  with  20  com  fields  covered 
tor  the  same  $50  for  one  com  field,  and  I  think  that  has  already 
been  addressed  this  morning,  again,  following  your  comments 


125 

FLAG  would  encourage  the  Committee  to  address  these  ambigu- 
ities to  avoid  improper  interpretation  problems  during  the  agency's 
rulemaking  process. 

Turning  to  something  that  happened  this  summer  of  a  legal  na- 
ture. One  important  issue  that  was  forced  to  the  table  this  summer 
is  proper  cancellation  of  insurance  contracts.  Earlier  this  morning, 
Mr.  Ackerman  mentioned  that  policies  should  not  be  ad  hoc  and, 
in  fact,  they  constitute  a  contract. 

It  is  the  contractual  relationship  that  I  wish  to  address  and  I 
have  two  examples  of  phone  calls  I  received  this  summer.  In  one 
case,  a  producer  purchased  crop  insurance  by  April  15  and  the  com- 
pany agreed  to  provide  coverage  at  a  certain  level. 

The  producer  reported  the  planting  dates,  but  did  not  provide  the 
exact  number  of  acres  through  an  oversight  on  his  part,  which  he 
admits.  After  the  farm  was  flooded  in  August,  the  insurance  com- 
pany notified  this  producer  that  they  were  cancelling  his  policy 
even  though  this  contract  had  been  formed.  The  reason  was  that 
he  did  not  report  the  number  of  acres. 

In  another  case,  a  far  worse  case,  this  person  did  the  same  thing, 
except  he  received  disaster  assistance  back  in  1992  and  as  a  condi- 
tion for  program  participation  and  collecting  disaster  last  year,  he 
had  to  buy  it  for  1993.  So  he  signs  up  by  April  15.  He  purchases 
the  policy.  This  person  also  did  not  report  the  acreage.  He  did  turn 
the  acreage  into  ASCS  and  he  honestly  believed  it  was  good  enough 
because  he  figured  ASCS,  Federal  crop  and  it  was  the  government, 
and  he  turned  them  in. 

Again,  the  rains  came  and  along  about  August,  they  called  him 
and  said  "We're  cancelling  your  policy."  When  ASCS  discovered 
this,  they  said  "Oh,  you're  out  of  compliance  with  your  1993  insur- 
ance contract.  You've  got  to  pay  back  your  1992  disaster,  as  well." 

So  this  guy,  after  making  what  he  believed  was  a  good-faith  ef- 
fort, wound  up  with  no  insurance  coverage  for  1993  and  he  had  to 
pay  back  his  1992  disaster,  as  well. 

Now,  the  regulations  governing  the  crop  insurance  program  pro- 
vides specific  reasons  for  cancellation  of  an  insurance  policy.  Vgdid 
reasons  for  policy  cancellation  include  failure  to  pay  the  premium, 
fraud,  misrepresentation,  death  and  judicially  declared  incom- 
petency. However,  failure  to  provide  planted  acreage  and  planting 
dates  are  not  valid  reasons  for  cancelling  the  policies. 

In  a  year  that  producers  needed  this  coverage  most,  it  appeared 
that  insurance  companies  were  all  too  eager  to  cancel  policies 
whenever  they  could.  FLAG  would  just  encourage  you  to  address 
an  issue  in  your  legislation  to  that  nature.  Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Kleven  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Kleven.  Appreciate  your  insights. 
Mr.  Jim  Lewis  is  the  next  individual  on  our  list.  Welcome,  Mr. 
Lewis. 

STATEMENT  OF  JIM  LEWIS,  LUVERNE,  MN 

Mr.  Lewis.  Thank  you.  Honorable  Chairman,  Congressman  John- 
son, David  Minge  and  Collin  Peterson,  thank  you  for  the  oppor- 
tunity to  say  a  few  words  today  about  Federsd  crop  insurance.  I  as- 
sure you  it  will  be  very  few. 


126 


•I?A^o?.o"^P^  veteran  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  all  of  it 
with  ASCS,  but  I  worked  very  closely  with  Federal  crop  insurance 
during  this  entire  period.  I  believe  Federal  crop  insurance  is  a  very 
important  tool  in  the  stabilization  of  agriculture.  It  offers  an  oppor- 
tunity to  protect  that  bottom  line. 

I  look  at  Federal  crop  insurance  as  a  management  tool  or  nec- 
essary expenditure  in  the  farming  operation.  Part  of  the  reason  for 
the  low  usage  of  the  Federal  crop  insurance  is,  first,  coverage  is  too 
low  to  protect  the  investment.  Second,  the  cost  of  protection  is  too 
high  even  with  the  Federal  subsidy.  Third,  the  Federal  Gk)vem- 
ment  always  bails  out  the  farmer  with  disaster  funds  with  or  with- 
out Federal  crop  insurance, 

I  think  this  is  something  we've  always  told  our  people.  If  you 
didn  t  take  Federal  crop  insurance,  you're  going  to  be  in  trouble 
and  It  seemed  like  you  guys  always  bailed  them  out. 

I  feel  we  need  to  do  three  things.  We  should  use  these  disaster 
hinds  or  at  least  part  of  those  disaster  funds  to  increase  the  Fed- 
eral crop  insurance  subsidy,  and  I  think  that's  what  has  been 
talked  about  all  day.  We  need  to  increase  the  coverage;  yet,  we've 
got  to  keep  the  program  actuarially  sound. 

Third,  we  must  say  no  to  these  disaster  bail-outs.  I  think  we've 
been— or  at  least  I  used  to  tell  people  in  my  office  ten  or  15  years 
ago  that  if  you  didn't  take  crop  insurance,  you  weren't  going  to  be 
protected.  I  was  proved  wrong  quite  often. 

I'm  sure  you've  done  it  with  good  intention.  Farmers  would  get 
in  serious  trouble  and  they  would  have  been  in  very  serious  trouble 
without  that  help.  So  I'm  not  critical.  I'm  just  bringing  up  the  facts. 
I  think  lenders  will  insist  on  the  insurance  protection,  if  we  have 
a  good  program.  I  read  recently  where  one  Senator  commented  that 
we  cannot  increase  the  subsidy  to  Federal  crop  insurance  due  to 
budget  restraints  and  that  disaster  payments  are  not  part  of  the 
budget.  Well,  they  are  still  tax  dollars  and  they  come  from  some- 
where. I  think  we  should  be  able  to  work  that  out. 

Another  issue  is  preventive  planting.  We  had  this  in  the  past  and 
it  s  very,  very  hard  to  administer.  We'd  have  to  be  very  strict  with 
meandering  land,  with  producers  that  probably  farm  more  than 
they  re  able  to  handle,  poor  management  practices  and  so  forth. 
Thank  you  for  allowing  me  to  say  a  few  things. 
Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Lewis.  Appreciate  your  input  on 
It.  And  you  are  right,  I  think,  on  all  your  points.  In  1980,  Congress 
said  we  re  going  to  do  crop  insurance  and  we're  never  going  to  do 
a  disaster  payment  again.  That  turned  out  to  be  a  not  very  credible 
promise  The  mechanism  that  we're  looking  at  utilizing  this  time 
is  sort  of  a  stop-me-before-I-spend-again  kind  of  mechanism,  where- 
by obviously  we  cannot  totally  prohibit  what  a  future  Congress  or 
future  White  House  wants  to  do,  that's  their  prerogatives,  but  we 
can  change  the  rules. 

Currently,  if  you  want  to  spend  disaster  money,  you  can  simply 
do  so  without  raising  taxes  or  cutting  other  spending,  unlike  all 
other  kinds  of  spending  which  require  budget  neutrality.  We're 
going  to  change  those  rules  so  that  m  the  future,  if  a  Congress  or 
a  White  House  wants  an  ad  hoc  disaster  bill,  they're  either  going 
to  have  to  raise  someone's  taxes  or  cut  the  rest  of  the  Ag  budget 
to  pay  for  it. 


127 

That  is  going  to  be  exceedingly  difficult  to  do  with  the  kind  of 
political  environment  that  exists  in  Washington  today.  So  I  think 
that  there  will  be  teeth  in  that  promise.  I'm  sure  there  will  be 
skeptics,  nonetheless,  until  we  go  through  a  cycle  of  no  crop  disas- 
ter payments,  but  the  mechanism  will  be  a  strong  one. 

The  next  individual  is  Mr.  Stan  Gyberg. 

STATEMENT  OF  STAN  GYBERG,  FARMER,  LUVERNE,  MN 

Mr.  Gyberg.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  coming  to  Luveme, 
Minnesota.  We  appreciate  your  being  here.  I  think  one  of  the  con- 
cerns I've  had  while  I've  been  listening  to  this — most  of  my  notes 
aren't  going  to  be  as  complete.  I've  been  writing  them  down  as  I've 

been  going  here.  ^    ,  „  , 

One  of  the  concerns  I  get  is  I  hear  a  lot  about  the  $2  billion  we  re 
spending  for  agriculture  and  the  consumer  always  being  concerned 
that  that's  our  tax  dollars.  But  I  also  have  to  point  out  to  them 
that  we  have  $10  billion  spent  in  Florida,  we  have  $10  billion  spent 
in  LA,  and  those  are  my  tax  dollars.  So  I'd  like  to  keep  that  point 
clear  that  it  works  both  ways. 

It  seems  that  in  agriculture,  we're  always  the  first  ones  that  are 
talked  about  when  we  cut  the  budget  and  we've  taken  a  lot  of  cuts 
already  and  our  programs  seem  to  be  getting  smaller  all  the  time. 
That's  one  of  my  observations. 

The  next  thing  I'd  like  to  get  to  is  that  it  concerns  me  that  our 
insurance  coverage  doesn't  get  more  into  the  ASCS  office  than  it 
is.  I  understand  your  point  that  someplace  there  is  an  agent.  In 
this  area,  we  are  very  well  provided  for  by  private  coverage  and  I 
think  they  do  a  good  job,  because  they  are  very  competitive.  When 
there  is  something  wrong,  they  will  explain  things  to  me.  They  will 
take  the  time  when  they  have  to.  Like  this  last  fall,  they  were 
working  from  7  o'clock  to  11  o'clock  at  night. 

There  are  no  8-to-4  hours  and  stuff  like  that.  If  I  don't  like  them, 
I  can  go  across  the  street  and  get  somebody  else.  That's  what 
makes  the  insurance  companies,  in  my  view,  good,  because  they 
have  to  be  in  order  or  they  don't  survive. 

I  like  the  per  acre  assessment.  I  like  that.  I  think  our  insurance 
has  to  be  affordable.  I  think  we  have  to  subsidize  the  higher  levels, 
because  when  I  go  into  a  bank  or  someplace,  I  need  a  certain 
amount  of  money  to  work  with.  When  I  look  at  50  percent  or  some- 
thing like  this  by  the  time  I'm  down  there,  I  really  need  that 
money.  But  I  still  need  65,  75,  whatever  the  coverage  has  to  be  to 
operate  and  those  levels  have  to  be  affordable. 

So  I  think  those  discounts  that  you're  talking  about  have  to  go 
through  the  higher  systems  of  our  coverage.  I  think  Jim  Lewis 
talked  about  some  of  the  points  of  why  people  don't  buy  insurance 
is  because  they  feel  that  government  is  going  to  bail  them  out  any- 
way. I  think  we  should  stick  to  some  policies. 

Last  summer  I  visited  my  ASC  office  more  than  I  visited  anybody 
else  in  the  whole  county  here,  trying  to  keep  up  on  program 
changes,  insurance  changes  and  this  type  of  thing.  I  have  had  27 
years  of  crop  insurance  coverage  and  I'll  tell  you  I'm  not  ahead  of 
the  game.  I  think  when  you  talk  about,  well,  if  you  turn  this  over 
to  the  state  private  insurance  companies,  they  deal  with  car  insur- 
ance. If  you're  in  different  areas,  it  costs  you  different. 


128 


I  don  t  know  how  the  Government  sets  their  rates,  that  somebody 
^  J  u  ^°^^^  &®^s  $2  versus  43  cents  or  whatever  it  is.  If  we  have 
good  history,  we  should  have  cheap  coverage.  If  you  have  a  poor 
history,  you  should  pay  for  it. 

That's  mainly  my  observations  here.  If  you  have  any  questions, 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Gyberg.  I  think  you  raise  a  good 
point.  1  think  many  people  will  buy  all  of  their  insurance  through 
a  private  insurance  agent,  because  there  is  nothing  in  the  reform 
that  requires  you  to  buy  your  insurance  from  the  ASCS  office  I 
think  it  IS  important.  I  think  people  will  increasingly  utiUze  their 
private  insurance  agency. 

I  think  you  raise  a  good  point,  as  well,  on  the  Florida  and  LA 
disasters.  Being  the  devil's  advocate  a  bit,  South  Dakota  and  Min- 
nesota and  wherever  else  will  continue  to  get  the  same  kind  of  re- 
hef  they  get  in  LA  and  in  Florida  if  your  house  washes  away  or 
whatever  happens.  But  agriculture  is  the  only  sector  of  the  econ- 
omy that  gets  compensation  for  lost  revenue.  No  other  sector  does 
and  that  s  why  we  are  trying  to  perfect  this  crop  insurance  system' 
so  that  we  do  continue  to  provide  that  kind  of  relief. 

Thank  you.  We  will  go  next  to  Mr.  Mack  Willers. 

STATEMENT  OF  MACK  WILLERS,  FARMER,  BEAVER  CREEK,  MN 

Mr.  Willers.  Chairman  Johnson  and  members  of  the  committee 
I  would  just  like  to  make  a  couple  comments.  First  of  all,  from  a 
farmer  s  standpoint,  you  always  buy  insurance  mandatory  if  you're 
a  young  farmer.  I  started  farming  17  years  ago  and  as  a  lender  bor- 
rowing me  money,  your  insurance  is  mandatory.  So  any  part  about 
arguments  of  not  mandatory  is  not  true. 

^n^o^°^^o  ^^^^  ^^  years,  I  have  never  collected  a  penny,  even  in 
1983,  1988  or  last  year.  So  I  think  the  idea  of  going  back  to  lesser 
amounts  of  premium  due  to  your  loss  would  be  obviously  well 

The  other  part  I  want  to  comment  on  is  on  the  ASC  committee, 
we  gave  out  $10  miUion  in  this  country  last  year  and  we're  not 
done  yet.  Your  comment  about  it  helping  is  obviously  there,  wheth- 
er people  want  to  admit  it  or  not.  The  thing  that  bothers  me— a 
couple  things. 

If  we  reform  this,  there  are  a  few  details  that  I'd  Uke  to  point 
out.  If  we're  going  to  do  away  with  disaster,  there  won't  be  any  dis- 
aster for  the  people  that  grow  hay.  The  way  the  hay  program 
works  now  is  that  every  time  that  you  have  a  disaster,  you  lower 
the  amount  and  you  can  never  raise  it.  If  that's  going  to  come 
under  the  insurance  program,  that  part  would  have  to  change. 

Also,  as  you  are  having  debt  or  structuring  budget  for  USDA  and 
you  re  talking  about  retraining  these  USDA  employees  or  going 
into  an  FSA,  where  is  the  money  going  to  go  to  retrain  the  crop 
insurance  people?  Because  when  we  go  through  a  forum  of  people 
in  from  the  elevator  that  has  a  Hst  of  every  form  they  bring  in,  we 
have  to  do  it  by  hand  at  the  ASC  office  to  figure  out  where  they 
are,  and  we  don't  use  the  same  form  as  the  crop  insurance  people. 

So  someplace  along  the  line  you  guys  are  going  to  have  to  have 
the  actuarial  people  come  up  with  that.  The  other  question  I  have 
IS  where  the  ASC  committee  will  stand  on  setting  yields.  Now, 


129 

we're  going  to  have  the  CRP  acre  start  coming  out.  Are  we  going 
to  come  back  and  go  back  to  their  original  corn  base  and  what  kind 
of  value  are  we  going  to  put  on  that  base  since  it  hasn't  been 
farmed  for  so  many  years. 

Will  we  be  able  to  get  decent  crop  insurance  for  them  people?  Be- 
cause in  western  Minnesota,  west  central,  and  in  South  Dakota, 
there's  a  lot  of  acres  in  some  of  these  counties  that  there's  going 
to  be  income  needed  from.  I  think  one  of  the  other  things  I  was 
worried  about  is  your  new  MVP  pilot  project.  My  question  is  it 
sounds  wonderful  to  be  able  to  ensure  at  a  higher  level,  but  if  you 
can  do  that  and  you  have  a  loss  or  you're  near  a  loss,  will  the  peo- 
ple be  interested  in  destroying  the  crop  because  they  won't  have 
any  basis  to  gain  from  the  price  difference  in  Chicago  compared  to 
local  grain  price. 

Will  you  actually  make  the  farmer  go  out  and  destroy  a  0/92  so 
they  can  get  paid  more,  because  there  wouldn't  be  any  basis  dif- 
ference. 

I  talked  to  Mr.  Clifford  Parker,  he's  the  Director  of  Claims  at 
FCIC,  about  last  week  and  he  said  there  was  no  mechanism  in 
there  to  counteract  that  yet.  So  maybe  you  could  look  into  that. 

Thank  you  for  your  time. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Willers.  I  think  you  raise  a  good 
point  that  we  continue  to  need  to  expand  the  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram to  added  crops,  and,  obviously,  there  has  to  be  a  mechanism 
and  there  is  a  mechanism  to  provide  some  protection  for 
nonprogram  crops.  The  CRP  question  will  be  taken  up  in  the  1995 
farm  bill.  That  remains  to  be  seen. 

I  have  a  feeling  that  we're  not  going  to  simply  totally  terminate 
that  program,  although  it's  true  that  we  may  not  have  the  full  level 
of  budget  that  we  have  now.  And  the  pilot  project  we  will  have  to 
monitor  very  closely.  I  think  we  need  always  to  be  trying  out  inno- 
vative new  ways  of  trjdng  to  protect  farm  income. 

This  is  one  that  may  not  work  at  all.  It  may  be  work.  There  may 
be  portions  of  it  that  work.  So  we're  sort  of,  I  guess,  waiting  to  see 
the  final  report  come  in  to  see  how  it  proceeded.  But  I  appreciate 
your  caution  on  that  issue. 

The  last  individual  we  have  on  our  list  that's  reported  to  me  is 
Mr.  Randy  White. 

STATEMENT  OF  RANDY  WHITE,  STATE  REPRESENTATIVE, 
NORTH  CENTRAL  CROP  INSURANCE,  INC. 

Mr.  White.  Thank  you.  Congressman,  for  coming  to  the  Midwest 
to  address  this  issue  on  crop  insurance.  There  are  some  things  that 
I  would  like  to  point  out  here. 

First  of  all,  as  we  all  know,  everything  comes  from  the  ground 
and  we  need  to  protect  the  viability  of  agriculture,  at  no  matter 
what  cost.  Multiperil  crop  insurance  is  one  aspect  of  that.  In  South 
Dakota,  where  I'm  from,  in  1993,  our  company  had  2,700  losses.  I 
know  that  some  of  the  people  from  Minnesota  felt  that  the  level, 
the  65  percent  level  did  not  provide  them  adequate  coverage. 

I  have  2,700  people  in  South  Dakota  that  collected  a  lot  of  money 
that  they  would  not  have  had  they  not  had  the  65  percent  level. 
They  were  very  happy  to  get  that  money. 


130 


In  visiting  with  these  farmers,  and  I  was  out  and  adjusted  a 
number  of  them,  they  would  certainly  support  eliminating  disaster 
payments  if  they  could  increase  their  level  of  coverage  a  reasonable 
premium  It  definitely  would  be  a  situation  that  they  would  accept 

Many  farmers  in  South  Dakota  in  1993  that  suffered  losses 
would  not  be  farming  in  1994.  They  would  not  get  the  funding  from 
their  banks  if  it  were  not  for  the  multiperil  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram. Many  banks  do  look  at  that  when  they  go  to  make  the  loan 
to  that  farmer. 

Multiperil  crop  insurance  versus  disaster  would  be  more  accept- 
able, I  would  imagine,  to  the  people  in  the  metro  areas  because  the 
farmer  does  contribute  to  the  plan,  which,  in  most  farm  programs 
they  do  not.  ' 

The  CAT  plan  for  1994  concerns  me  a  Httle  bit  because  in  1993 
when  the  35  percent  level  came  out,  we  had  more  problems  with 
the  35  percent  level  than  any  of  the  other  levels,  simply  for  the  fact 
the  farmer  was  not  happy  when  we  adjusted  it.  Even  though  they 
were  told  at  the  time  they  purchased  the  policy  that  they  had  very 
low  coverage,  when  it  came  time  to  collect,  they  were  very  unhappy 
because  they  had  lost  their  crop  and  they  were  getting  very  small 
amounts. 

We  had  situations  where  people  were  paid  a  couple  thousand  dol- 
lars that  could  have  gotten  $50,000  or  $60,000  had  they  bought  the 
higher  levels  of  coverage.  It  concerns  me  that  that  would  give  the 
multiperil  policy  another  black  eye  that  we  do  not  need. 

Preventive  planting  coverage  is  in  the  1994  crop  policy.  It  con- 
cerns me  a  little  bit  because  there  is  some  confusion  regarding  the 
number  of  acres  available  for  coverage  and  how  it  will  be  allocated 
or  prorated.  We've  had  several  meetings  with  FCIC.  There  is  some 
confusion  regarding  that.  I  think  a  lot  of  farmers  think  that  if  they 
don  t  get  it  planted,  they're  going  to  have  coverage,  and  that  is  not 
necessarily  the  case. 

The  dual  delivery  system  also  concerns  me.  The  multiperil  policy 
can  be  very  confusing  to  the  client  and  I'm  afraid  that  it  would 
cause  more  confusion  having  to  go  possibly  to  the  ASCS  or  to  inde- 
pendents. They're  not  going  to  know  what  they  should  do.  Inde- 
pendent companies  are  also  forced  by  the  client  to  do  a  good  job. 
If  they  don't,  as  the  gentleman  earlier  indicated,  the  person  can 
chzmge  companies. 

Also,  I'd  like  to  address  the  issue  that  was  brought  up  about 
competition  among  companies.  Multiperil  crop  insurance  is  not  like 
hail  insurance  in  the  aspect  that  there  is  a  lot  more  paperwork 
Companies  need  the  staff  to  handle  this  paper  flow  for  the  acreage 
reports,  the  production  reports,  et  cetera. 

With  differences  in  rates,  business  could  be  transferring  from 
year  to  year,  causing  more  confusion.  As  someone  said  earlier, 
there  is  a  lot  of  confusion  in  this  product.  If  rates  were  different 
every  year,  different  companies  would  have  different  levels  of  pre- 
inium.  Those  policies  could  be  transferring  from  one  company  to 
the  nejrt.  It's  very  hard  to  staff  and  to  be  able  to  handle  your  work 
load  when  you  can't  anticipate  what  kind  of  a  premium  you're 
going  to  be  dealing  with.  I  feel  that  that  may  cause  some  compa- 
nies to  withdraw  from  the  multiperil  market. 


131 

Thank  you  very  much  for  your  time  and  I  appreciate  you  coming 

here. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  White.  I  appreciate  your  observa- 
tions on  the  competition  and,  also,  on  the  administrative  difficulties 
of  implementing  preventive  planting  programs.  I  think  we're  all 
very  supportive  that  you've  got  to  have  preventive  planting  cov- 
erage, but  obviously  there's  a  lot  of  complications  in  getting  it  done 
right.  Thank  you  for  your  observations. 

I  want  to  thank  the  Luverne  VFW  for  hosting  this  hearing  in 
what  is  really  an  excellent  facility  for  this  kind  of  gathering.  The 
community  should  be  awfully  proud  to  have  this  kind  of  facility. 
And  thanks  to  VFW,  as  well,  for  the  coffee  provided  and  for  the 
warm  welcome  that  we've  had  to  the  Luverne  community. 

Mr.  Peterson,  do  you  have  any  closing  comments? 

Mr.  Peterson  of  Minnesota.  Again,  I  appreciate  your  leadership 
and  look  forward  to  working  with  you  to  start  this  all  up. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  Mr.  Minge? 

Mr.  Minge.  I  would  also  like  to  thank  the  VFW,  the  community 
of  Luverne  for  hosting  this  event,  and  thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman, 
for  bringing  the  subcommittee  hearing  to  southwestern  Minnesota, 
an  area  that  has  been  so  hard  hit  by  the  1993  flooding  tragedy. 

In  that  regard,  I  would  like  to  point  out  that  the  Federal  Govern- 
ment, as  of  March  1,  had  paid  out  approximately  $2.5  billion  in  ag- 
riculture disaster  and  crop  insurance  benefits  to  the  Midwest.  Of 
that  amount,  approximately  30  percent  came  to  Minnesota  and  we 
still  are  not  done  with  all  of  the  adjusting  and  the  disaster  assist- 
ance claims  processing. 

We  could  end  up  in  Minnesota  with  as  much  as  $1  billion  of  ben- 
efits from  the  Federal  Government  to  help  us  and  that  actually 
came  to  the  Second  Congressional  District.  We  have  received  more 
money  in  this  congressional  district  than  any  other  congressional 
district  in  the  country  for  a  crop  disaster. 

As  a  consequence,  I  think  that  we  have  to  recognize  that  we  had 
a  program  last  year  that,  with  all  of  the  warts  on  it,  it  worked  for 
thousands  and  thousands  of  farm  families.  If  it  were  not  for  the 
program  that  we  had  in  1993,  with  the  shortcomings  that  it  had, 
we  would  probably  find  that  as  much  as  10  percent  of  the  farmers 
in  our  area  would  be  going  out  of  business. 

So  we  have  a  passion  to  improve  the  program  and  I  continue  to 
work  hard  on  that  and  I  appreciate  everyone  coming  out  to,  even 
by  your  presence,  testify  to  the  importance  of  this  undertaking,  but, 
at  the  same  time,  to  recognize  that  we  do  have  a  program  that  has 
been  beneficial. 

I  look  forward  to  working  with  all  of  you  in  the  months  ahead 
and  especially  working  with  Ken  Ackerman  and  the  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  Corporation.  I'll  say  it's  been  a  breath  of  fresh  air  to 
have  Mr.  Ackerman  come  to  Minnesota  twice  in  3  months  to  ad- 
dress farmers,  bankers.  Federal  crop  insurance  agents  about  the 
problems  that  he  sees,  having  just  taken  over  management  of  this 
corporation,  and  trying  to  make  the  corporation  responsive  to  the 
problems  that  have  been  identified. 

Hopefully,  in  1995,  and  if  not  1995,  by  1996,  we  will  have  a  qual- 
ity product  out  there  and  we  won't  have  to  have  any  more  hearings 
on  this  topic  for  several  years  to  come.  Thanks,  again. 


132 

Mr  Johnson  Thank  you,  Mr.  Minge.  Again,  there  is  no  lack  of 
experts  m  Washington  anxious  to  tell  us  their  points  of  view  and 
1  think  one  of  the  refreshing  things  and  one  of  the  necessary  things 
IS  that  we  spend  some  time  listening  to  bankers,  insurance  people 
and  farmers  themselves  who  have  to  Hve  on  a  day-to-day  basis 
with  these  decisions  that  are  made  from  Washington. 

It's  very  good  that  Mr.  Ackerman  has  spent  an  enormous  amount 
ot  time  listening  to  people  firsthand.  So  the  nature  of  any  end  prod- 
uct IS  that  it  involves  some  compromise  and  some  give  and  take 
and,  no  doubt,  some  things  we'll  like  better  than  others. 

But  I  am  confident  that  if  we  work  closely  together,  put  aside  all 
the  partisan  political  nonsense  that  sometimes  creeps  into  public 
p^icy  today  and  focus  on  what  makes  common  sense  and  what  can 
etriciently  deliver  the  greatest  help  to  our  producers,  that  we'll 
emerge  from  the  end  of  this  year  in  far  better  shape  than  we  were 
when  we  went  in. 

So  thank  you  to  all  of  you  for  your  contributions  to  this  ongoing 

rwT^'  ^^^'  ^®  ^^^  adjourn  this  subcommittee  hearing. 

[Whereupon,  at  12:45  p.m.,  the  subcommittee  was  recessed  to  re- 
convene at  the  call  of  the  Chair.] 

[Material  submitted  for  inclusion  in  the  record  follows:] 


133 


KENNETH  D.  ACKERMAN 

MANAGER,  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION, 

UNITED  STATES  DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE 

BEFORE  THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT,  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 

UNITED  STATES  HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

LUVERNE,  MINNESOTA 

APRIL  5,  1994 


We  want  to  thank  the  Subcommittee  for  holding  this  hearing  today  on  the 
Administration's  proposed  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994,"  which  was 
first  submitted  to  Congress  by  Secretary  Espy  four  weeks  ago.  We,  and  particularly 
Secretary  Espy,  greatly  appreciate  the  Subcommittee's  attention  to  the  goal  of 
reforming  Federal  crop  insurance  and  very  much  look  forward  to  working  with  all 
Committee  members  in  developing  a  plan  that  will  work  well  both  for  American 
farmers  and  taxpayers. 

As  much  as  any  program  in  Washington,  Federal  crop  insurance  has  long  needed 
change.  The  discontent  with  this  program  from  farmers,  taxpayers,  insurance  industry 
leaders,  Congress,  the  President,  and  others,  has  focused  on  long-standing,  well- 
documented  problems: 

0  Despite  an  annual  crop  insurance  price-tag  approaching  $900  million, 
Washington  has  had  to  step  in  with  crop  disaster  relief  payments  to  farmers  in 
eight  of  the  last  eight  years.  Standing  alone,  crop  insurance,  with  a  nationwide 
participation  rate  of  just  33  percent  in  1993,  simply  has  not  provided  an 
adequate  safety  net.  These  off-budget  crop  disaster  programs  have  cost 
taxpayers  an  average  $1  billion  per  year  over  the  last  decade,  and  more  than 
$1.5  billion  per  year  over  the  last  six  years.  This  conflict  between  crop 
insurance  and  crop  disaster  programs  must  end. 

o  Crop  insurance  has  chronically  lost  money.  Since  1981,  the  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  Corporation's  (FCIC)  insurance  operations  have  produced  an  overall 
"loss  ratio"  of  about  1.47.  That  means  that  we  have  paid  out  about  $1.47  in 
claims  for  every  $1.00  collected  in  premiums  and  premium  subsidies,  not 
counting  overhead  costs.  Any  private  business  posting  these  numbers  would 
have  gone  bankrupt  years  ago.  Taxpayers  are  tired  of  picking  up  the  tab.  The 
program  must  be  made  more  financially  sound. 


134 


0        Farmers  continue  to  complain  that  Federal  crop  insurance  does  not  meet  their 
needs.    The  program  must  be  made  more  farmer-friendly  with  new  products 
more  flexibility,  and  a  good  attitude  toward  listening  to  customers. 

Last  summer's  disastrous  Midwest  flood  and  Southeast  drought  brought  the 
problems  of  crop  insurance  into  sharp  focus  for  Americans  across  the  country 
Secretary  Espy  and  President  Clinton  travelled  extensively  in  the  flooded  areas  and 
spoke  directly  with  farmers  about  their  problems  and  experiences  in  dealing  with 
Federal  programs  designed  to  assist  them.  Again  and  again,  they  heard  concerns 
These  problems  ranged  from  lack  of  coverage  for  prevented  planting,  to  inflexible  price 
elections,  to  uncertainty  about  the  availability  and  timeliness  of  help  On  March  2  just 
four  weeks  ago.  Secretary  Espy  announced  a  massive  reform  program  that  grew  dirictly 
irom  last  summer's  experience. 

In  essence,  we  are  recommending  a  two-pronged  program  to  fix  Federal  crop 
insurance:  (1)  reform  from  the  inside  out  -  administrative  steps  to  make  the  program 
more  financially  sound  and  farmer-friendly,  and  (2)  reform  from  the  outside  in  -  the 
new    Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994." 

Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  is  the  centerpiece  of  our  reform 
plan.  This  bill  responds  specifically  to  the  central  finding  of  our  review  following  last 
summer  s  experience.  Ad  hoc  crop  disaster  bills  over  the  years  have  been  an  effective 
act  of  government  for  people  in  crisis.  These  relief  programs  have  helped  millions  of 
Americans,  farmers  and  non-farmers  alike,  survive  the  most  difficult  periods  in  their 
lives.  But  the  reliance  on  this  ad  hoc  relief  that  has  developed  as  a  result  of  an  under- 
used crop  insurance  system,  has  created  a  level  of  uncertainty  that  is  bad  both  for 
fanners  and  taxpayers. 

In  fact,  the  repeated  availability  of  ad  hoc  relief  has  been  a  disincentive  for 
many  farmers  to  participate  in  the  Federally  backed  crop  insurance  program. 

In  a  crisis,  a  farmer  without  crop  insurance,  who  depends  on  disaster  relief  has 
no  way  of  knowing  in  advance  what  his  or  her  protection  will  be.  Farmers  do  not 
know  whether  a  disaster  bill  will  be  approved  or.  if  approved,  what  payment  level  the 
bill  will  provide.  Even  then,  a  farmer  suffering  loss  must  hope  that  other  farmers 
across  the  state,  and  m  ten  or  twenty  other  states,  are  experiencing  similar  losses  in 


135 


order  to  create  the  momentum  for  action.  An  examination  of  history  reveals  that  victims 
of  local  disasters  often  get  less  than  those  of  wider  disasters,  even  though  the  individual 
farmers  may  suffer  similar  losses. 

For  example,  victims  of  1992's  Hurricane  Andrew  in  Florida,  received  aid  at 
50.04  percent  proration  while  victims  of  this  summer's  Midwest  flood  received  aid  at 
100  percent.  Farmers  with  losses  in  states  not  involved  in  the  large  disasters  found  that 
congressional  decisions  affecting  their  livelihoods  were  being  based  upon  factors  totally 
disconnected  from  their  circumstances. 

What  will  happen  if  natural  disaster  strikes  again  next  year?  Farmers  trying  to 
plan  their  operations  in  a  businesslike  manner  simply  have  no  way  to  know. 

Meanwhile,  taxpayers  are  concerned  that  disaster  aid  is  exempt  from  the  budget 
discipline  that  controls  spending  in  virtually  every  other  area  of  government.  At  a  time 
when  deficit  reduction  is  a  paramount  domestic  priority,  the  price  of  these  emergency 
programs  continues  to  rise.  The  public  rightly  questions  the  point  of  having  two 
expensive  programs  trying  to  address  a  single  recurring  problem  —  crop  disaster  aid. 
Americans  are  generous  in  a  crisis,  but  their  patience  has  limits. 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  resolves  this  situation  by 
combining  crop  insurance  and  disaster  aid  into  a  single,  unified,  on-budget  program. 
This  requires  two  steps.  First,  the  legislation  expands  the  crop  insurance  program  to 
protect  farmers,  financially,  when  natural  disasters  ruin  or  damage  their  crops.  Second, 
it  creates  a  legal  barrier  against  future  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  programs. 

We  view  this  proposal  as  being  both  a  vital  budget  reform  as  well  as  a  vital 
agricultural  reform. 

The  legislation  is  built  upon  several  key  pillars: 


1 :  Catastrophic  crop  insurance  coverage:  The  Federal  crop  insurance  program 
is  supplemented  with  a  new  catastrophic  coverage  level  available  to  farmers  of 
insured  crops  for  a  nominal  processing  fee  of  $50  ger  crop  ger  county,  up  to 
$100  per  farmer  per  county.  The  processing  fee  may  be  waived  for  limited 
resource  farmers.  The  idea  is  to  make  this  coverage  very  economical  and 
accessible. 


136 


Policies  will  cover  prevented  planting  as  well  as  actual  crop  losses,  and  will  be 
based  on  actual  individual  farm  yields. 

This  catastrophic  plan  will  protect  against  yield  losses  greater  than  50  percent 
at  a  payment  rate  of  60  percent  of  the  expected  market  price  -  a  level 
comparable  to  disaster  relief  programs  in  recent  years.  The  difference  is  this: 
catastrophic  coverage  is  an  individual  insurance  policy,  not  an  ad  hoc  relief 
payment.  It  is  a  contract  that  a  farmer  can  take  to  the  bank  as  collateral  on  a 
loan.  Even  if  no  other  farmer  in  the  country  suffers  a  loss,  the  farmer  has  the 
security  of  knowing  that  he  or  she  is  covered. 

Under  this  approach,  in  a  future  agricultural  crisis,  farmers  will  know  in  advance 
the  extent  of  their  protection  and  taxpayers  will  know  in  advance  the  limits  of 
their  exposure. 

2:  Buv-Up  coverage:  Most  producers  desire  higher  levels  of  coverage  than  the 
catastrophic  plan  offers  to  protect  their  fanm  businesses.  The  legislation  provides 
targeted  subsidies  for  these  higher  insurance  coverage  levels.  The  out-of-pocket 
cost  for  coverage  at  the  65  or  75  percent  yield  levels  will  fall  by  about  10 
percent.  In  addition,  the  bill  gives  FCIC  the  authority  to  offer  policies  covering 
85  percent  of  yield.  The  more  farmers  buy  higher  levels  of  coverage,  the  more 
fiscally  sound  the  system  will  be. 

^-  Linkage  to  farm  programs:  To  ensure  the  widest  participation,  crop  insurance 
coverage  at  the  catastrophic  level  or  above  is  linked  to  participation  in  Federal 
commodity  price  support,  production  adjustment,  and  conservation  programs  and 
Farmers  Home  Administration  loans.  We  expect  that  this  step  will  result  in  crop 
insurance  participation  rising  from  33  percent  to  about  80  percent  of  insurable 
acres. 

The  purpose  of  linkage  is  to  guarantee  that,  if  disaster  strikes,  the  bulk  of  U  S 
farmers  will  be  protected.  We  understand  that  farmers,  like  other  Americans  do 
not  like  being  told  what  to  do,  this  is  human  nature.   But  the  linkage  proposal 
is  fair  and  not  onerous  given  the  nominal  cost  of  catastrophic  coverage  to 
farmers.   Farmers  also  gain  security  for  the  future. 

4:  Delivery:  Farmers  may  choose  to  obtain  the  catastrophic  coverage  either 
through  a  pnvate  reinsured  company  or  through  a  USDA  county  office.  Higher 
insurance  coverages  remain  available  only  from  private  insurers.  Our  goal  is  to 
provide  the  most  convenient  and  efficient  means  of  quickly  getting  catastrophic 


137 


crop  insurance  coverage  to  the  largest  number  of  farmers.  The  private  sector's 
insurance  sales  force  will  have  a  full  opportunity  to  compete  for  the  catastropliic 
market. 

5:  Industry  comDetition:  The  legislation  restructures  premium  rates  to  reflect  both 
direct  premium  subsidies  and  the  expense  reimbursement  allowance  to  reinsured 
companies.  This  provides  a  more  realistic  picture  of  the  cost  of  the  program 
both  to  farmers  and  taxpayers.  More-efficient  companies  will  be  allowed  to  pass 
along  lowered  overhead  costs  in  reduced  rates  charged  to  farmers,  creating  a 
more  competitive  market  environment. 

6:  Uninsurable  crops:  A  standing  disaster  program  is  created  for  crops  not 
covered  by  crop  insurance,  with  payments  triggered  by  area-wide  loss  levels  and 
protection  levels  similar  to  those  under  the  catastrophic  insurance  plan.  This 
way,  no  one  is  left  out  in  the  cold,  the  wet,  or  the  dry. 

7:  Repeal  of  standing  disaster  assistance  authority:  Current  authorities  for 
standing  crop  disaster  relief  are  repealed.  In  the  future,  the  expanded  crop 
insurance  program  will  replace  disaster  bills  as  the  Federal  response  to 
emergencies  involving  widespread  crop  loss. 

As  added  protection,  the  legislation  exempts  appropriations  for  agricultural  crop 
disaster  assistance  from  designation  as  an  "emergency"  for  purposes  of  the 
Balanced  Budget  and  Emergency  Deficit  Control  Act  of  1985,  as  amended.  This 
action  essentially  places  future  crop  disaster  bills  on  budget.  They  must  be  paid 
by  off-setting  spending  cuts,  rather  than  being  allowed  to  proceed  as 
"emergency"  spending.  Therefore,  the  primary  vehicle  for  providing  crop 
disaster  assistance  will  be  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program,  as  its  legislation 
originally  intended. 

We  project  that  the  new  program  created  by  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform 
Act  of  1994  will  cost  about  $8.1  billion  for  fiscal  years  1995  through  1999.  This 
represents  a  five-year  savings  of  some  $750  million  compared  to  the  projected  cost  of 
the  current  Federal  crop  insurance  program  plus  the  average  annual  cost  of  ad  hoc  crop 
loss  disaster  relief  programs  over  the  past  decade.  Essentially,  this  plan  takes  the  $1 
billion  that  Washington  now  spends  each  year  on  off-budget  crop  disaster  programs  and 
re-channels  it  into  a  more-disciplined,  on-budget  insurance  plan. 

We  would  like  to  implement  this  new  program  in  crop  year  1995  so  that  its 
benefits  of  certainty  can  be  felt  by  farmers  and  taxpayers.  This  timetable  is  ambitious. 


138 


and  will  require  Congress  to  do  its  part.  Combining  Federal  crop  insurance  and 
disaster  aid  will  be  a  complicated  process  involving  training  of  personnel,  rewriting  of 
rules,  and  educating  customers.    We  must  do  it  right. 


Achieving  Financial  Soundnes.s 

Resolving  the  conflict  between  Federal  crop  insurance  and  disaster  programs  is 
not  enough.  We  must,  at  the  same  time,  also  make  Federal  crop  insurance  more 
financially  sound.  The  old  way  of  doing  business,  where  Federal  crop  insurance  lost 
excessive  amounts  of  taxpayer  money  year  after  year,  is  simply  no  longer  acceptable 
The  1993  Omnibus  Reconciliation  Act  (OBRA)  requires  FCIC  to  achieve  an  overall 
projected  loss  ratio  of  1.1  by  the  year  beginning  October  1995.  The  1994  Agricultural 
Appropriations  Act  mandated  additional  cost-saving  reforms.  We  are  committed  to,  at 
least,  meeting  this  loss  ratio  goal  and  obtaining  actuarial  soundness.  American 
taxpayers  will  accept  nothing  less. 

As  part  of  the  March  2  reform  package.  Secretary  Espy  released  the  FCIC's 
"Blueprint  for  Financial  Soundness"  mandated  by  OBRA  1993.  This  document  outlines 
the  specific  steps  that  FCIC  will  take  to  improve  the  program's  financial  soundness  and 
the  savings  we  expect  to  result.   Those  steps  include: 

A  modified-APH  (actual  production  history)  program  to  better  tie  individual 
farmer's  insurance  coverage  to  their  individual  yield  history.  We  will  modify 
this  program  to  permit  a  catastrophic  yield  adjustment  beginning  in  crop  year 

An  expanded  non-standard  classification  system  (NCS)  to  identify  those  farmers 
with  unusually  high  loss  histories  and  adjust  their  rates  to  more  sound  levels; 

Greater  emphasis  on  program  compliance  to  prevent  over  payments  based  on 
errors  and  abuses;  and 

Greater  risk-sharing  with  private  insurance  companies. 

Finally,  we  will  work  to  make  Federal  crop  insurance  more  farmer-fiiendly  by 
introducing  new  products,  more  flexibility,  and  more  responsiveness  to  complaints  and 
Ideas  from  farmers,  agents,  companies,  and  all  participants  in  this  program.  Just 
recently.  FCIC  for  the  first  time  used  the  authority  granted  under  the  Food.  Agriculture, 


139 


w 


Trade  and  Conservation  Act  of  1990  to  back  financially  an  innovative  new  insurance 
product  developed  by  the  private  sector.  This  process  of  partnership  will  continue. 

The  challenge  of  reforming  Federal  crop  insurance  is  complex  and  difficult,  but 
we  believe  our  plan  is  a  responsible  one  and  will  be  responsive  to  the  needs  of 
American  farmers  and  taxpayers.  We  hope  that  Congress  will  act  expeditiously  on  the 
legislation  so  that  we  may  implement  the  new  program  for  the  1995  crop  year. 

We  will  be  pleased  to  answer  any  questions  you  may  have. 

(Attachments  follow:) 


140 


is 

'"  2. 

n  o" 

b)  in 

Ol   oi 

'-  ^ 

P4 

O 

O^ 

^„^ 

^ 

♦^  H 

^-^^ 

o!    IS 

T-    0> 

>— ' 

i^in 

;— .00 

2  o> 

o>^ 

il 

si 

T-   (D 

<^  w 

o  2 
3  ? 

>   0) 

'-  ^ 

<> 

5?  ^ 

0)  T 

^.^ 

o>  "i 

T-        - 

'"  2. 

S2^ 

eo  c» 

^S 

o>2 
1  o> 

0>   T- 

00"^ 

a>  0) 

^f 

_  to 

O   w 

^..^ 

o>«> 

r^  o 

CO  > 

So 

>-  < 

^  ^ 

>  ^ 

<s 

t5>- 

0  (O 

s  *^ 

>« 

O)    u) 

(o  t: 

r-    !ii- 

.  c 

o  a> 

:£  E 

S  >> 

2  «o 

T-     -^-^ 

=  0- 

CO*     , 

Q-ra   E 

P    W    :S 

o 

^  ~       M 

1= 

UO  uj 

141 


0) 

•K 

« 

«« 

0) 

I 

If) 

o 
o 

o 
o 

o 
o 

o 
o 

o 

U) 

0 

1- 

0) 

0) 

0) 

o 

101 

0) 
00 

00 

(0 

^ 

c 

■  ^^ 

> 

OS 

m  m 

■o  w 

■o 

•  • 

0) 

^rf 

■n 

(A 

c 

<  o 

0) 

■D 

u 

c 

(0 

c 

o 

c 

> 

(0 

tn 

rgency 
Taxpay 

> 

5 

c 

•  • 

o 

re 
o 

3 
(A 

C 

Q 

o 
o 

•  ■ 

3 

o 

!5 

E 
o 
o 

■  ■ 

E 
2 

> 

(0 

> 

■5 
u 

u 

u. 

en 

Si 

3 

>• 

a 

a 

a 
o 

a: 

0) 

"3 

i2 

0) 

2 

a 

(0 

c 

1 

is 

c 
.2 

o  < 

o 

^  cc 

Ql 

H 

0  c 

Z    0) 

■i^ 

S 

1  c 

LU    o 

o  0 

a. a 
o  o 

(0 

O    0 

»1 

o  ri: 

o 
o 

0    3 

ii  E 

11 

142 


UNITED  STATES  CROP  VALVE  SUMMARY 

INSURED  CROPS 
NATIONAL  VALUE  OF  ALL  CROPS  $92,385,311,215 


CROP 


REPORTED 
ACRES 


DOLLAR 
VALUE 


PERCENT 

OF  TOTAL 

VALUE 


Com,  Grain 

Soybeans 

^Vheat 

Cotton,  Upland 

Tobacco 

Potatoes 

Nursery,  Container 

Corn,  Silage 

Oranges 

Apples 

Peanuts 

Sorghum,  Grain 

Sugar  Beets 

Rice 

Tomatoes  -  Fresh 
Barley 

Grapes  -  Processed 

Sugarcane 

Raisins 

Beans,  Dry 

Almonds 

Tomatoes  -  Processed 

Grapes,  Table 

Onions 

Peaches 

Oats 

Grapefruit 

Lemons 

Pears 

Plums  -  Fresh 

Sweet  Corn  -  Fresh 

Walnuts,  English 

Sunflowers 

Peppers 


66,950,480 
56,498,545 
69,353,948 
11,501,930 
732,740 
1,363,816 

6,124,202 
770,214 
352,114 
1,807,325 
9,086,031 
1,375,468 
2,812,429 
137,578 
7,505,000 
408,090 
723,840 
266,737 
2,099,403 
413,202 
353,911 
90,343 
146,180 
117,823 
6,015,517 
168,928 
59,816 
50,031 
45,199 
191,672 
184,837 
1,854,495 
53,513 


18,008,691,703 

11,213,520,994 

7,296,722,323 

4,884,989,171 

2,829,953,119 

2,396,315,957 

2,375,462,434 

1,954,333,349 

1,515,565,984 

1,408,875,579 

1,256,883,370 

1,203,379,180 

1,125,379,300 

1,040,085,810 

924,639,769 

906.414,000 

885,062,003 

813,706,190 

677,942,810 

660,075,798 

639,048,900 

617,956,960 

494,035,398 

493,421,041 

482,137,001 

412,485,275 

354,979,543 

347,117,610 

281,428,961 

265,029,699 

256,059,591 

254,4n,036 

247,439,110 

225,972,741 


19.493 
12.138 
7.898 
5.288 
3.063 
2.594 
2.571 
2.115 
1.640 
1.525 
1.360 
1.303 
1.218 
1.126 
1.001 
0.981 
0.958 
0.881 
0.734 
0.714 
0.692 
0.669 
0.535 
0.534 
0.522 
0.446 
0.384 
0.376 
0.305 
0.287 
0.277 
0.275 
0.268 
0.245 


.\oveinber  j,  1992' 


Page:  1 


143 


CROP  EXPANSION 
FEASIBILITY  STUDY  LIST 


Feasibility  studies  are  currently  underway  on  the 
following  crops  in  anticipation  of  developing  new 
crop  programs: 


AVOCADOS 

ASPARAGUS 

BLUEBERRIES 

BROCCOLI 

CANOLA 

CANTALOUPE 

CARROTS 

CAULIFLOWER 

CELERY 

CHERRIES-SWEET 

HAY-ALL 

HAY-HAYLAGE 

HAY-OTHER 


LETTUCE-HEAD 

LETTUCE-LEAF 

MUSHROOMS 

NURSERY  CROPS 

PECANS 

PEPPERMINT 

PINEAPPLE 

PISTACHIOS 

SEED-FORAGE 

SEED-LAWN 

STRAWBERRIES 

SWEET  POTATOES 

WATERMELON 


144 


.Participation  Under  the  Reform  Proposal 

(with  linkage) 


1S93 


1SS5    1SS6   1S97 
Crop  year 


19S8        1SS9 


Buy  up  coverage  (//;>.  Basic  coverage 


Lnder  the  reform  proposal,  producers  who  participate  in  price  support  and 

H.'^?A?^^°'^  ^""^"^  °'  "^°  ^^'^  '°^^  "^'^^^  ^°y  P^°S^  °f  'l^«  Farmers 
Home  Admmistrauoa  are  required  to  obtain  at  least  the  catastrophic  Jerel  of 
i  insurance  for  oi/  crops  of  economic  significance  farmed  in  the  county  in  which 
^a   producer  has  an  mterest.   The  linkage  with  commodity  programs  will  ensure 
tha^paruapation  m  the  crop  insurance  progr^  is  80  percent  of  eligible  acreage 

Requiring  producers  to  obtain  catastrophic  crop  insurance  ior  prog  mm  crvps  only 
would  potent.aUy  lower  the  crop  insurance  participation  rate  as  signiHcant  crops 
(eg.,  soybeans)  would  be  largely  unaffected.  Participation  rates  would  likely  be 
only  as  high  as  65-70  percent  of  eUgible  acreage. 

If  crop  insurance  is  not  linked  to  commodity  program  eUgibUity  it  is  likely 
that  crop  msurance  participation  wiU  be  only  55-60  percent  of  eU-ible 
acreage,  at  least  in  the  early  years  of  program  operation.   Lower 
participation  rates  could  encourage  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  which  would 
lunher  undermine  participation. 


145 


TARGETED  SUBSromS  FOR  BUY-UPS 
rONfPARISON  OF  FARMER'S  OUT-OF-POCKET  EXPENSE 


Wrm  TARGETED  SUBSIDY  FOR  BUY-UPS: 


Coverage 
Level 


Current 
Cost 


Cost  Under 
Reform  Act 


Difference 


65  ?S  of  yield 
75%  of  yield 


S296 
S623 


S246 
S574 


-17  percent 
-  8  percent 


WllHUUT  TARGklED  S 

lUBSroY  FOR  BUT-l 

jTS: 

Coverage 
Level 

Current 
Cost 

Cost  Under 
Reform  Act 
Without  Buy-up 
Subsidy 

Difference 

65  fS  of  yield 

S296 

S282 

-  5   percent 

75  5S  of  yield 

S623 

S609 

-  2  percent 

Assumpdons: 

100  acres  planted/    100  bushel  yield/  SI. 00  price  election 
10  percent  premium  rate  for  75  percent  coverage 

Stated  costs  axe  the  farmer's  out-of-pocket  cost  for  the  coverage  after  deducting  the 
subsidy. 


YEAfl 


1981 
19S2 
1983 
1984 
1985 
198S 
1987 
1988 
1989 
1990 
1991 
1992 
1993  (est.) 


146 


FEDEnAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 
PREMIUM/INDEMNITies/LCSS  RATIOS 
1981  -  1993  (Crop  Year  Data) 
(dollars  in  Siousancis) 


TOTAL  1951   -  1993 


AVERAGE  1981-1993 


PREMIUM 


■- 


S379,169 
398.671 
291.353 
435,588 
*39.733 
381.753 
366. 640 
•*37.654 
820,763 
838. 04O 
737,146 
758.768 
784,652 


$7,069,930 


SS43.841 


INDEMNITrSS 


$408,101 
528.157 
587.691 
639.969 
684,364 
616.993 
369,163 
1.053.775 
1.215,763 
1.023.581 
953.257 
920.901 
1,412.374 


$10,419,089 


$301,468 


1992  Figure,  -  Actuals  from  Oct.  27.  1993  Summary  of  Business 
1SS3  Figures  trom  Damage  Report  of  Oct.  20.  1993. 


LOSS  RATIO 


1.C8 
1.22 
2.02 
1.47 

1.56 

1.S2 

1.01 

2.41 

1.48 

1.23 

1.29 

1.21 

1.S0 


1.47 


1.47 


CO,MPT.nCLLE.H,.-MT/LOTUS:KWFTE 


11.'11.'93 


147 


CORN  -  PARTICIPANT 

Comparison  between  Disaster  Assistance  and  MPCI  proposed  Catastrophic  Coverage 

••DOES  NOT  INCLUDE  DEHCIENCY  PAYMENTS  RECEIVED^^ 


Assumptions:  APH  yield  =  1 20  bushels 

ASCS  Yield  =100  bushels 
MPCI  price  =  $2.40^u 
ASCS  target  price  =  $2.75^u 
ASCS  deficiency  pymt  =  $0.45^u 
Acres  planted  =  90 


Farm 

Per  Acre 

Disaster  (.5004  pro-rate) 

$3,952.00 

$43.91 

Disaster  (No  pro-rate) 

$7,898.00 

$87.76 

Catastrophic  Protection 

$7,776.00 

$86.40 

148 


FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 


CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  COMPARED  TO  DLSASTFR  ASSLSTANCF. 


CORN  NON-PARTICTPANT 


YIELD 
LOSS 

% 

100% 
PRORATE 

50% 
PRORATE 

REFORM 
PLAN 

1 

100 

$  PER  ACRE 

1 

80 

40 

86 

90 

67 

34 

69 

80 

54 

27 

52 

70 

41 

20 

35 

60 

27 

13 

17 

50 

18 

9 

0 

40 

0 

0 

0 

ASSUMPTIONS: 
COUNTY  AVERAGE  YIELD 
DISASTER  ASSIST.  PAYMENT 
APH  YIELD  (REFORM  PLAN) 
PRICE  ELECTION 


120  BUSHELS  PER  ACRE 
$1.12  PER  BUSHEL 

120  BUSHELS  PER  ACRE 
$2.40  PER  BUSHEL 


149 


FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 


«        CROP  INSLTR-AgNCE  REFORM  COMP.\R£D  TO  DISASTER  ASSISTANCE 


1                   SOYBEANS 

YIELD 
LOSS 

100% 
PRORAIH 

50% 
PRORATE 

REFORM 
PLAN 

% 

100 

$  PER  ACRE 

100 

53 

80 

90 

88 

44 

64 

80 

71 

36 

48 

70 

53 

27 

32 

60 

35 

18 

16 

50 

18 

9 

0 

40 

0 

0 

0 

ASSL'Ml'lION 
COUNTY  ANT 
DISASTER  AS 
APH  YIELD  0 
PRICE  ELEC 

S: 

:RAGE  YIELD 

SIST.  PAYMENT 

ElEFORM  PLAN) 

TION 

45  BUSHELS  1 
S3.91  PER  BUSH] 

45  BUSHELS  1 
SS.90  PER  BUSH] 

'ER  ACRE 

iL 

PER  ACRE 

EL 

150 


COTTON 

Comparison  between  Disaster  Assistance  and  MPCI  proposed  Catastrophic  Coverage 


EXAMPLX#1 


Assumptions: 


APH  yield  =  406  pounds 
ASCS  Yield  =  406  pounds 
MPCI  price  =  $0.53/Ib 
ASCS  target  pnce  =  $0.729/lb 
ASCS  deficiency  pymt  =  $0. 1 86/lb 
Acres  planted  =  92.5 


Disaster  (.5004  pro-rate) 

Farm 

$3,813.00 

Per  Acre 

$41.22 

Catastrophic  Protection 

$5,971.25 

$64.55 

Disaster  (No  pro-rate) 

$7,620.00 

$82.38 

EXAMPLE  #2 

Assumptions: 


APH  yield  =  383  pounds 
ASCS  Yield  =  406  pounds 
MPCI  price  =  $0.53/lb 
ASCS  target  pnce  =  $0.729/lb 
ASCS  deficiency  pymt  =  $0. 1 86/lb 
Acres  planted  =  92.5 


Disaster  (.5004  pro-rate) 

Farm 

$3,813.00 

Per  Acre 

$41.22 

Catastrophic  Protection 

$5,633.00 

$60.90 

Disaster  (No  pro-rate) 

$7,620.00 

$82.38 

151 


COMPARISON  BETWEEN  CATASTROPHIC  RISK  PROTECTION 

AND 
DISASTER  ASSISTANCE 

WHEAT  -  PARTICIPANT 


Bushels 
produced  per 
acre 

0 
5 

10 
15 
20 

Catastrophic 

Risk              With  .5004       With  No 
Protection          Pro-rate         Pro-rate 

$32  18                $19.44             $38.86 

$22  43                $15.07             $30.11 

$12  68                 $10.69             $21.36 

$2  93                   $6.31               $12.61 

$1.93               $3.86 

25 

30 

WHEAT  -  NONPARTICIPANT 

Bushels 
produced  per 
acre 

0 
5 

10 
15 

Catastrophic      ^.^^^  jqq^       ^j^^  nq 

'^'^^               Pro-rate         Pro-rate 
Protection 

$32.18                 $16.61              $33.20 

$22.43                 $12.42             $24.82 

$12.68                 $8.22              $16.43 

$2.93                  $4.03               $8.05 

20 

25 

30 

ASSUMPTIONS: 

33  Bushel/ Acre  ASCS  yield  and  APH  yield 

MPCI  Market  price  of  $3.25 

Target  price  of  $4.00 

Loan  price  of  $2.58 

Flex  acres  calculated  at  65  %  of  target 


152 


United  States 
Department  of 
Agriculture 


Federal  Crop 

Insurance 

Corporation 


Office  of 
The  Manager 


Washington,  D.C. 
20250 


Honorable  Collin  Peterson 
U.S.  House  of  Representatives 
1133  Lxjngworth  House  Office  Building 
Washington,  D.C.    20515-2307 

Dear  Congressman  Peterson; 

This  letter  provides  answers  to  questions  you  asked  at  the  field  hearing  for  the 
Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural  Development  of  the  House  Committee  on 
Agriculture  in  LuVeme,  Minnesota,  on  April  5,  1994. 

You  asked  about  the  difference  in  farmers'  costs  if  the  processing  fee  for  catastt-ophic 
coverage  is  assessed  at  the  rate  of  $0.50  per  acre  radier  than  the  amount  of  $50  per  crop  as 
contamed  in  the  crop  insurance  reform  proposal.    The  Department  of  Agriculture  (USD A) 
estunates  that  the  effect  would  be  minor  for  farmers  in  general.    The  fee  of  $50  per  crop  has 
an  estimated  cost  to  farmers  of  $190-200  million  during  fiscal  years  1995-1999   whereas  a 
fee  of  $0.50  per  acre  would  cost  $230-240  million  for  the  same  period.    The  reason  for  this 
relatively  small  difference  is  that  the  average  crop  policy  is  estimated  to  include  120  acres, 
which  results  in  an  average  cost  of  $60  per  policy  at  the  per  acre  fee. 

Of  course,  the  per  acre  fee  changes  the  distribution  of  costs  among  farmers.    Those 
producing  fewer  than  100  acres  of  a  crop  would  pay  less  than  the  $50  fixed  fee.    This 
appears  to  establish  a  more  equitable  distribution  of  costs  in  terms  of  ability  to  pay. 
However,  USDA  believes  that  the  cost  of  establishing  the  catastt-ophic  coverage  is  largely 
mdependent  of  acreage.    Costs  do  not  change  markedly  for  issuing  the  poUcy  and  handling 
the  papenvork  for  varying  acreages.    This  is  the  reason  USDA  proposed,  and  continues  to 
support,  the  concept  of  charging  a  fixed  fee  per  policy,  with  waivers  for  limited  resource 
farmers. 

You  also  asked  about  the  effect  of  different  subsidy  arrangements  for  the  catastrophic 
coverage.    Specifically,  you  wished  to  know  the  potential  differences  in  costs  of  varying 
catasu-ophic  coverage  levels  and  prices  (such  as  35  percent  yield,  100  percent  price 
[35/100]).    The  difference  (in  millions  of  dollars)  for  fiscal  years  1995-1999  relative  to  the 
proposed  plan  of  50  percent  coverage,  60  percent  price  (50/60)  are  shown  below: 


iir\ 


153 


Honorable  Collin  Peterson 


Alternative 

Cost 

Difference 

Coverage/Price 

50/  60 

$1,675 

N/A 

35/  100 

1,400 

$275 

50/   40 

1,120 

555 

50/    50 

1,400 

275 

50/    55 

1.550 

125 

The  costs  of  a  plan  that  provides  40  or  45  percent  coverage  of  yield  at  50  percent  of 
price  would  fall  between  the  estimates  for  50/40  and  50/50. 

Please  let  us  know  if  you  wish  to  receive  additional  information  concerning  the  reform 
proposal  and  estimated  costs  of  alternatives. 

Sincerely, 


Kenneth  D.  Ackerman 
Manager 


154 

Statement  of  AI  Christopherson,  President,  Minnesota  Farm  Bureau  Federation 
House  Agriculture  Committee,   Subcommittee  on  Environment,   Credit  and  Rural 
Development  field  hearing,  April  5,  1994 

Subject:         Clinton  Administration's  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Proposal 

Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  comment  of  federal  crop  insurance  reform  and 
its  impact  on  Mimiesota  farmers.  I  would  like  to  commend  Subcommittee  Chairman 
Johnson  and  Congressman  Minge  for  bringing  this  important  hearing  to  Minnesota  to  hear 
from  us  firsthand. 

I  would  also  like  to  commend  the  Clinton  Administration  for  recognizing  the 
tremendous  need  for  reform  of  the  federal  crop  insurance  and  disaster  programs.  With 
a  national  utilization  rate  of  less  than  30  percent,  and  average  annual  disaster  payments 
of  over  a  billion  dollars,  the  time  has  come  to  completely  overhaul  a  system  that  isn't 
working  for  farmers  or  taxpayers. 

Secretary  Espy  has  accurately  commented  that  the  current  program's  high 
premiums  and  spotty  coverage  combine  with  the  disaster  program  to  virtually  guarantee 
low  participation  in  the  program.  The  time  to  reform  the  system  in  a  serious  and 
comprehensive  manner  is  long-overdue.  The  existing  combination  of  inadequate  coverage 
and  disaster  programs  satisfies  no  one  involved. 


155 

The  stated  goal  of  the  Clinton  reform  proposal  is  to  boost  participation  in  the  crop 
insurance  program  by  providing  adequate  coverage  to  producers,  and  thereby  eliminate 
the  need  for  emergency  disaster  assistance.  The  Farm  Bureau  fully  agrees  with  this 
central  goal,  and  are  committed  to  helping  this  restructuring  occur.  Farm  Bureau 

policy  states  that  crop  disaster  programs  and  crop  insurance  should  be  combined  into  a 
single  voluntary  program  designed  to  obtain  the  greatest  amount  of  participation.  We  can 
all  agree  that  today's  pattern  should  be  replaced  with  a  more  common  sense  and 
responsible  model. 

As  you  know,  the  Clinton  plan  compels  farmers  to  purchase  the  minimum  amount 
of  federal  insurance  on  eligible  crops  to  participate  in  any  USDA  programs.  This 
mandatory  part  of  the  program  is  our  most  fundamental  practical  and  philosophical 
objection  to  this  reform  plan.  An  unattractive  crop  insurance  policy  cannot  be  made 
pretty  to  farmers  simply  by  mandating  program  participation.  This  avoidance  of  the  crop 
insurance  program's  basic  inadequacies  will  not  result  in  a  long-term  solution  to  the 
problem. 

We  need  a  program  that  makes  crop  insurance  a  good  idea  in  the  free  marketplace. 
The  shortcut  provided  by  mandated  coverage  virtually  assures  that  budgetary  and  other 
pressures  will  continue  to  force  a  federal  crop  insurance  program  that  simply  does  not 
make  sense  economically  for  the  typical  farmer.  That  is  precisely  why  participation  is 
so  low  nationwide  today. 


81-128  0-94-6 


156 

The  mandatory  provisions,  combined  with  a  cost  that  is  bound  to  grow  with  time 
and  budgetary  pressures,  also  establishes  a  state-control  mechanism  that  could  become 
extremely  costly  to  farmers.  Although  the  fees  for  catastrophic  coverage  are  very  limited 
in  the  initial  proposal,  fiscal  realities  suggest  that  this  pricing  system  would  not  remain 
inexpensive  long. 

Farm  Bureau  policy  has  consistenUy  opposed  mandatory  linkages  between  crop 
insurance  and  farmer  program  eligibility.  The  more  cross-compliance  restrictions  and 
mandatory  conditions  we  add  to  federal  programs,  the  less  basic  business  decisions  are 
left  up  to  the  farmer  in  the  marketplace. 

In  addition.  Farm  Bureau  members  oppose  the  program's  continued  reliance  on 
yield  as  a  trigger  mechanism  for  insurance  payout.  Coverage  based  on  dollars  per  acre 
would  make  much  more  sense.  Reliance  on  yield  as  the  determinant  tends  to  skew  the 
program  in  favor  of  high-risk  production  acres  and  makes  it  much  more  likely  that  gaps 
in  coverage  will  exist. 

Although  we  recognize  that  full  consideration  of  crop  insurance  reform  may  not 
occur  until  the  1995  Farm  BUI.  pledge  our  commitment  to  working  with  the 
Administration  and  Congress  to  design  a  workable  program  that  meets  all  of  our  goals. 

I  am  convinced  that  all  parties  can  come  together  to  fix  a  system  that  is  clearly 
broken.  Again,  however,  in  order  to  do  that,  we  simply  must  design  an  insurance 
program  that  good  businesspersons  will  want  to  purchase.  Wider  mandated  coverage 
simply  eliminates  that  possibUity  and  further  complicates  the  maze  of  govermnent 
requirements. 


157 


April   5,    1994 

United  States  House  of  Representatives 

Committee  on  Agriculture 

Sub -Committee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 

Comments  to  the  hearing  on  the  Administration's  Crop  Insurance  Proposal 

VFW  Hall  in  Luveme,  Minnesota 

Testimony  provided  on  behalf  of  the  Minnesota  Corn  Growers 

Association   and   the  Minnesota   Soybean   Growers  Association 

by  Richard  Peterson  of  Mountain  Lake,   Minnesota 

I  would  like  to  thank  the  committee  for  coming  to  Minnesota  to  hear  our 
concerns  regarding  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform.  My  name  is  Richard 
Peterson  and  I  am  here  today  to  represent  the  Minnesota  Corn  Growers 
Association  and  the  Minnesota  Soybean  Growers  Association.  I  am  a 
farmer  from  southwestern  Minnesota,  by  Mountain  Lake,  where  I  grow  corn 
and  soybeans. 

We  feel  the  catastrophic  coverage  for  insurable  crops  is  adequate  for 
it's  intended  purpose.  The  cost  per  crop,  not  to  exceed  $100.00  per 
producer,  per  county,  will  penalize  producers  farming  in  more  than  one 
county  if  language  is  left  as  is.  It  would  be  beneficial  to  address 
limits  for  producers  farming  in  multiple  counties  or  states. 


158 


In  requiring  producers  to  obtain  this  coverage  to  be  eligible  for  price 
support,  production  adjustments  and  conservation  programs,  you  will  most 
likely  find  some  who  object.  Our  position  is  that  it  seems  reasonable 
and  we  do  not  object  to  these  requirements. 

We  are  pleased  that  producers  will  have  a  choice  under  the  dual  delivery 
system.  They  may  sign  up  in  programs  and  insurance  at  the  same  time,  or 
they  may  complete  applications  for  the  catastrophic  coverage  when  they 
buy  additional  coverage  from  their  crop  insurance  agent.  The  only 
concerns  we  have  are  the  costs  to  train  and/or  the  increases  in 
paperwork  this  may  cause  our  government  offices,  currently  ASCS  offices, 
which  would  be  renamed  Farmers  Service  Agency  under  the  restructuring  of 
the  USDA. 

The  use  of  Actual  Production  History  (A.P.H.)  for  the  four  (4)  previous 
crop  years,  building  up  to  ten  (10)  years,  along  with  transitional 
yields  (T-yields)  if  A.P.H.  is  not  available,  is  a  step  in  the  right 
direction.  Prevented  planting  and  disaster  considerations  should  allow 
for  A.P.H.  and  county  averages  to  be  maintained  at  realistic  levels. 

We  support  the  requirement  for  producers  to  insure  all  land  (production) 
in  the  county  for  that  particular  crop.  This  broad  coverage  will  help 
the  actuarial  soundness  of  catastrophic  and  higher  levels  of  coverage. 


159 


The  buy-up  coverage  needs  to  be  written  as  an  incentive  rather  than  a 
dis-incentive  for  the  75%  coverage  level.  These  premium  rates  should  be 
set  much  like  hail  insurance  on  a  county  by  county  basis.  Whatever 
levels  of  premium  subsidies  are  available,  it  should  favor  the  75%  or 
higher,  rather  than  lower.  Doing  this  will  contribute  more  premium 
dollars  to  the  insurance  program,  with  a  greater  percentage  of  producers 
participating,  because  the  coverage  will  more  closely  reflect  the  cost 
of  production.  Extremely  broad  coverage,  including  most  all  producers, 
will  be  necessary  to  eliminate  the  political  need  for  ad  hoc  disaster 
programs.  Higher  levels  of  coverage  will  help  accomplish  this.  We 
would  also  favor  consideration  of  85%  coverage  level  being  available  for 
farmers  who  wish  to  purchase  it . 

We  have  a  concern  that  the  proposed  Group  Risk  Plan  doesn't  appear  to 
make  allowances  for  the  variation  of  productivity  within  counties.  Many 
counties  vary  widely  from  rich  productive  soils  to  lessor  or  upland 
soils  within  county  lines.  The  Market  Value  Protection  Plan  is  new  and 
will  be  more  slowly  accepted.  We  feel  the  plan  has  potential  and  should 
be  offered  through  private  insurance  agents  who  can  assist  the  producer 
with  this  more  technical  plan.  This  protection  plan  may  need  to  be 
tried  as  an  experiment  or  on  a  trial  basis  to  check  out  its  effect  for 
both  the  producer  and  the  protector. 


160 

in  addition,  we  want  to  be  certain  preventative  and  late  plantings  for 
corn  and  soybeans  are  included  in  basic  coverage.   Also,  we  would  like 
to  improve  the  price  selection  formula  to  be  more  realistic  for  current 
corn  and  soybean  prices. 

we  feel  that  the  Administration's  Crop  Insurance  Proposal  is  a  big  step 
in  the  right  direction  and  applaud  all  those  involved  in  making  the 
progress  this  proposal  brings.  We  wish  to  thank  Congressman  Minge  for 
requesting  this  hearing,  so  that  additional  discussion  has  the 
opportunity  to  enhance  this  proposal's  outcome. 


161 

PRESENTED  BY  FRANCIS  BUSCHETTE, 
MEMBER  OF  MINNESOTA  ASSOCIATION  OF  WHEAT  GROWERS 

RENVILLE,  MN 

My  name  is  Francis  Buschette  and  I  farm  near  Renville,  Minnesota. 
I  am  testilying  on  behalf  of  the  Minnesota  Association  of  Wheat  Growers. 

We  appreciate  this  opportunity  to  express  our  views  on  the 
proposed  Federal  Crop  Insurance  reform  and  whether  it  could  adequately 
replace  disaster  programs. 

Let  me  begin  by  saying  that  the  Minnesota  Association  of  Wheat 
Growers  would  support  a  significantly  improved  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
program  over  the  disaster  programs  we  have  had  in  the  past. 

We  recognize  the  funding  problems  associated  with  having  both  an 
improved  crop  insurance  program  and  a  standing  disaster  program. 
However,  we  believe,  an  adequate,  affordable  and  proven  new  insurance 
program  should  be  operational  before  all  disaster  authority  is  abandoned. 
A  strong  basis  for  development  of  a  viable  new  program  is  on  the  board. 
But  until  such  a  time  that  a  new  regime  of  yield  and  price  risk  protection  is 
proven  to  be  effective,  we  urge  continued  standby  authority  for  disaster 
relief  programs. 

On  the  specifics  of  crop  insurance  reform,  we  strongly  support  the 
Actual  Production  History  (APH)  based  on  four  years;  however,  a  high 


Page  I 


162 

priority  for  FCIC  should  be  to  develop  and  implement  a  catastrophic  yield 
clause.  This  would  stop  the  APH  yield  reductions  for  producers  in  a  region 
that  has  experienced  abnormally  high  losses  during  the  four  years  of  the  APH. 
This  need  is  very  evident  in  Minnesota  when  you  consider  that  the  losses  due 
to  a  100  year  flood  will  account  for  25  percent  of  an  individual's  APH.  On 
the  positive  side,  the  decision  to  use  individual  APH  as  a  base  for  catastrophic 
yield  coverage  instead  of  an  average  or  ASCS  yield  is  very  important  and  is  a 
welcomed  improvement  over  the  disaster  program. 

In  another  comparison,  we  find  that  the  disaster  program  has  an  advantage  over 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  when  it  comes  to  de  minimus  yields.  The  lack  of  a  de 
minimus  yield  for  crop  insurance  has  been  a  glaring  negative  factor  for  growers, 
especially  in  light  of  ASCS  implementing  a  de  minimus  yield  in  last  year's 
disaster  program.  This  inequity  needs  to  be  corrected. 

For  many  wheat  producers,  the  catastrophic  coverage  will  not  be  adequate  to 
meet  their  risk  management  needs,  so  they  will  want  to  purchase  additional 
insurance.  The  reform  proposal,  with  additional  funding,  should  provide 
reductions  in  premiums  at  the  higher  coverage  levels.  This  would  be  very 
important  for  long-term  crop  insurance  customers  who  will  want  to  see  benefits 
from  reform. 


163 

One  possible  benefit  could  be  reduced  premiums  at  the  65  and  75  percent 
coverage  levels  under  the  proposed  reforms.  Nevertheless,  what  effect  this  reform 
proposal  will  actually  have  on  premiums  for  increased  coverage  is  something  we'll  want 

to  know. 

Finally,  we  beheve  that  additional  premium  subsidies  should  be  extended  to 
the  65  and  75  percent  coverage  levels,  which  would  help  make  this  reform  package 
adequate  enough  to  replace  disaster  programs. 

Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  express  our  views. 


Page  3 


164 


Testimony 

on  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  1994 

Before  the  U.S.  House  Committee 

on 

Agriculture  Sub-Committee  on  General  Farm  Commodities 


Aprils,  1994 
Luveme,  Minnesota 


Presented  by 

Gerald  Lacey  President  of 

National  Barley  Growers  Association 

Campbell,  Minnesota 


165 


Good  Morning.    My  name  is  Gerald  Lacey.  I  grow  barley,  wheat  and 
sugarbeets  with  my  son  on  a  farm  near  Campbell,  Minnesota.  I  am  cur- 
rently serving  as  the  President  of  the  National  Barley  Growers  Association. 
It  is  an  honor  for  me  to  present  this  testimony  in  front  of  this  select  commit- 
tee. We,  as  farmers,  understand  that  reform  is  needed  to  keep  abreast  with 
the  ever  changing  world.  We  also  understand  the  difference  between 
meaningful  reform  and  budget  driven,  political  reform.  It  is  difficult  for  me  to 
testify  upon  this  proposal  when  the  Senate  just  voted  to  reduce  expendi- 
tures for  the  proposal  by  $250  million.  I  would  hope  that  you  as  elected 
officials  would  put  aside  the  political  bickering  and  assist  us  producers  in 
establishing  a  Federal  Crop  Insurance  policy  that  would  adequately  protect 
us  from  the  whimsical  ways  of  Mother  Nature.  I  would  like  to  address  three 
main  concerns  in  my  testimony:  ;  -    ••^ 

1 .  Same  percentage  rate  of  subsidy  for  65%,  75%  and     85%  price  se 
lection  level.  •      '       ■      -     ''        ^ '■ 

2.  Allow  ASCS  to  sell  policies. 

3.  Support  a  Gross  Revenue  Insurance  Pilot  Program  for  Minnesota, 
Mississippi  and  North  Dakota.  :  ^  -c 


se- 


1)  Same  percentage  rate  of  subsidy  for  the  65%.  75%  and  85%  price 
lection  levels: 


We  agree  that  a  catastrophic  coverage  must  be  offered  to  producers  in 
order  to  get  participation  up  to  that  levd  where  everyone  will  feel  comfort- 


166 

able  that  there  will  be  no  more  ad  hoc  disaster  bills.  We  would  suggest 
increasing  the  rate  of  subsidy  provided  for  enrollment  in  the  65  percent 
level  and  also  for  the  75  percent  level  and  the  proposed  85  percent  level  of 
price  protection.  Producers  are  being  pushed  into  the  higher  price  selec- 
tion levels  because  of  the  constant  increase  in  the  cost  of  production. 

2)  Administrative  Costs: 

I  have  taken  out  Federal  Crop  Insurance  from  my  agent  since  1989. 
During  that  time  I  have  helped  him  enjoy  a  very  good  standard  of  living 
because  of  the  guaranteed  commission.  I  would  like  to  suggest  that  we 
allow  the  ASCS  offices  the  opportunity  to  sell  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
policies.  This  is  not  new  or  unique,  but  something  they  have  handled  in  the 
past.  I  would  also  suggest  that  the  ASCS  offices  charge  a  10  percent  fee  to 
cover  their  costs  of  doing  business.  Perhaps  this  could  be  done  on  a  pilot 
project  basis.  I  make  this  suggestion  in  the  hopes  that  the  insurance  com- 
panies will  be  challenged  to  make  their  money  competitively  in  the  market, 
not  through  a  controlled,  guaranteed  system.  The  burden  of  balancing  the 
budget  should  not  have  to  be  bom  solely  by  the  producers  and  not  the  rest 
of  the  industry. 

3)  Pilot  Program 

As  a  representative  of  the  Minnesota  Barley  Growers  Association  I  would 
also  like  to  speak  in  support  of  introducing  a  Gross  Revenue  Insurance 


167 


Program  on  a  trial  basis  in  Minnesota,  Mississippi  and  North  Dakota.  My 
thoughts  behind  this  are  fairly  simple.  Lenders  are  not  all  that  concerned 
about  how  many  bushels  a  producer  grows  per  acre  but  rather  in  how  many 
dollars  per  acre  that  fanner  produces.  We  would  like  to  see  if  we  couldn't 
devise  a  program  that  would  have  a  farmer  insure  his  gross  revenue.  Al- 
though many  of  the  technical  points  will  have  to  be  worked  out,  what  I  envi- 
sion is  a  program  whereby  a  producer  would  be  able  to  insure  his  minimum 
gross  income  based  on  perhaps  his  last  5  >^rs  average  gross  income  as 
shown  on  his  individual  tax  fomn. 

I  would  like  to  thank  the  Committee  for  listening  to  my  testimony  and 
would  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions  you  may  have. 


168 


minnEsoTn 

FnnmERs 

union 


Office  of  tfie  President 


STATEMENT  OF 

DAVID  J.  FREDERICKSON,  PRESIDENT 

MINNESOTA  FARMERS  UNION 


SUBMITTED  TO 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT, 

CREDIT.  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

UNITED  STATES  HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

APRIL  5.  1994 

LUVERNE.  MINNESOTA 


600  County  Road  D  West  •  SuHe  14  •  St.  Paul.  MN  55112-3521   •  (612)  639-1223  •  FAX  (612)  639^)421 


169 


I  want  to  thank  the  Chairman  and  members  of  the  sub-committee  for 
holding  this  hearing  in   Representative  Minge's  District.     The  Second 
Congressional   District  was  one  of  the  most  severely  affected  by  the 
flooding  of   1993. 

The   following    is   written   testimony   explaining    Minnesota   Farmers 
Union's  views  on  a  variety  of  issues  related  to  crop  insurance  reform. 

1)The  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage  -  The  current  proposal  would 
provide  coverage  at  60  percent  of  the  target  price,  on  losses  exceeding  50 
percent.     This  yields  coverage  at  $.30/$1.00  of  loss  in  years  where  the 
producer  suffers  a  total  loss.     This  compares  to  the  1993  disaster 
program  which  paid  $.42/$1.00  of  loss  and  the  1992  program  which  paid 
$.19  -$.21/$1.00  of  loss,  (depending  on  whether  or  not  the  producer  had 
crop   insurance.) 

From  a  lenders  perspective,  the  catastrophic  coverage  is  superior,  since 
it  can  be  available  to  producers  whether  or  not  they  reside  in  a  disaster- 
declared  county. 

If  funding   permits,   it  would  be  helpful  to  increase  the  sixty  percent  to  a 
figure  closer  to   100  percent  of  target  price,   still   using  the   50  percent 
deductible. 

Catastrophic  coverage  should  include  coverage  for  late  and  prevented 
planting,    as  well   as  disaster-related   quality   loss. 


2)  The  processing  fee  -  The  processing  fee  is  very  reasonable.     The  draft 
language  states  that  the  fee  will  be  waived  for  those  who  purchase 
additional  coverage      How  will  this  work  for  those  who  obtain  the 
catastrophic  level  of  coverage  at  the  Farm  Service  Agency,  and  then  obtain 
additional  coverage  through  a  private  agency?      Who  covers  the 
reimbursement? 


170 


-2 


3)  Mandatory  coverage  -  National  Farmers  Union  supports  making  coverage 
mandatory  for  farm  program  participants.     However,  farmers  may  have  a 
different  position  if  the  processing  fee  were  to  be  increased. 


4)  The  dual  delivery  system  -  Dual  delivery  offers  producers  the  option  of 
where  to  obtain  the  catastrophic  coverage.     It  also  raises  some  questions. 
Who  will  do  the  adjusting?     Who  will  pay  the  administrative  cost  if  the 
producer  obtains  coverage  from  both  the  FSA  and  the  private  agent? 


5)  The  use  of  actual  production  history  (APH)  -  the  use  of  actual 
production   history  (APH)  should  make  crop  insurance  a  better  product  for 
producers  who  are  at>ove  the  county  average.     It  should  also  help  in 
preventing  farmers  from  farming  the  program.      However,   years  in  which 
the  producer  resided  in  a  disaster  -  declared  area  should  be  excluded  from 
the  APH.     This  could  be  accomplished  by  using  the  last  four  non-disaster 
years  of  production   history. 


6)  The  requirement  to  insure  all  land  in  the  county  for  a  particular  crop  - 
It  is  appropriate  to  require  a  producer  to  include  all  land  in  a  county  for  a 
particular  crop.     However,  dry-land  crops,  e.g.  wheat,  should  not  be 
averaged  in  with  irrigated  crops.     These  should  be  separate  units. 


7)  Adequacy  of     buy-up  coverage  for  insurable  crops  -  Buy-up  coverage 
should  extend  higher  than  the  75  percent  election. 


8)  Provisions  of  non-insured  crops  -  This  question  is  unclear      Does  "non- 
insured"  mean  no  insurance  is  available  or  that  the  producer  chooses  not 
to  purchase  insurance?    NFU  recommends  that  a  producer  be  required 


171 


-3- 


to  establish  production  history  before  being  allowed  to  insure  a  crop  that 
has  never  been  planted  in  previous  years.     This  will  guard  against 
producers  farming  the  program. 


9)  The  amount  of  premium  subsidies  at  different  levels  of  coverage  -  If 
the  goal  is  to  encourage  producers  to  purchase  adequate  coverage,  than  a 
subsidy  should  be  offered  as  a  percent  of  the  premium,  instead  of  as  a  flat 
dollar  amount.     The  current  subsidy,  which  is  the  same  whether  the 
producer  purchases  coverage  at  the  65  or  75  percent  level,  encourages 
producers  to  purchase  only  65  percent  coverage. 

10)  Likelihood  that  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  will  no  longer  be  available  - 
Farmers  Union   supports  maintaining  the  Secretary's  authority  to  call  for 
disaster  assistance,   if  needed,   recognizing  that  these   reform   provisions 
will   significantly   reduce  the   need  for  disaster  assistance. 


In   conclusion,  I  would  like  to  include  for  the  record  the  SPECIAL  ORDER  OF 
BUSINESS  relating  to  crop  insurance  adopted  by  the  deJegates  at  the 
National  Farmers  Union  Convention  in  March  7.  1994 


(Attachment  follows:) 


172 


SPECIAL  ORDER  OF  BUSINESS 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform 

Adopted  by  National  Farmers  Union 
March  7.   1994 

We  commend  the  Administration  for  supporting  the  reform  of  the 
of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  program. 

We  support  provisions  which  would  provide  catastrophic  coverage  as 
a  benefit  of   participation   in  commodity  programs  or  Farmers   Home 
Administration    lending    programs. 

We  support  allowing  producers  to  base  yield  coverage  on  actual 
production   history   (APH). 

We  support  offering  producers  assistance  to  purchase  coverage 
above  the  catastrophic  level. 

We  support  ottering  coverage  for  late  or  prevented  plantings. 

We  call  on  .Congress  to  make  the  following  additions  to  the  above- 
stated    provisions. 

1.     We  support  increasing  catastrophic  coverage  from  the  proposed 
60  percent  of  coverage  to  100  percent  of  the  expected  market  price 

2      We  support  allowing  producers  to  exclude  disaster  years  from 
APH   calculations. 

3.     We  support  adding  an  additional  level  of  coverage  higher  than  the 
75  percent  level. 


173 


-2- 


4.  We  support  basing  the  expected  price  on  the  higher  of  the  target 
price  or  the  5  year  rolling  average  of  the  12  month  market  phce. 

5.  We  support  requiring  insurance  companies  to  offer  both  APH  and 
area  yield  options  to  producers. 

6.  We  support  maintaining  the  Secretary's  authority  to  call  for 
disaster  assistance,   it  needed,   recognizing  that  these  reform   provisions 
will   significantly   reduce  the   need  for  di^tster   assistance. 


174 

APRIL  5,  1994 

ORAL  TESTIMONY  OF  MIKE  CROWLEY 
CROP  AGENCY,  INC. 


I  would  like  to  thank  the  Chairman.  Congressman  Johnson,  the 
Congressional  Committee  and  Mr.  Ken  Ackerman  for  the  opportunity  to 
speak  here  today. 

I  farmed  for  7  years,  worked  In  the  crop  insurance  industry  as  a 
company  representative  for  several  years  and  for  the  past  7  years  have 
worked  as  an  Independent  Insurance  agent  working  directly  with  the 
farmer  and  crop  insurance  needs.  These  experiences  have  allowed  me  to 
observe  all  aspects  of  the  needs  of  the  farmer  regarding  the  crop 
insurance  program. 

Crop  insurance  offers  our  farmers  the  opportunity  to  protect 
themselves  from  financial  disaster.  The  existing  program  needs  some 
changes  in  order  to  meet  today's  needs.  I  would  like  to  present  some 
of  the  changes  that  I  feel  will  enhance  the  program  and  provide  the 
necessary  disaster  protection  that  today's  farmer  needs.  I  will  use 
the  male  pronoun,  he:  although  I  realize  that  there  are  many  female 
farmers  In  our  area  both  as  independents  and  partners. 

As  we  look  at  the  existing  program  in  our  area,  the  APH  program  has 
worked  fairly  well.  The  problem  has  been  that  we  have  had  a  number  of 
years,  1988  and  1993  for  example,  that  have  been  catastrophe  years. 
When  these  two  years  are  figured  into  the  APH  calculation  the  farmer's 
ability  to  insure  at  adequate  levels  is  greatly  reduced.  A  key  factor 
for  the  program  to  work  for  the  farmer  Is  that  it  be  set  up  so  that  an 
adequate  amount  of  protection  can  be  purchased.  Due  to  bad  weather 
conditions  the  farmer  may  be  placed  in  a  high  loss  situation  which  he 
has  no  control  over.  The  farmer  certainly  doesn't  choose  the  bad 
weather  and  the  loss  has  nothing  to  do  with  his  farming  practices.  I 
would  like  to  see  the  catastrophe  years  removed  from  the  1.1  loss 
ratio  that  Is  being  calculated.  If  a  farmer  goes  over  the  1.1  loss 
ratio  today,  he  is  subject  to  the  non-standard  classification  level. 
This  results  in  higher  rates  and  higher  expenses  to  him. 

In  the  past  few  years  we  have  seen  a  lot  of  changes  in  farm  size.  One 
farmer  increases  his  number  of  acres,  another  decreases  his  farm  size 
and  another  quits  altogether.  This  presents  another  problem  for  the 
crop  insurance  program.  This  same  problem  exists  for  the  new  farmer 
Just  beginning  his  farming  career.  The  new  producer  and  the  farmer 
increasing  his  operation  is  limited  to  the  T-yleld  factor.  I  would 
like  to  see  this  T-yield  factor  removed  from  the  calculation  and 
replaced  with  a  straight  ASCS  yield.  This  should  apply  for  2  to  3 
years,  allowing  the  farmer  to  have  adequate  protection  and  to 
establish  his  normal  yield  protection  limit.   The  program  should  allow 


175 


this  new  land  to  be  insurable  at  level  3  (75%)  during  this  2  to  3  year 
per  i  od. 

I  have  several  concerns  about  the  new  proposed  crop  Insurance  program. 
As  I  now  understand  it,  the  proposal  Is  to  give  each  farmer  50% 
coverage  for  a  flat  fee  of  $50.00  per  crop  or  SlOO  per  county.  I  feel 
that  this  will  give  the  farmer  a  false  sense  of  security  since  It  only 
covers  the  bottom  level  of  coverage.  Will  his  banker  be  willing  to 
accept  this  as  security?  If  he  chooses  the  minimum  50%  level  of 
coverage  and  there  is  another  disaster.  I  think  that  there  will  be 
tremendous  pressure  put  on  the  Federal  Government  to  grant  additional 
disaster  aid.  I  understand  there  are  additional  by-up  policies.  I 
have  not  seen  any  costs  for  these  additional  by-ups  so  the  question 
still  remains  -  will  these  policies  be  at  a  fair  price  or  cost 
prohibitive  to  the  farmer.  The  aim  of  the  new  program  is  to  eliminate 
the  disaster  program.  It  will  not  happen  with  the  50%  level  of 
protection.  We  will  have  the  same  program  that  is  currently  in  force 
-  but  it  will  have  cost  more  money! 

The  program  also  proposes  a  dual  delivery  system.  These  being  the  new 
Farm  Service  Agency  and  the  independent  agent.  This  will  not  be 
efficient.  First  of  all  is  the  expense  of  hiring  and  training  the 
Farm  Service  Agency  office  staff  -  who  will  pay  this  cost 
(taxpayers?)!  Secondly,  it  is  going  to  be  very  confusing  to  the 
farmer  to  have  2  different  delivery  systems  and  explanations  of  the 
program. 

Under  the  current  system  the  farmer  pays  for  his  coverage  on  a 
subsidized  basis.  What  is  being  proposed  is  to  use  the  disaster 
dollars  to  give  him  his  coverage.  It  seems  that  it  would  make  more 
sense  to  use  those  current  dollars  (disaster  money)  each  year  to  shore 
up  the  existing  system  with  adequate  protection.  Subsidize  the  75% 
level  at  a  higher  rate  and  most  farmers  will  be  properly  protected  at 
a  lower  cost  to  the  government. 

I  believe  that  the  producers  in  our  area  would  rather  have  a  higher 
level  of  coverage  at  a  fair  rate.  If  we  could  get  more  producers  to 
purchase  the  75%  level  of  coverage,  with  30%  subsidies,  I  believe  that 
we  could  make  the  program  more  cost  effective  for  the  farmer  and  the 
government.  The  farmer  would  receive  a  higher  level  of  coverage.  To 
make  this  actuarially  sound,  we  need  to  have  every  farmer 
participating  in  the  (^rop  Insurance  Program.  With  every  producer 
using  crop  Insurance,  all  additional  disaster  programs  would  be 
e 1 Imi  nated. 

Another  tremendous  problem  with  the  proposed  system  is  charging  the 
farmer  a  maximum  of  $100  for  the  50%  level  per  county  with  no  regard 
to  the  great  differential  in  farm  size.  Is  it  fair  to  charge  the 
farmer  with  160  acres  the  same  dollars  as  the  farmer  with  800  acres? 
The  exposure  to  the  government  and  tax  payer  is  much  larger  with  the 
large  farm.  Need  -  for  the  farmer  in  disaster  relief  may  be  the  same 
or  greater.  Each  farmer/producer  should  be  obligated  to  pay  his 
share . 


176 


In  summary,  v/hat  I  really  feel  needs  to  be  accomplished  with  the  crop 
insurance  program  Is  increased  guarantees  and  the  use  of  subsidy 
dollars  to  Improve  the  current  program.  Today's  farmer  is  willing  to 
pay  his  fair  share  -  if  he  is  getting  adequate  protection.  He  doesn't 
want  a  'free  program'  that  still  leaves  him  with  a  great  deal  of 
uncertainty.  He  deals  with  uncertainty  every  day  when  he  checks  the 
weather!  We  need  to  provide  these  valuable  business  people  with 
guaranteed  protection,  at  a  reasonable  premium  -  with  a  workable 
system.  I  ask  for  your  support  in  not  creating  another  area  for 
Federal  bureaucracy  and  control.  Allow  the  farmer  choices  and 
opportunities  -  and  most  importantly,  essential  support.  I  ask  you  to 
use  existing  dollars  to  modify  the  current  system  into  one  that  is 
equitible  and  fair  to  all.  This  will  Include  the  farmer  and  all  U.S. 
ci  t izens. 

Thank  you  for  allowing  me  this  time  to  speak  to  you.  I  appreciate  the 
opportunity  to  present  my  ideas  and  thoughts  on  this  very  important 

issue . 


(Actachment  follows:) 


177 


TO:  COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

FROM:  MIKE  CROWLEY 

CROP  AGENCY.  INC. 
1508  N.  DOUGLAS 
WORTHINGTON  MN  56187 
TELEPHONE:  (507)372-741 1 

REGARDING:  WRITTEN  TESTIMONY  ON  VARIOUS  ISSUES  ADDRESSED  IN  THE  MARCH 
18,  1994  LETTER  AND  APRIL  5,  1994  HEARING  DEALING  WITH  THE  FEDERAL 
CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  ACT  OF  1994 

1.  ADEQUACY  OF  CATASTROPHIC  COVERAGE  FOR  INSURABLE  CROPS  Coverage 
is  available  to  the  farmer  at  this  time  but  the  complaint  that  we  hear 
most  often  Is  that  the  coverage  Is  not  enough.  The  current  coverage 
will  cover  most  production  expenses  but  in  the  unpredictable  business 
of  farming  this  level  of  protection  may  not  be  enough  to  keep  him  In 
business.  What  the  farmer  wants  is  a  higher  guarantee  level  which 
should  probably  be  85%  of  their  normal  guarantee.  Today  most  farmers 
only  purchase  the  level  2  coverage  at  65%  of  their  guarantee  at  the 
price  election.  If  they  could  purchase  75  to  85%  of  their  guarantee 
at  the  same  subsidized  rate  as  level  1  and  2  they  would  be  able  to 
afford  the  coverage.  Level  1  and  2  are  subsidized  by  30%,  level  3  is 
subsidized  at  approximately  15%.  With  a  subsidy  of  30%  on  the  level  3 
most  farmers  would  carry  level  3  rather  than  level  2.  This  would 
insure  them  at  75%  of  their  APH.  If  the  farmer  is  insured  at  level  3 
(75%)  lt_gr_eatly  reduces  the  need  for  a  disaster  program. 

2.  PROCESSING  FEE  OF  »50  PER  PRODUCER  PER  CROP  PER  COUNTY,  NOT  TO 
EXCEED  »100  PER  PRODUCER  PER  COUNTY  This  is  one  of  the  most  unfair 
items  proposed  in  the  new  crop  insurance  program.  If  you  have  160 
acres  or  800  acres  you  pay  the  same  *100.  Does  this  make  sense?  I 
don't  think  so.  The  potential  exposure  is  not  the  same  at  all. 
Consider  this:  if  the  160  acre  farm  has  a  total  disaster  and  is  paid 
the  maximum  on  80  acres  of  corn  and  80  acres  of  beans  he  would  receive 
«23.280.  If  he  had  800  acres  <400  acres  corn  and  400  acres  beans)  he 
would  receive  $116,400.   This  makes  no  sense  at  all. 

3.  REQUIREMENT  THAT  PRODUCERS  MUST  OBTAIN  CATASTROPHIC  COVERAGE  TO  BE 
ELIGIBLE  FOR  PRICE  SUPPORT,  PRODUCTION  ADJUSTMENT  AND  CONSERVATION 
PROGRAMS  This  Is  Important  as  It  provides  the  vehicle  that  Insures  a 
very  high  level  of  participation  In  the  crop  Insurance  program.  For 
example.  Nobles  County  In  Minnesota  has  a  high  level  of  participation 
and  a  large  amount  of  premium  has  been  collected  over  the  years.  When 
large  losses  occur  such  as  in  1993  an  adequate  amount  of  money  has 
been  collected  over  the  years  to  pay  for  the  losses.  By  having  a 
large  percentage  of  participation  this  will  help  to  make  the  program 
actuarially  sound.  If  all  farmers  nationwide  are  required  to  purchase 
crop  Insurance  coverage  on  at  least  level  2  (65%)  there  would  be  a 
great  deal  of  money  coming  Into  the  program.   This  would  reduce  the 


178 


amount  of  money  needed  from  the  government  to  subsidize  the  program. 
Participation  could  perhaps  be  monitored  by  having  an  area  on  tax 
returns  to  mark  -  YES,  I  purchase  crop  Insurance;  NO,  I  do  not 
purchase  crop  Insurance.  I  feel  that  we  need  less,  not  more 
government  intervention  in  the  crop  insurance  program  but  using  the 
tax  return  could  help  to  insure  100%  participation. 

4.  DUAL  DELIVERY  SYSTEM:  CATASTROPHIC  COVERAGE  MAY  BE  PURCHASED 
EITHER  AT  USDA  SERVICE  CENTERS  OR  THROUGH  PRIVATE  INSURANCE  AGENCTS; 
ADDITIONAL  COVERAGE  MAY  BE  PURCHASED  ONLY  FROM  PRIVATE  AGENTS  I 
really  feel  that  this  would  be  a  very  bad  system.  A  dual  delivery 
system  Just  will  not  work.  It  would  be  Inefficient,  costly  and 
confusing.  The  Farm  Service  Agency  (ASCS)  currently  has  it's  hands 
full  providing  adequate  service  to  the  farmer.  With  the  additional 
responsibility  of  crop  Insurance  It  would  be  necessary  to  hire  more 
employees.  Currently  crop  insurance  is  handled  by  independent  agents 
and  staff.  As  an  example  of  the  work  force  needed  to  service  crop 
insurance  I  will  outline  my  agency.  I  work  full  time  servicing  only 
crop  insurance.  I  have  one  additional  full  time  agent/service 
representative  and  3  parttime  employees.  Crop  Insurance  is  the  only 
thing  we  work  with.  A  high  level  of  knowledge  and  expert  ice  is 
necessary  because  we  are  working  with  a  farmer's  source  of  livelihood. 
Further,  there  are  many  other  agencies  In  Nobles  County  that  sell  and 
service  crop  insurance  on  a  full  or  parttime  basis.  The  total  number 
of  people  needed  to  handle  crop  insurance  is  very  high.  How  many 
additional  employees  are  you  willing  to  hire  and  pay  to  handle  the 
proposed  program?  Who  will  bear  this  tremendous  cost?  Are  you 
willing  to  put  many  independent  agencies  out  of  business  and  thousands 
of  employees  out  of  their  Jobs?  This  will  reduce  tax  revenue. 

5.  USE  OF  ACTUAL  PRODUCTION  HISTORY  (APH)  FOR  THE  4  PREVIOUS  CROP 
YEARS,  BUILDING  UP  TO  10  YEARS,  AND  THE  USE  OF  TRANSITIONAL  YIELDS 
(T-YIELDS)  IF  APH  IS  NOT  AVAILABLE  I  believe  in  the  Actual 
Production  History  (APH)  and  I  feel  that  the  4  year  average  building 
up  to  10  years  would  be  fair.  I  would  like  to  see  the  transitional 
yields  (T-yields)  removed  and  replaced  with  the  full  ASCS  yield  or 
some  form  of  transferring  yield  history  from  one  producer  to  another 
based  on  similar  ASCS  yields  and  soil  conditions. 

6.  REQUIREMENT  FOR  PRODUCERS  TO  INSURE  ALL  LAND  IN  THE  COUNTY  FOR  A 
PARTICULAR  CROP  All  acres  of  a  particular  crop  should  be  insured. 
This  helps  to  make  the  program  actuarially  sound.  For  example:  You 
farm  600  acres.  400  acres  are  well  tiled,  excellent  farm  ground  but 
the  other  200  acres  are  marginal  to  poor  land.  You  don't  expect  a 
loss  on  the  good  acres  but  the  poor  acres  are  questionable  so  you 
insure  only  the  marginal  200  acres. 

7.  ADEQUACY  OF  THE  BUY-UP  COVERAGE  FOR  INSURABLE  CROPS  With  the 
proposed  program  it  is  my  understanding  that  the  farmer  will  get  50% 
coverage  at  virtually  no  cost.  There  supposedly  is  going  to  be  some 
subsidy  for  additional  coverage  (if  purchased)  but  there  is  currently 
no  information  available  telling  us  what  this  amount  is  going  to  be. 
If  additional  coverage  is  cost  prohibitive  -  no  farmers  will  purchase 
it.    You  must  have  a  high   level   of  participation,   providing  a 


179 


relatively  high  gwarantee  In  order  to  provide  security.  This  Is  the 
only  way  the  program  could  work. 

8.  PROVISIONS  FOR  NONINSURED  CROPS  In  our  area  the  most  Important 
are  the  main  cash  crops  -  corn,  soybeans,  wheat.  Many  other  crops 
should  be  considered  -  alfalfa,  etc.  All  major  crops  should  be 
Included. 

9.  AMOUNT  OF  THE  PREMIUM  SUBSIDIES  AT  DIFFERENT  LEVELS  OF  COVERAGE 
The  subsidy  Is  currently  30%  at  the  50%  level  1  and  30%  at  the  level  2 
coverage.  When  you  go  to  level  3  the  percent  of  subsidy  Is 
approximately  15%.  Once  again,  you  must  encourage  a  high  level  of 
participation  at  the  highest  possible  level.  To  do  this  you  allow  the 
same  subsidy  as  level  3. 

10.  LIKELIHOOD  THAT  AD  HOC  DISASTER  PROGRAMS  WILL  NO  LONGER  BE 
AVAILABLE  I  think  that  the  largest  problem  with  participation  in  the 
existing  program  is  the  fact  that  the  government  has  repeatedly  stated 
that  the  only  assistance  available  will  be  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Program.  Farmers  do  not  believe  this.  Whenever  there  has  been  a 
major  crop  failure  the  government  has  stepped  in  with  disaster 
payments.  Why  purchase  protection?  If  Congress  would  pass  a  law  that 
the  only  assistance  available  will  be  the  subsidy  to  the  Crop 
Insurance  Program  and  there  will  be  no  disaster  payments  you  would 
have  much  higher  participation. 

11.  EXPENSE  REIMBURSEMENT  FORMULA  FOR  PRIVATE  INSURANCE  COMPANIES 
Both  state  and  federal  government  provides  subsidies  for  many  high 
risk  programs  -  Federal  Flood  Insurance,  Assigned  Risk  Workers' 
Compensation,  Assigned  Risk  Automobile  Insurance,  etc.  All  private 
Insurance  companies  must  purchase  Reinsurance  on  any  lines  of 
insurance  that  have  high  exposure.  There  is  tremendous  exposure  in  a 
crop  insurance  program  so  it  is  mandatory  for  the  federal  government 
to  provide  some  type  of  reinsurance.  I  don't,  know  what  the  level 
should  be  but  if  you  would  require  100%  participation  by  farmers  the 
cost  would  be  much  lower. 

12.  PROVISION  TO  ALLOW  PRIVATE  INSURANCE  COMPANIES  TO  LOWER  THE  RATES 
CHARGED  TO  PRODUCERS,  SUBJECT  TO  FCIC  APPROVAL  I  don't  believe  that 
private  companies  should  be  allowed  to  lower  their  rates.  If  you 
require  100%  participation  the  loss  ratio  will  greatly  improve  and  the 
subsidy  can  be  lowered.  If  you  allow  private  companies  to  set  their 
own  rates  you  will  have  some  that  will  set  rates  too  low  In  order  to 
sell  policies.  Over  a  period  of  time  they  will  suffer  great  financial 
di f f Icul i t ies  -  possibly  going  out  of  business  and  creating  additional 
problems  for  insureds  and  the  government.  Insurance  companies.  Just 
as  any  other  business,  must  have  adequate  pricing  to  stay  in  business. 
Adequate,  reasonable  pricing  and  good  service  will  guarantee  that  a 
company  will  be  in  business  in  the  future. 

13.  NON-STANDARD  CLASSIFICATION  SYSTEM  The  non-standard 
classification  is  not  fair  to  a  farmer.  He  has  no  control  over 
adverse  weather  conditions  that  may  occur.  However,  there  should  be 
more  scrutiny  and  retribution  for  poor  farming  practices. 


180 


14.  GROUP  RISK  PLAN    This  coverage  should  not  be  available. 

15.  MARKET  VALUE  PROTECTION  PLAN     I  have  no  information  on  this 
plan. 


I  ask  that  you  consider  these  additional  points: 

a)  The  current  system  is  the  best  system  to  continue  to 
provide  crop  Insurance  to  our  farmers.  There  is  room  for 
improvement  so  that  it  provides  better  protection.  I  feel 
that  effort  should  be  put  into  Improving  the  current  program 
-  not  designing  a  new  program  that  appears  to  be  totally 
unworkable . 

b)  The  proposed  new  program  will  be  extremely  costly  to  the 
government  and  taxpayers. 

c>  The  proposed  program  will  give  the  farmer  much  less 
secur i  ty . 

Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  express  my  concerns  and  ideas 
regarding  the  crop  insurance  program.  I  would  be  happy  to  discuss  any 
questions  you  have  regarding  my  statements. 


Si  ncerel y , 

/J 


Mike  Crowley 


STATEMENT 

National  Association 

OF 

Professional 
Insurance  Agents 

"THE  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  ACT  OF  1994" 

Presented  by: 

Donald  R.  Marin,  CIC 

Marin-Biel  Insurance,  inc. 

Sdby,  Soudi  Dakota 

Field  Hearing  at  the  VFW  Hall,  Luverne,  Minnesota 

April  S,  1994 


MnOHU 

400  North  Washington  St 

Alexandria,  VA  22314-9980 

703/836-9340  •  Fax  703/836-1279 

Representing  more  than  180,000  independent  insurance  agents,  brokers  and  their  employees 


182 


I  am  Don  Marin.   I  am  an  independent  agent  and  owner  of  a  smaD  insurance  agency  in 
Sdby,  South  Dakota.   I  iiave  iieen  in  the  crop  insurance  business  for  over  13  years. 
All  my  crop  insurance  business  is  witii  reinsured  companies.  I  am  here  representing 
the  National  Association  of  Professional  Insurance  Agents  (PIA  National). 

PIA  National  is  a  nonprofit  trade  association  representing  more  flian  180,000  independent 
insurance  agents  and  brokers  and  their  employees  who  sell  and  service  all  lines  of 
insurance,  specializing  in  coverage  for  homes,  auto  and  business.  PIA  National  has 
members  in  each  state  participating  in  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  program  by  selling 
FCIC-reinsured  multiple  peril  crop  insurance.   Hiey  also  sell  hafl  insurance  and  can 
provide  farmers  and  ranchers  with  a  broad  range  of  insurance  coverages  taflored  to  meet 
their  dients'  needs. 

PIA  National  commends  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 
of  the  House  Committee  on  Agriculture  for  holding  this  field  hearing.  We  welcome  this 
opportunity  to  present  our  positions  and  observations  on  various  aspects  of  the  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Program. 

On  the  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage  for  insurance  crops 

The  USDA's  proposal  would  provide  a  basic  level  of  coverage  against  catastrophic 
loss  at  no  cost  to  fanners  except  for  a  processing  fee  of  $50  per  policy  or  $100  per 
farmer.  Hie  processing  fee  could  be  waived  if  the  farmer  has  limited  resources. 

Y/e  believe  that  the  catastrophic  coverage  is  better  tiian  no  coverage.   However, 


183 


-  2  - 
we  believe  the  coverage  is  inadequate  to  cover  farmers'  expenses  in  some  cases.  Crops  are 
subject  to  many  hazards  over  which  farmers  have  no  control.  Even  in  the  best  producing 
years,  thousands  of  crop  acres  are  totally  or  partially  destroyed  by  bad  weather,  insects  and 
disease. 

On  the  $50  processing  fee  per  producer  per  crop  per  county,  not  to  exceed  $100 

I  personally  fed  the  processing  fee  should  be  higher  to  compensate  for  the 
paperwork  or  at  least  elimination  of  the  maximum  of  $100  if  they  have  more  than  two 
crops  per  county.  I  suggest  a  minimum  of  $50  per  crop  or  possibly  $100  for  first  crop  and 
$50  for  each  additional  crop. 

On  the  requirement  that  producers  obtain  catastrophic  coverage  to  be  eligible  for  price 
support,  production  adjustment  and  conservation  programs 

Considering  the  current  program  participation  affected  by  producers  reliance  on  ad 
hoc  disaster  assistance,  we  bdieve  the  catastrophic  coverage  has  to  be  part  of  the  reform 
package  for  the  program  to  succeed. 

On  the  dual  delivery  system 

As  you  would  expect,  this  issue  is  dear  to  our  hearts  as  independent  insurance  agents. 
As  I  suggested  to  Secretary  Espy  when  we  met  with  him  in  Washington,  it  would 
be  better  for  the  farmer  if  they  first  went  to  an  independent  insurance  agent  so  that  the 
entire  program  including  costs  could  be  explained.  Then,  the  farmer  would  be  given  a 
voucher  or  certificate  by  the  agent,  noting  his  purchase  of  the  catastrophic  coverage 


184 


-  3  - 

and/or  higher  levels  of  coverage. 

The  largest  strength  of  the  current  crop  insurance  prc^ram  structure  is  that  it  relies 
on  the  private  sector  almost  exclusively  for  the  delivery  of  die  at>p  insurance  product  A 
network  of  over  68,000  individuals  in  the  private  sector  currendy  earn  part  or  all  of  their 
income  through  the  sale  and  service  of  Federally-rdnsured  crop  insurance.  This  labor  force 
not  only  provides  the  farmer-customer  with  convenient,  dose-to-home  access  to  crop 
insurance,  it  also  provides  a  tremendous  boost  to  rural  development 

In  terms  of  convenience  to  the  farmer,  as  USDA  proceeds  to  consolidate  and  relocate 
offices,  the  local  crop  insurance  agent  will  probably  be  mudi  doser  and  more  convenient 
to  the  fanner  than  the  new  Farm  Service  Agency  (FSA)  office.  In  addition,  agents  make 
house  calls;  farmers  need  not  stand  in  line  at  an  FSA  office. 

PIA  believes  that  FSA  will  never  be  able  to  provide  die  kind  of  personal  service  that 
is  the  hallmark  of  insurance  agents.  Professional,  consumer-oriented  agents  wiD  survive 
and  succeed  in  their  competition  with  banks,  and  this  time,  with  die  Feds,  by  doing  what 
they  have  always  done  —  serving  the  needs  of  thdr  clients. 

On  the  use  of  actual  production  history  (APH)  for  the  4  previous  crop  years,  building  to 
10  years  and  the  use  of  transitional  yidds  (T-yields) 

My  comment  here  is  that  anyone  who  has  not  been  in  the  Crop  Insurance  Program 
before  and  cannot  prove  his  yields  would  only  get  65%  of  their  T-yield  and  diat  does  not 


185 


-  4  - 

make  it  a  very  good  program  for  them  in  the  first  3  years,  until  they  can  get  a  proven 
yield  built  up.  This  would  not  be  an  incentive  to  enter  the  program,  when  our  objective  is 
to  get  more  participation. 

On  the  requirement  for  producers  to  insure  all  land  in  the  county  for  a  particular  crop 

We  believe  this  is  a  necessary  requirement  since  our  goal  is  increased  program 
participation  and  better  protection  of  farmers  by  encouraging  them  to  buy  crop  insurance, 
which  is  true  risk  management 

On  the  adequacy  of  the  bpy-DP  coverage  for  insurable  crops 

Once  we  get  more  partidpation,  with  up  to  85%  of  their  proven  yield  available  in 
the  new  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994,  will  give  the  farmers  adequate  coverage  for 
his  fanning  operations. 

PIA  also  believes  that  this  provision  of  the  reform  package  should  be  taken  by  the 
insurance  industry,  reinsurance  companies  espedaOy,  as  a  challenge  to  develop 
supplemental  coverages  that  agents  could  sell  to  their  farmer-dients. 

On  the  provisions  for  noninsnred  crops 

We  believe  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  diould  consider  expanding  the 
list  of  program  crops  beyond  the  m^jor  crops  produced  in  the  country  including  "specialty 
crops." 


186 


On  the  amount  of  premium  subsidy  at  levels  of  coverage 

For  farmers  to  be  adequately  protected,  crop  insurance  must  be  sold,  even  if  a 
portion  is  given  away  for  little  or  no  diarge.   We  would  have  preferred  to  see  the 
catastrophic  level  lower,  such  as  25%  or  35%,  and  more  subsidy  put  into  the  higher  levds 
of  coverage  to  encourage  more  participation.   Buying  into  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Program  is  a  business  decision.   With  adequate  coverage  and  acceptable  pricing,  you're 
going  to  be  able  to  sell  the  program  because  today's  farmers  recognize  more  than  ever  that 
they  put  more  risk  in  one  year  than  farmers  ever  had  in  the  past  so  it  is  less  likely  that 
the  farmers  will  say  we'll  wait  untfl  next  year.  Farmers  have  to  make  every  year  count. 
Unless  you  provide  federal  crop  insurance,  you're  not  going  to  allow  every  farmer  to  gain 
that  protection. 

On  the  likelihood  that  ad  hoc  disaster  program  will  no  longer  be  available 

Congress  should  consider  the  recent  numerous  catastrophic  events  in  the  country 
as  a  "wake-up  call"  for  ending  ad  hoc  disaster  payments.  Whfle  political  realities  are 
that  Members  of  Congress  are  often  times  elected  by  their  constituents  throu^  their 
assistance  in  disaster  programs,  our  dwindling  Federal  dollars  and  the  difficulty  of 
"finding"  disaster  funds,  magnifies  the  importance  of  crop  insurance. 

For  us  agents  who  are  on  the  firont-line  in  the  sale  of  crop  insurance,  the  availability 
of  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  is  the  Number  One  disincentive  for  farmers  to  buy  crop 
insurance.  This  is  also  our  experience  in  selling  Federal  flood  insurance. 


187 


PIA  NatiMial  fully  support  efTorts  to  reduce  or  better  still,  efiminate  ad  hoc  disaster 
assistance.  Ad  hoc  disaster  bills  can  be  bad  both  for  farmers  and  taxpayers. 

On  die  expense  reimbursement  formula  for  private  insurance  compames 

This  is  a  sensitive  issue  for  agents  because  in  most  cases,  agents  commissions  are 
dependent  on  private  reinsured  companies  expense  reimbursemenL  1  would  like  to  address 
this  subject  by  mentioning  some  of  the  disincentives  which  discourage  agents  from  sdling 
crop  insurance.   Paperwork  is  horrendous.   Regulations  are  constantly  dialing  and 
insurance  deadlines  are  often  times  hard  to  meeL  These  factors  increase  the  agents* 
cxposorc  to  errors  and  omissions  liability.  And  most  of  aD,  farmers  are  tough  clients  to 
scO.  It's  harder  to  sdl  them  crop  insurance  because  farmers  are  confident  that  in  the  event 
of  a  disaster,  the  federal  government  would  provide  relief  regardless  of  whether  a  farmer 
had  insurance  or  not 

Another  mqjor  disincentive  is  die  unpredictaMlitv  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Program  in  terms  of  program  funding  which  ultimately  affects  insurance  agents' 
commissions.  PIA  National  believes  dnt  the  "dwindling"  expense  reimbursements  could 
affect  the  insurance  industry's  ability  to  assist  in  reforming  this  federal  program. 
Personally,  I  don't  think  the  reimbursement  should  be  lower  than  the  current  31%. 
The  <^>eraling  expense  ratio  for  die  property/casualty  industry  averages  between  25%  to 
35%,  so  31  %  is  in  the  middle/upper  range. 


81-128  0-94-7 


188 


-   7   - 

On  the  provision  to  allow  private  insurance  companies  to  lower  flie  rates  charged  to 
producers,  subject  to  FCIC  approval 

While  we  advocate  "cost  through  market  forces"  or  a  market  base  mechanism  rather 
than  government  edict,  we  have  some  reservations  on  allowing  insurance  companies  to 
lower  the  rates.  Hie  principle  may  look  good,  but  in  the  long  run,  it  could  limit 
competition  in  the  marketplace  to  the  disadvantage  of  smaDer  companies.  Selective 
marketing  and  "dierry-picking"  could  easfly  result  in  company  insolvency  and  this  wiD 
be  very  detrimental  to  the  program. 

On  the  non-standard  dassiBcation  system 

PIA  supports  efforts  to  eliminate  "abuses"  to  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Program. 
However,  this  needs  to  be  looked  at  dosely  because  there  are  cases  where  some  states 
have  had  8  out  of  10  years  drought,  and  we  don't  beUeve  people  should  have  their  yidds 
cut  and  their  premiums  raised,  because  of  an  Act  of  God.  Many  of  the  hazards  faced  by 
farmers  —  floods,  droughts  and  other  natural  disasters  —  not  only  are  largdy  beyond  their 
control,  but  most  are  not  subject  to  coverage  by  private  sector  insurance  because  of  their 
catastrophic  nature. 

On  the  Group  Risk  Plan 

The  Group  Risk  Plan  (GRP)  is  a  new  risk  management  tool  devdoped  by  the  FCIC. 


189 


-  8  - 

It  is  another  choice  for  fanners.  If  unhappy  with  the  Multiple  Peril  Crop  Insurance,  GRP 
could  work  for  them.  GRP  is  not  for  everybody  but  for  us  agents,  it  is  another 
insurance  product  we  can  sdH;  a  "door  opener"  for  die  sale  of  other  property/casualty 
products.   More  choices  for  the  fanners,  the  better. 

On  die  market  value  protection  plan 

We  support  this  plan  because  it  wiD  benefit  die  farmers  individually  and  the  over-all 
program  wiD  be  improved  because  adequate  rates  wiD  be  charged. 

In  oondusion,  PIA  National's:  ^^ 

*  M^or  concern  at  this  time  is  to  get  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Program 

adequately  funded  so  that  reform  of  this  program  can  occur. 

*  Believes  that  this  program  is  a  program  designed  first  and  foremost  to 

protect  die  American  fanner.   Farmers  participating  in  the  program 
enhance  the  stability  of  the  economy  in  a  given  agricultural  area. 

*  Believes  that  mqjor  improvements  to  this  federal  insurance  program  have 

been  passible  because  of  the  government  and  private  industry  partnership. 
It  is  PIA  National's  belief  that  a  key  to  the  success  ot  the  Federal  Crop 
Insunince  Program  is  the  maximum  possible  use  by  the  FCIC  of  die  private 
insurance  sector. 

*  We  oontinne  to  stand  ready  to  work  with  Congress,  the  VS.  Department  of 

Agriculture  and  other  agencies  to  protect  the  American  farmer  by  providing 


190 


the  necessary  insuranoe  coverage  to  protect  the  stability  of  our  local 
and  national  economy. 


Mr.  Chairman,  we  need  your  help  and  support  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Program.   While  not  perfect,  crop  insurance  works. 


LMA/3i/30/94 


HEARING  OF  THE  HOUSE  COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

April  5,  1994,  Luverne  MN 


Steve  Lindholm,  President 

Farmers  &  Merchants  State  Bank  of  Clarkfield 

F&M  Insurance  Agency 

940  10th  Avenue 

PO  Box  248 

Clarkfield,  MN   56223 

I  support  the  Administrations  Crop  Insurance  Proposal  -  The  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994. 

In  my  view,  the  effort  to  reform  the  crop  insurance  program  by 
providing  catastrophic  coverage  on  an  individual  farm  basis  and 
eliminate  or  at  least  substantially  reduce  ad  hoc  disaster  programs 
is  a  good  move  for  America's  farmers  and  a  good  move  for  the 
American  public.  It  will  provide  farmers  and  lenders  with 
protection  they  can  rely  on  and  it  will  be  cost  effective  for  tax 
payers . 

It  is  imperative  that  the  House/ Senate  Budget  Conference  Committee 
adopt  the  Administrations  recommendation  to  transfer  one  billion 
dollars  to  "on-budget"  for  crop  insurance  reform  when  they  meet  the 
week  of  April  10.  Inadequate  funding  of  crop  insurance  reform 
would  be  a  case  of  killing  the  goose  that  lays  the  golden  egg. 

There  is  a  direct  relationship  between  a  sound  crop  insurance 
program  and  the  availability  of  a  plentiful,  low  cost  supply  of 
food  for  the  American  public.  The  ability  to  insure  crops  is 
fundamental  to  farmers  ability  to  obtain  substantial  credit 
necessary  to  grow  and  harvest  crops  that  are  so  vulnerable  to 
natural  disaster.  With  a  sound  crop  insurance  program,  the  U.S. 
faunner  will  continue  to  produce  crops  more  efficiently  and  in  more 
abundance  than  anywhere  else  in  the  world. 

Please  carefully  consider  all  suggestions  that  could  improve  the 
proposal.  The  following  comments  will  specifically  address  issues 
upon  which  I  was  asked  to  comment. 

1.  The  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage.  It's  my  understanding 
that  this  coverage  of  50  percent  of  the  proven  yield  times  60 
percent  of  the  established  price  approximates  the  average  net 
disaster  payments.  It  has  some  validity  from  that  standpoint. 
However  from  a  risk  management  stand  point  it  will  be  inadequate 
for  most  farmers.  Therefore,  every  effort  should  be  made  to 
provide  both  counseling  and  incentives  for  growers  to  buy-up  this 
coverage  to  more  meaningful  amounts  of  protection. 


192 


2.  The  catastrophic  coverage  processing  fee  of  $50  per  crop  not 
to  exceed  SlOO  per  grower  per  county.  This  fee  apparently  is 
intended  to  represent  a  producer  paid  administration  fee  rather 
than  a  premium  charge.  This  will  be  affordable  for  most  producers. 
The  adequacy  of  this  fee  to  cover  administrative  costs  will  depend 
largely  on  the  extent  "that  USDA/FCIC  permits  the  private  sector  to 
streamline  and  simplify  the  program,  its  administrative  processes, 
and  its  presentation  to  growers.  The  simplicity  of  the  private 
crop  hail  programs  can  be  used  as  a  model  for  the  reformed  crop 
insurance  program. 

3 .  The  requirement  that  producers  be  required  to  obtain  at  least 
catastrophic  coverage  to  be  eligible  to  participate  in  price 
support  and  loan  programs.  Personally  I  feel  that  the  small  $50- 
$100  cost  of  the  basis  coverage  is  so  reasonable  that  ad  hoc 
disaster  payments  should  not  be  necessary  for  those  who  would  not 
take  catastrophic  coverage  on  a  voluntary  basis.  If,  however,  the 
requirement  is  politically  necessary  to  be  sure  there  will  be  very 
few  if  any  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  for  crops  in  the  future,  I  can 
accept  it  as  a  requirement . 

4.  The  dual  delivery  system  with  catastrophic  protection 
available  from  both  private  insurance  agents  or  the  USDA  service 
centers  and  additional  coverage  being  available  only  through 
private  agents.  I  fully  endorse  maximum  use  of  the  private 
insurance  agents  and  companies  for  several  reasons. 

First,  private  agents  are  experienced  risk  management  counselors 
who  will  evaluate  crop  insurance  protection  and  make 
recommendations  that  best  address  the  needs  of  individual 
producers.  Since  I  believe  the  basic  coverage  is  inadequate  for 
most  producers,  it  is  critical  they  be  required,  as  a  minimum,  to 
go  to  a  private  agent  for  a  full  review  of  the  coverage  choices 
available  to  them  before  they  buy  the  minimum  coverage  from  the 
government  office. 

Secondly,  the  government  service  offices  are  already  challenged  to 
administer  farmer  programs  without  the  additional  burden  of  issuing 
crop  insurance  policies.  Local  USDA  offices  are  being  asked  to  get 
along  with  fewer  personnel  and  yet  the  work  load  and  documentation 
required  to  deliver  government  services  is  increasing.  They  would 
be  asked  to  issue  catastrophic  crop  insurance  policies  at  the  scime 
time  they  are  under  the  gun  to  complete  spring  sign  up  for  farmer 
programs.  If  they  are  burdened  with  issuing  crop  insxirance 
policies,  they  might  have  trouble  getting  the  job  done  or  errors 
may  increase  substantially. 

Last,  to  duplicate  the  current  private  sector  services  in  a 
government  office  is  unnecessary  and  will  cost  taxpayers  a  high 
price. 

I  strongly  recommend  that  the  use  of  government  offices  to  sell 
crop  insurance  be  limited  to  only  those  geographical  areas  where 
private  insurance  agents  are  not  available. 


193 


5.  The  use  of  actual  production  history  fAPH)  to  establish 
coverage .  This  approach  provides  more  equitable  coverage  than 
using  farm  program  yields  when  actual  yield  records  are  available. 
Every  effort  and  incentive  should  be  provided  to  make  actual 
records  available.  'Also,  the  rules  should  favor  the  use  of 
previous  yield  records  the  producer  has  had  a  part  in  making  on 
another  farm  or  in  another  county. 

When  less  than  4  years  of  records  are  available  I  recommend  that 
transitional  yield  (T-yield)  be  eliminated  and  the  full  ASCS  yield 
be  used  in  calculating  the  bushel  guarantee.  The  current  APH  rules 
reduce  yields  in  our  area  to  approximately  85%  of  ASCS  yields 
before  bushel  guarantees  are  calculated.  ASCS  yields  are  already 
10-20%  below  normal  production,  for  our  area.  As  a  result,  a 
farmer  who  must  use  T-yields  will  only  receive  approximately  40% 
coverage  at  Level  II  (which  is  designed  to  provide  65%  protection) 
until  records  are  available.  The  current  T-yield  formula  does 
prevent  some  beginning  farmers  and  farmers  who  are  teOcing  on  new 
land  from  being  able  to  obtain  adequate  protection. 

Livestock  producers  especially  cattle  feeders,  are  at  a 
disadvantage  in  producing  records  because  they  often  don't  have  an 
effective  way  to  measure  yields  on  crops  that  are  fed.  They  should 
also  be  able  to  use  more  realistic  yields  than  T-yields  to 
establish  bushel  guarantees  when  they  are  unable  to  provide 
adequate  records. 

6.  Requiring  that  the  producer  insure  all  land  of  a  crop  in  the 
county .  This  approach  is  part  of  the  current  program  and  is  a 
sound  basis  for  insurance. 

7.  Adequacy  of  buy-up  coverage  for  insurable  crops.  This  may  be 
adequate  for  many  growers.  However,  two  deficient  situations 
should  be  recognized.  First,  certain  producers,  especially 
beginning  farmers  who  are  highly  leveraged  may  need  more  than  75 
percent  coverage.  I  recognize  that  the  reform  proposal  allows  up 
to  85  percent  coverage  and  I  hope  that  FCIC  will  give  producers  an 
opportunity  to  buy  it  at  premiums  that  are  affordable. 

Second,  we  need  to  recognize  that  farmers  have  more  coverage  today 
vmder  disaster  payments  and  crop  insurance  than  they  would  have 
under  the  reformed  program.  This  should  be  addressed  by  giving 
producers  the  opportunity  to  buy  a  supplemental  product  that  would 
increase  the  rate  of  payment  perhaps  after  the  producer  suffers  a 
loss  of  50  percent  or  more.  A  provision  of  this  nature  was  part  of 
the  1988  disaster  program  and  is  included  in  most  private  crop  hail 
policies.  This  could  be  a  very  cost-effective  way  to  address  this 
issue  and  could  probably  be  done  by  the  private  sector  with  the 
backing  of  federal  reinsurance  at  reasonable  rates. 

We  need  to  do  everything  we  can  to  increase  insurance  protection 
available. 


194 


8 .  Adequacy  of  protection  for  non-insured  crops.  Livestock 
producers  in  our  area  have  difficulty  obtaining  coverage  for  some 
forage  crops.  Any  additional  crops  that  can  be  included  in  the 
program  would  be  an  improvement  from  the  ad  hoc  system. 

9 .  The  amount  of  premium  subsidy  at  the  different  levels.  The 
more  subsidy  the  lower  the  farmer's  cost  and  the  more  they  will 
buy.  For  example,  more  producers  would  buy  75  percent  coverage  if 
it  had  a  higher  subsidy  and  less  cost.  Every  effort  should  be  made 
to  provide  incentives  for  producers  to  increase  coverage  to  more 
adequate  levels  of  protection. 

10.  The  likelihood  that  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  will  no  longer  be 
available.  If  we  can  assume  that  USDA's  estimates  are  accurate 
that  80  percent  of  the  producers  will  be  protected  (about  the  same 
as  under  current  disaster  programs)  and  that  higher  legislative 
hurdles  will  make  it  more  difficult  to  pass  future  ad  hoc  disaster 
programs,  there  should  be  fewer  such  programs  in  the  future.  This 
will  be  the  result  of  both  reduced  need  and  increased  difficulty  to 
pass  them. 

11.  The  adequacy  of  the  expense  formula  for  private  companies.  I 
am  not  the  expert  here  but  I  will  share  a  few  thoughts.  Over  the 
last  few  years  the  number  of  private  companies  in  the  business  has 
declined  by  over  50  percent  which  could  indicate  that  margins  are 
pretty  thin.  I  also  know  that  each  year  FCIC  adds  more 
requirements  for  companies  while  reducing  the  expense  rates.  This 
cannot  go  on  indefinitely.  I  recommend  that  FCIC  with  the  private 
sector  conduct  a  thorough  review  of  program  design  and 
administration  with  a  primary  emphasis  on  simplification  and 
reduction  of  administrative  cost  at  all  levels.  The  private  crop 
hail  program  is  a  model  to  look  at  for  simplification  and 
efficiency. 

If  the  program  was  simplified  the  expense  formulas  may  be  adequate. 

12.  Authority  for  rate  competition  between  private  companies  with 
FCIC  approval.  Competition  is  the  foundation  of  our  free 
enterprise  system.  It  should  be  permitted  here  too.  FCIC  must 
make  sure  that  companies  maintain  adequate  financial  reserves  to 
avoid  insolvencies. 

13.  Non-standard  classification  system.  This  underwriting  system 
is  strong  medicine  when  a  grower,  through  no  fault  of  their  own, 
has  a  series  of  disasters.  Compassion  should  be  a  part  of  the 
system.  I  do  not  think  non-standard  classification  should  apply  to 
the  catastrophic  coverage.  In  other  words,  producers  with  a  high 
frequency  of  losses  might  fall  to  the  safety  net  of  catastrophic 
coverage,  but  they  should  never  fall  through  the  safety  net. 

14.  The  group  risk  plan.  This  plan  is  OK  as  an  option,  but  it 
should  never  be  the  only  form  of  coverage  available.  It  is  not  an 
effective  risk  management  tool  to  use  in  the  granting  of  loans 


195 


because  a  widespread  catastrophe  must  occur  before  the  producer 
qualifies  for  a  loss  payment.  If  no  widespread  disaster  occurs, 
the  individual  fanner  who  experiences  a  crop  failure  would  not  be 
protected. 

15.  Market  value  protrection.  This  is  a  good  concept  that  ties  the 
price  election  to  the  market  place.  This  also  provides  more 
protection  for  growers  who  forward  sell  or  hedge  their  crops  during 
the  growing  season.  I  encourage  FCIC  to  maJce  much  broader  use  of 
their  authority  to  back  private  sector  initiatives  like  this. 

I  would  also  like  to  see  an  increasing  payment  provision 
implemented  by  the  private  companies  with  PCIC's  reinsurance  to 
provide  similar  indemnity  that  is  available  under  the  current 
program  where  MPCI  and  disaster  programs  combined  provide 
protection  up  to  the  ASCS  yield  times  the  price. 


Occasionally  I  read  or  hear  comments  from  Washington  and  at  home 
about  the  crop  insurance  program  not  working  very  well  or  that  it 
costs  too  much.  I  do  not  share  that  view.  I  believe  the  current 
program  works  relatively  well  but  can  be  improved  in  terms  of 
increasing  available  coverage  and  reducing  administrative  costs. 

It  would  be  very  wrong  to  think  of  crop  insiurance  subsidies  as  a 
"give  away"  program.  I  believe  the  amount  by  which  crop  insurance 
progriun  costs  exceed  premiums  paid  represents  a  very  small 
investment  of  tax  dollars  for  a  very  substantial  return. 

Please  keep  up  the  important  work  of  improving  crop  insiurance. 
Thank  you  Congressman  Hinge  and  the  rest  of  the  committee  members 
for  holding  this  hearing  and  inviting  our  comments. 


i^ 


196 


m  CO  • 
*«■•«• 
o  •      • 

HJJ.J 

.       ■«     ■ 


vwr>r-9«^0**  «« 


■e  • 

M 

K  ■ 

O 

H  M 

■C  •« 

5  u 


£«  • 

•     I     ■ 


^  e  o»         ^t  • 


K^t  t««t^ra« 


Si 


■ 

ii 


El 

U  • 


•  ■ 

m  • 


«■        X        « 

i  .s  si  Es 

So        M  U  M«>MO        « 

m     fc  MZMxauoM     • 

«       O       MMK  p^  up,     • 

&«x8^<'<ua|aM^abHMdMd^id  m 
i^323«S2KE*<zilooo3Xp5xt4 
3auo3ooc9aOO^*>£(atA(afr>K5  o 


• XXXSXXZXXXXXXXXSZSXX4 


§Si  = 


fe** 


m     m     KMx2o  oo     mkS 

X        ib«»OilU  «MU«MMO 


SiSSSSSSSSSSiSSSSISS. 


^S'l 


«  so  i 

M  I 

I       •  ao  • 


p«oo      O  -«I««»W 


mon«      M  mr»#»« 


•  «ne*««      M 


5  b 


St 

M  n 

a:: 


IB  : 

Ski* 


33333. 


X  u  O  • 

i^S2  t «  ■ 
2uuC H  o 


3       KU 


3 


?2*l«k   MMXUOH   • 
M  p2   Up   • 
■  Mm    XXX    zI*Mt*uAH 
•l^KX«MM«U«<iM<«^^ 

akSE2H<M««^H»M«2t]« 

523okZk<<mooxpPz*' 
•  OuateOOOa>>fc«Nt-»*X  O 


2     s 


a 


iiiii.     .eaasasaiissassi. 


3  . 

•  »■  P         • 

HM       X       H  H 

52oK  <ox  M 
•  uoo*»5  o 
«« 

M  3 

X  « 

M  aa  M  M  M  •■  M 
• XZXXXXX* 


Statement  of  Gene  Smestad 

Director  of  Crop  Insurance 

Farm  Credit  Services  of  Fargo,  ACA 


CROP  INSURANCE  HEARING 


April  5,  1994 
Luveme,  Minnesota 


It  is  my  pleasure  to  have  the  opportunity  to  participate  as  a  witness  today.  My 
testimony  will  be  qualified  to  the  extent  that  I  became  a  licensed  insurance  agent 
27  years  ago,  have  been  participating  in  farming  and  purchasing  crop  insurance 
products  for  21  years,  and  as  an  employee  of  Farm  Credit  Services  of  Fargo,  ACA 
my  responsibilities  include  directing  the  crop  insurance  program  in  a  9  county  area 
in  southeastern  North  Dakota. 

When  congress  passed  the  1980  Federal  Crop  Insurance  legislation,  they  did  it  for 
all  of  the  right  reasons  - 

1.  Provide  risk  protection  to  farmers  at  optional  levels. 

2.  Include    private    industry    in    the    delivery    system    so    as    to    increase 
participation. 

Additionally,  the  reformed  FCIC  program  was  intended  to  eliminate  the  need  for 
disaster  legislation  AND  eliminate  subsidization  to  the  program  over  time.  This 
was  indeed  a  visionary  expectation  which  could  only  be  achieved  if  the  MPCI 
product  had  "value"  in  the  eyes  of  the  producer /purchaser.  To  date,  it  has  not  had 
enough  "value"  to  increase  participation  to  expected  levels. 


198 


Crop  Insurance  Hearing 
Gene  Smestad  Stmt. 
April  5,  1994 
Page  2 


Why  hasn't  this  happened?   Let  me  offer  a  couple  of  thoughts  - 

Thought  #1  -  FCIC  remained  in  charge.  They  established  program  direction, 
administration  and  reviews.  The  important  question  here  is 
"what  incentive  did  they  have  to  aggressively  step  up  to  the 
plate  and  make  the  changes  necessary  to  meet  the  expectations 
of  the  1980  legislation? 

Thought  #2  -  Insurance  companies  contracted  with  FCIC  and  ran  a  cost  plus, 
risk  free  business  until  1989  when  the  element  of  real  risk 
sharing  was  included  in  their  contracts.  Prior  to  1989,  there 
was  little  incentive  to  lead  the  charge  in  product  enhancement. 


FCIC  has  recently  been  reducing  the  Expense  Reimbursement 
contracts  with  it's  reinsureds,  causing  companies  to  pull  back 
from  developing  added  products  as  they  search  for  means  to 
remain  profitable  and  gain  reinsurance  for  the  added  products. 

The  Interim  Report  of  the  Commission  for  the  Improvement  of  the  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  Program,  dated  April  3,  1989,  contains  a  summary  of  recommendations 
that  would  have  greatly  enhanced  the  present  product.  Those  recommendations 
were  the  result  of  hearings  throughout  the  United  States.  It  is  my  belief  that  the 
hearings  identified  the  issues,  but  because  of  the  administrative  structure  of  FCIC 
and  the  initial  contracts  with  the  private  companies,  changes  were  too  slow  in 
coming.  As  a  result,  we  have  had  considerably  more  disaster  legislation  and  red 
ink  -  -  all  at  a  time  when  Washington  is  trying  to  balance  their  checkbook. 

So  here  we  are  today,  some  13  years  since  the  1980  legislation.  With  knife  in 
hand,  we  are  about  to  perform  some  major  "reform  surgery".  The  basic  proposal 
begins  with  a  "something  for  nothing"  coverage  with  the  option  to  purchase 
additional  coverage.  The  expectations  of  this  reform  are  identical  to  that  of  the 
1980  legislation  -  which  we  recall  were,  1)  greater  participation,  2)  eliminate 
disaster  legislation,  and  3)  actuarially  sound. 


199 


Crop  Insurance  Hearing 
Gene  Smestad  Stmt. 
April  5,  1994 
Page  3 


Although  this  proposal  would  not  have  been  my  first  choice,  it  may  well  be  the 
only  way  toward  product  enhancement.  Private  companies,  driven  by  business 
fundamentals  of  profits  and  market  share,  will  now  develop  products  that  the 
customer  perceives  to  have  "value". 

So  what  are  some  of  the  issues  open  for  debate: 

Issue  #1  -  Dual  delivery  system: 

History  clearly  demonstrates  the  inability  to  lace  marketing  and 
servicing  incentives  into  a  governmental  delivery  system.  Only 
private  agents  will  have  the  incentive  to  provide  the  product 
counseling  necessary  to  assure  good  risk  management 
participation.  Additionally,  when  the  agents  personal  success 
is  based  upon  farmer  participation,  there  will  exist  an  automatic 
incentive  to  improve  product  value  so  that  the  sales  materialize. 
Greater  participation  is  an  expectation  of  this  reform  — 
increasing  product  value  is  the  only  path  towards  increased 
participation. 

Efforts  should  be  made  to  increase  industry's  role  and 
responsibility  in  the  delivery  and  marketing  system  rather  than 
pay  the  government  to  come  back  in  as  a  player. 

Issue  #2  -  Group  Risk  Plan: 

This  is  clearly  another  attempt  to  provide  something  less  in 
value  to  save  budget.  All  of  us  buy  insurance  and  we  buy 
individual  coverage  to  match  our  risk  management  needs.  The 
present  APH  approach  provides  for  individual  coverage  which 
can  be  measured  in  specific  dollars  of  protection.  GRP  cannot 
be  measured  until  the  year  is  over.  It  could  be  a  bonus  or  a 
ticket  out  of  farming.  It  is  a  dangerous  option  to  promote  if  we 
are  truly  concerned  about  providing  risk  management  insurance 
to  fanners. 


200 


Crop  Insurance  Hearing 
Gene  Smestad  Stmt. 
April  5,  1994 
Page  4 


The  implications  of  not  having  individual  coverage  will  shrink 
some  operators  credit  limits  with  their  respective  lender. 
Buying  a  product  which  provides  no  measurable  protection 
value  is  like  shooting  craps  --  it  simply  does  not  reconcile  with 
sound  business  judgement. 

Under  a  dual  delivery  system,  I  wonder  what  incentive  an 
ASCS  office  employee  would  have  to  truly  evaluate  this  option 
with  a  farmer. 


Issue  #3  -  APH  calculation. 


This  is  a  good  approach  to  individual  protection  and  the  1994 
enhancement  was  good  to  see.  However,  further  enhancements 
would  increase  product  value.  Enhancement  #1  would  be  to 
limit  catastrophic  loss  years  to  the  T-yield.  Enhancement  #2 
would  be  to  keep  that  catastrophic  loss  from  the  rate  base  data. 
The  purpose  of  these  two  enhancements  would  be  to  prevent 
product  value  deterioration  and  prevent  increased  product  price 
relative  to  value. 

Without  these  enhancements,  it  is  doubtful  that  product  value 
will  increase  to  the  desired  levels.  A  farmer  can  buy  $100  of 
hail  coverage  per  acre,  incur  a  total  loss  and  the  next  year  he 
can  again  buy  $100/acre  of  protection.  However,  with  MPCI, 
the  total  loss  will  diminish  the  amount  of  coverage  he  can 
purchase  the  following  year.  This  identifies  a  product 
deficiency  as  his  expenses  and  risk  protection  needs  will  not 
diminish. 


Issue  #4  -  Cheaper  theory: 


Proponents  of  this  reform  are  saying  that  the  additional 
insurance  the  farmer  buys  above  the  "something  for  nothing" 
line  could  be  less  expensive  as  a  result  of  more  participation. 
This  is  doubtful.  We  must  increase  product  value  to  get 
participation  and  product  value  will  have  added  price  if  it  is  to 
be  actuarially  sound. 


201 


Crop  Insurance  Hearing 
Gene  Smestad  Stmt. 
April  5,  1994 
Page  5 


Let's  get  away  from  believing  we  can  sell  a  poor  product  just 
because  it  is  cheap.  History  proves  this  is  not  possible. 
Instead,  let's  improve  the  product  and  price  it  according  to 
value.  Farmers  are  very  large  buyers  of  value  products  ~  they 
will  make  good  business  decisions  if  the  product  options  are 
available. 


Issue  #5  -  Adverse  selection  is  thought  to  be  a  function  of  "Knowing 

disaster  legislation  will  be  available". 

As  a  farm  owner  who  buys  MPCI,  and  as  a  lender  who  sets  up 
farm  operating  lines  of  credit,  I  see  adverse  selection  as  a  direct 
function  of  perceived  product  value.  That  is  why  participation 
varies  by  crop  and  geographic  area. 

If  product  value  is  increased,  the  size  of  the  risk  pool  will 
increase,  and  adverse  selection  will  decrease. 


Issue  #6  -  Role  of  FCIC 

Simply  stated,  they  must  not  be  a  roadblock  to  private 
industry's  attempt  to  develop  and  market  products  of  increased 
value.  Allowing  them  to  establish  a  presence  at  the  county 
level,  as  proposed,  would  be  a  mistake.  That  would  be 
building  another  cost  structure  that  would  defer  dollars  away 
from  enhancing  product  value. 

FCIC  must  move  faster  in  both  approving  and  reinsuring  added 
products  so  as  to  be  a  more  accommodating  player  in  program 
enhancements.  Private  industry  needs  this  type  of  cooperation 
if  reform  expectations  are  to  be  accomplished. 


202 


Crop  Insurance  Hearing 

Gene  Smestad  Stmt. 

April  5,  1994  ^ 

Page  6  \ 


Conclusion 

We  are  again  standing  at  the  gate  of  opportunity  in  regards  to  improving  risk 
management  tools  for  agriculture. 

If  this  reform  gets  caught  up  strictly  in  the  emotion  of  cutting  costs,  it  will  fail 
everyone.  The  focus  must  be  to  bring  business  principals  to  an  enhanced  risk 
management  product  which  can  measurably  protect  production  agriculture. 

If  we  promote  single  delivery  by  private  industry  -  if  we  promote  the  development 
of  products  with  true  and  measurable  value  ~  if  we  enhance  the  APH  formula  to 
limit  product  value  deterioration  ~  and  if  we  promote  an  American  free  enterprise 
spirit  to  the  above  process  ~  we  will  have  a  chance  at  achieving  reform 
expectations. 

Good  luck  in  your  continued  efforts  ~  it's  been  my  pleasure. 


Eugene  C.  Smestad, 

Farm  Credit  Services 

Box  1025 

Valley  City,  ND  58072 

1-701-845-1751 

Fax  701-845-5690 


203 


John  R.  Keister 

P.O.  Box  340 

Blue  Earth,  MN      56013 

Ph:  507-526-7394  '       '     '      ^ 

Mr  Chairman:  _. 

There  are  three  areas  that  I  feel  must  be  addressed  in  any 
revision  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  act.   Before  I  address 
these  revisions  I  would  like  to  state  my  support  for  the  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  program.   In  the  last  fifteen  years  this  prograun 
has  evolved  into  a  good  progrcun  that  basicly  delivers  what  the 
current  legislation  intended  it  to  do.   I  believe  that  most 
everyone  agrees  that  new  legislation  must  be  enacted  to  make 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  universally  acceptable. 

My  first  recommendation  is  the  new  legislation  must  clearly 


define  Federal  Crop  Insurance's  role.   Current  legislation  does 
not  allow  for  the  flexibility  that  is  currently  demanded  of 
Multiperil  Crop  insurance.   Along  with  a  clearly  defined  role, 
the  legislation  must  redefine  the  position  of  the  manager  of  the 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation.   The  managers  position  should 
be  changed  from  a  political  appointment  to  a  permanent  position. 
The  revolving  door  of  managers  of  the  last  fifteen  years  has   .  ._  , 
significantly  harmed  the  program.   We  cannot  have  a  consistant 
progrcun  without  clear  leadership.   Relationships  between  private 
companies  and  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  have  been 
strained  because  of  this  turn  over.   With  a  permanent  manager 
long  term  relationships  can  be  established  and  a  spirit  of 
cooperation  will  have  a  better  chance  of  prevailing.   The  manager 


204 


must  have  the  ability  to  implement  progreuns  and  procedures  within 
a  much  shorter  time  frame. 

The  current  system  of  publishing  a  procedure  before  it  is 
implemented  does  not  allow  for  the  program  to  react  to  changes  in 
farm  economics.   A  clear  example  of  this  was  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  Corporation's  failure  to  revise  its  coarse  grain 
quality  adjustment  procedure.   This  failure  of  action  resulted  in 
the  policy  holder  making  a  decision  based  on  information  that  he 
was  given  in  good  faith  and  later  being  penalized  by  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Corporation's  clarification  of  an  old  procedure. 
This  clarification  penalized  the  farmer  for  a  grain  buying 
practice  that  was  beyond  his  control.    A  strong  managers 
position  would  not  have  allowed  this  situation  to  happen. 

My  second  recommendation  is  to  allow  coverage  to  be  raised 
to  cover  cost  of  production.   I  do  not  believe  that  the  current 
maximum  level  of  75%  of  a  farmers  yield  should  be  raised.   I  do 
believe  that  the  dollar  amount  of  coverage  per  bushel  is  not 
adequate.   I  do  not  subscribe  to  the  theory  that  raising  the 
price  election  above  market  price  causes  a  moral  hazard.   The 
past  practice  of  allowing  a  farmer  to  collect  both  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  and  disaster  payments  has  in  effect  allowed  the  same 
thing.   There  are  many  procedures  that  can  be  easily  adopted  to 
prevent  the  small  percentage  of  farmers  from  abusing  the  program. 


205 


Until  we  allow  coverage  that  will  act  as  collateral  and 
subordinate  a  loan  we  will  always  receive  pressure  to  enact 
disaster  legislation.   The  availability  of  this  coverage  is 
primary  over  price  of  the  coverage  or  the  eunount  of  subsidy. 
The  eibility  to  raise  coverage  to  secure  debt  will  singularly  make 
this  progrcun  universally  acceptable  and  take  pressures  off  many 
other  government  agencies.   The  American  farmer  is  not  asking  for 
cheep  coverage.   They  are  first  asking  for  the  ability  to  cover 
their  cost  of  production  and  then  for  a  reasonable  premium.   The 
main  problem  of  the  current  progreim  is  the  amount  of  coverage  not 
the  cost.  '    ' 

The  third  recommendation  is  to  redirect  Federal  Crop's   ' 
actuarial  approach  to  the  program.   The  actuarial  division  must 
be  directed  to  stop  the  practice  of  subsidizing  high  loss  ratio 
areas  with  premium  dollars  from  another  part  of  the  country.   For 
congress  or  private  industry  to  evaluate  any  Federal  Crop 
Insurance  progreun  it  must  have  accurate  information.   Once  we 
know  the  true  probability  of  loss  for  a  given  crop  in  a  given 
area,  then  it  is  up  to  congress  to  decide  the  level  of  subsidy 
and  the  farmer  to  decide  if  he  wants  to  pay  the  premium.   This 
would  stop  nontraditional  crops  grown  on  marginal  land.   I  have 
been  told  that  true  rating  in  the  norther  corn  belt  would  lower 
corn  premiums  by  25%. 


206 

The  new  program  division  of  Federal  Crop  actuarial  should  be 
expanded.   History  has  taught  us  that  the  private  reinsurance 
industry  is  not  a  consistent  viable  resource.   I  believe  many 
progreuns  can  be  developed  with  government  cooperation.   It  is  not 
necessary  that  the  government  subsidize  these  programs  but  simply 
acts  as  a  reinsurance  source. 

The  demand  for  a  quality  disaster  program  administered 
through  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  has  wide  spread 
support  in  this  area.   I  urge  congress  to  either  choose  disaster 
payments  or  Federal  Crop  Insurance  to  deliver  aid  to  farmers. 
The  debate  between  the  two  forms  of  aid  has  gone  much  to  long. 
The  American  farmer  needs  steUoility  and  congress  needs  cost 
control.   I  belive  Federal  Crop  Insurance  will  favorably  address 
both  concerns. 


207 


Farmers'  Legal  Action  Group,  Inc. 


1301  Minnesota  Building 

46  East  Fourth  Street 

Saint  Paul,  Minnesota  55101-1 109 

(612)223-5400 

(612)  223-5335  (fax) 


April    5,     1994 


Randi  llyse  Roth 

INTERIM  EXECUTIVE  DIRECTOR 


Lynn  A  Hayes 

STAFF  ATTORNEY 


Juliet  M   Tomkins 

STAFF  ATTORNEY 


Timothy  J  Sullivan 

STAFF  ATTORNEY 
Admiitvd  in  Minnnot*. 
Montana,  and  N«w  Mei-co 


Bruce  M   Kleven 

STAFF  ATTORNEY 


Stephen  Caipenter 

STAFF  ATTORNEY 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 
Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit, 

and  Rural  Development 
2438  Rayburn  House  Office  Building 
Washington,  DC  20515 

Dear  Representative  Johnson: 

My  name  is  Bruce  Kleven  and  I  am  a  staff  attorney  at  Farmers' 
Legal  Action  Group,  Inc.  (FLAG)  located  in  St.  Paul,  Minnesota. 
FLAG  is  a  nonprofit  law  firm  that  provides  legal  services  to 
small  and  mid-size  family  farmers.   FLAG  is  submitting  testimony 
today  on  behalf  of  its  client  National  Family  Farm  Coalition 
(NFFC) .   NFFC  represents  39  rural  and  farm  advocacy  organizations 
in  30  states. 


For  the  past  eight  years,  FLAG  attorneys  have  worked  extensively 
with  USDA  agencies,  including  the  Farmers  Home  Administration 
(FmHA) ,  the  Agricultural  Stabilization  and  Conservation  Service 
(ASCS) ,  and  the  Soil  Conservation  Service  (SCS) .   FLAG  has 
successfully  represented  thousands  of  farmers  in  class  action 
lawsuits  to  challenge  illegal  agency  actions  and  to  enforce 
administrative  requirements.   FLAG  also  provides  legal  education 
and  training  services  to  attorneys,  farm  advocates,  and  farm 
organizations  regarding  USDA  programs  and  related  legal  issues. 
Over  the  years,  FLAG  attorneys  have  acquired  specialized 
knowledge  in  the  field  of  agricultural  law. 

In  response  to  the  extensive  flooding  in  the  Midwest  last  stunner, 
FLAG  attorneys  began  analyzing  existing  disaster  programs  to  cut 
through  the  red  tape  surrounding  federal  disaster  relief 
assistance.   FLAG  published  a  book  entitled  Farmers'  Guide  to 
Disaster  Assistance  that  explains  complicated  disaster  programs 
in  plain  language  format.   FLAG  also  operates  a  hotline  that 
farmers  from  around  the  country  can  call  for  legal  assistance. 

Much  of  my  work  in  the  past  year  has  focused  on  writing  portions 
of  the  book  and  answering  calls  from  disaster-stricken  farm 
families.   My  comments  this  morning  are  directed  at  some  of  the 
issues  that  were  raised  in  the  heat  of  the  disaster  last  sununer  " 
and  how  they  fit  into  the  proposed  crop  insurance  reform 
legislation. 


208 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

Page  2 

April  5,  1994 


General  Comments 

NFFC  generally  supports  the  concept  of  federal  crop  insurance 
reform  and  welcomes  a  workable  disaster  assistance  program.   For 
years,  the  federal  crop  insurance  program  has  been  plagued  by  low 
participation  rates  and  less  than  adequate  coverage  levels. 
Although  some  farmers  have  purchased  crop  insurance  as  a  normal 
part  of  the  cost  of  operating  a  farm,  others  have  been  forced  to 
give  up  crop  insurance  coverage  because  they  could  not  afford  the 
high  cost  of  insurance  premiums.   In  either  case,  fanners  with 
disaster  losses  have  relied  on  ASCS  disaster  payments  because 
crop  insurance  only  covers  a  portion  of  actual  losses.   This  dual 
disaster  assistance  approach  has  caused  considerable  confusion 
and  has  undermined  the  effectiveness  of  the  crop  insurance 
program. 

There  are  some  innovative  provisions  in  the  proposed  crop 
insurance  legislative  reforms  that  address  existing  problems. 
For  example,  FCIC  has  traditionally  required  a  ten-year 
production  history  to  purchase  effective  insurance.   A  beginning 
farmer  who  does  not  have  ten  years  of  history  was  penalized 
because  he  could  not  be  covered  at  an  effective  level  until  the 
ten-year  history  was  established.   Section  508(f)(2)(A)  of  the 
proposed  legislation  attempts  to  solve  this  problem  by  requiring 
a  minimum  four-year  history.   Such  a  provision  is  a  step  in  the 
right  direction  to  reforming  the  crop  insurance  system. 

Specific  Sections  of  the  Bill 

There  are  several  provisions  that  NFFC  feels  must  be  addressed  or 
clarified. 

1.   The  Catastrophic  Coverage  Level 

Under  the  proposed  legislation,  the  authority  to  pass  ad  hoc 
disaster  relief  legislation  has  been  replaced  with  a  catastrophic 
coverage  level.   Organizations  that  represent  the  interest  of 
family  farmers,  including  NFFC,  have  debated  the  proposed 
catastrophic  coverage  level.   While  the  $50  per  crop,  per  county 
is  arguably  very  affordable  insurance,  the  proposed  rate  raises 
some  questions: 

a)  Does  a  farmer  with  800  acres  of  corn  pay  the  same  $50  as  a 
farmer  with  80  acres  of  corn?   If  the  answer  is  yes,  the 
smaller  the  farmer,  the  more  that  farmer  will  pay  for  the 
same  coverage. 

b)  What  happens  when  a  farmer  has  more  than  two  crops?  The 
language  provides  that  catastrophic  insurance  can  be 


209 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

Page  3 

April  5,  1994 


purchased  at  $50  per  crop,  per  county,  not  to  exceed  $100. 
This  allows  only  two  crops  to  be  covered,  yet  it  is 
unclear  what  happens  when  a  farmer  raises  three  or  more 
different  crops.   If  the  catastrophic  coverage  level  is 
capped  at  $100,  there  is  no  statutory  mechanism  that 
allows  a  producer  to  insure  crops  three,  four,  and  five  at 
a  rate  of  $50  per  crop. 

c)   Does  the  language  "$50  per  crop"  mean  per  crop  raised 
(meaning  all  fields  planted  to  that  crop)  or  per  field? 
If  the  language  is  strictly  construed,  a  producer  with  20 
corn  fields  would  only  have  to  pay  $50  to  insure  all  20 
fields,  while  the  producer  with  1  corn  field  pays  the  same 
$50.   The  statute  should  define  what  "$50  per  crop"  means. 

The  above  cjuestions  illustrate  some  of  the  confusion  that  could 
occur  if  the  proposed  legislation  is  adopted  as  drafted.   FLAG 
encourages  the  Committee  to  address  these  ambiguities  to  avoid 
improper  interpretation  problems  during  the  rule-making  process. 

2 .  The  Group  Risk  Plan 

A  new  coverage  option  in  the  legislation  is  the  Group  Risk  Plan 
(GRP) ,  which  operates  on  a  county  average  system.   Our 
understanding  of  this  option  is  that  farmers  can  purchase  GRP 
coverage,  and  if  the  actual  production  for  that  crop  is  below  the 
county  average,  participating  farmers  will  get  a  payment 
representing  that  loss  even  if  the  farmer  did  not  personally 
suffer  a  loss.   This  will  allow  farmers  who  do  not  suffer  a  loss 
to  get  a  payment.   The  GRP  is  potentially  inconsistent  with  the 
purpose  of  the  FCIC  and  the  goal  to  improve  the  loss  ratio. 

On  the  other  hand,  if  the  overall  county  average  is  met  during 
the  crop  year,  but  an  individual  producer  suffered  a  disaster 
related  production  loss,  a  payment  will  not  be  made  to  that 
producer  because  the  county  average  was  met  that  year.   In  this 
situation,  the  producer  purchased  crop  insurance,  but  could  not 
get  an  indemnity  even  though  he  suffered  a  substantial  loss.   The 
GRP  potentially  covers  unaffected  fanners  and  does  not  always 
cover  affected  fanners. 

In  addition,  NFFC  feels  that  a  producer's  actual  production 
history  (APH)  should  be  used  in  place  of  county  averages  if  the 
producer  so  chooses.   The  producer,  not  the  insurer,  should  be 
able  to  choose  whether  to  use  APH  or  county  averages. 


210 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

Page  4 

April  5,  1994 


3-   The  Delivery  System 

In  past  years,  the  FCIC  has  offered  insurance  through  two 
vehicles:   directly  through  the  FCIC  or  indirectly  through 
private  insurance  companies,  which  are  reinsured  by  the  FCIC. 
The  vast  majority  of  the  crop  insurance  policies  (85  percent)  are 
purchased  from  private  insurance  companies.   Regardless  of 
whether  the  policy  was  direct  or  reinsured,  the  producer  would 
get  the  same  policy  because  the  reinsurance  agreement  was 
standard.   In  other  words,  private  insurance  companies  had  to 
offer  the  same  federal  policy  for  a  crop  to  all  producers  because 
the  agreements  were  standard.   This  system  provided  consistency 
throughout  the  industry. 

The  new  system  appears  to  have  the  federal  government  offer 
direct  policies  for  the  first  50  percent  level  of  coverage  (the 
catastrophic  coverage  level)  through  ASCS  offices.   The  private 
companies  would  offer  additional  coverage  levels  above  the 
50  percent  level.   However,  the  legislation  does  not  provide  a 
standard  reinsurance  agreement;  in  fact,  private  insurance 
companies  are  encouraged  to  be  more  efficient  and  competitive. 
In  the  absence  of  a  standard  reinsurance  agreement,  private 
companies  may  draft  insurance  agreements  that  are  either 
arbitrary  or  unfair  to  the  producers.   In  addition,  producers 
will  lose  administrative  appeals  rights  because  private  insurance 
companies  will  not  be  subject  to  federal  administrative  appeals 
procedures.   Without  an  effective  appeals  system,  private 
carriers  cannot  be  held  accountable  for  erroneous  or  unfair 
decisions. 

4.   The  Loss  Ratio 

The  Budget  Reconciliation  Act  of  1993  requires  the  FCIC  to  get 
its  loss  ratio  bac)c  to  1.1  by  October  1995.   This  means  that  the 
Corporation  cannot  pay  out  more  than  $1.10  in  claims  for  every  $1 
in  premiums.   Although  the  proposed  legislation  states  this  as  a 
broad  goal,  it  does  not  explain  exactly  how  the  FCIC  will  comply 
with  the  Budget  Reconciliation  Act. 

A  concern  farmers  have  is  that  they  will  have  to  pay  more  and 
receive  less  service  because  of  the  mandated  loss  ratio.   There 
are  only  two  ways  to  maintain  a  loss  ratio  of  1.1:   pay  less  in 
indemnities  or  increase  premiums.   Either  way,  the  producer  will 
get  less  service  for  the  money. 

Disaster  Concerns 

The  flooding  in  the  Midwest  last  summer  forced  some  issues  to  the 
table  that  had  not  been  addressed  in  past  years.   This  section  of 


211 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

Page  5 

April  5,  1994 


my  comments  illustrates  problems  that  could  recur  in  future  years 
and  therefore  need  to  be  addressed. 

1.   Specific  Cancellation  Provisions 

Producers  who  buy  corn  and  soybean  crop  insurance  in  this  part  of 
the  country  must  purchase  the  policy  by  April  15  of  the  crop 
year.   However,  the  insurance  premium  is  not  due  until  October 
when  the  crop  has  been  harvested.   This  method  of  payment  eases 
the  financial  burden  on  the  producer  by  reducing  the  amount  of 
money  needed  to  finance  the  operation  in  the  spring.   Even  though 
the  actual  premium  is  not  paid  until  the  end  of  the  year,  a 
binding  contract  has  been  created:   The  insurance  company  agrees 
to  provide  coverage  and  the  producer  promises  to  pay  the  premium. 
However,  several  farmers  contacted  our  office  in  1993  with 
complaints  about  improper  cancellation  of  insurance  contracts. 

In  one  case,  a  producer  purchased  crop  insurance  by  April  15,  and 
the  company  agreed  to  provide  coverage  at  a  certain  level.   The 
producer  reported  the  planting  dates,  but  did  not  provide  the 
exact  number  of  acres.   After  the  farm  was  flooded,  the  insurance 
company  notified  this  producer  that  they  were  cancelling  his 
policy,  even  though  the  contract  had  been  formed. 

In  another  case,  a  producer  received  disaster  assistance  in  1992, 
and  as  a  condition  agreed  to  purchase  crop  insurance  for  the  1993 
crop  year.   He  did  so  by  the  April  15  deadline,  and  reported  the 
number  of  acres  to  ASCS  but  did  not  report  his  acreage  to  his 
private  insurance  carrier.   He  believed  that  this  was  adequate, 
since  both  ASCS  and  FCIC  are  government  agencies.   Again,  after 
the  farm  had  flooded,  the  insurance  company  notified  him  that  it 
was  cancelling  his  policy  because  he  failed  to  report  his 
acreage.   When  ASCS  learned  that  the  producer  was  out  of 
compliance  because  he  did  not  have  crop  insurance  in  effect  for 
1993,  it  notified  him  that  he  was  ineligible  for  1993  disaster 
payments  and  that  he  must  pay  back  1992  disaster  benefits.   This 
producer  ended  up  without  insurance  coverage  for  1993  and  in 
addition,  had  to  pay  back  1992  benefits. 

The  regulations  governing  the  crop  insurance  program  (located  in 
volume  seven  of  the  Code  of  Federal  Regulations  at  Part  400) 
provide  specific  reasons  for  cancellation  of  an  insurance  policy. 
Valid  reasons  for  policy  cancellation  include  failure  to  pay  the 
premium,  fraud,  misrepresentation,  death,  and  judicially  declared 
incompetency.   However,  failure  to  provide  planted  acreage  and 
planting  dates  are  not  valid  reasons  for  cancelling  the  policies. 
Despite  this  language,  insurance  companies  denied  coverage  for 
those  reasons  in  the  examples. 


212 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

Page  6 

April  5,  1994 


Unfortunately,  in  a  year  when  the  producers  needed  the  insurance 
most,  the  insurance  companies  were  all  to  eager  to  avoid  claims 
whenever  they  could.   Clear  and  fair  cancellation  provisions 
should  be  included  in  this  legislation  so  that  insurance 
providers  will  be  prevented  from  acting  arbitrarily  with  respect 
to  the  cancelation  of  policies. 

2.  Penalties  for  Dual  Coverage 

Another  unfair  and  costly  situation  that  occurred  this  summer 
concerned  the  issue  of  dual  coverage.   A  Minnesota  farmer  had 
inadvertently  purchased  two  crop  insurance  policies  on  the  same 
acreage  for  several  years.   One  policy  was  purchased  directly 
from  the  FCIC  and  one  was  purchased  from  a  private  carrier.   The 
regulations  specifically  state  that  only  one  policy  can  be  in 
effect  at  one  time.   However  the  farmer  honestly  believed  that 
the  two  policies  were  different. 

The  dual  coverage  existed  for  several  years  but  was  discovered 
this  past  svimmer  during  the  severe  flooding.   As  a  penalty,  the 
FCIC  required  this  person  to  pay  back  all  of  the  indemnities  paid 
out  on  one  of  the  policies.   Fortunately,  the  FCIC  required  him 
to  pay  back  the  lower  of  the  two  indemnities.   However,  the 
payback  requirement  still  increased  the  financial  burden  in  a 
year  when  he  could  least  afford  the  penalty. 

It  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  severe  payback  penalty  is  not 
a  statutory  provision.   The  payback  requirement  was  adopted 
through  the  agency's  rule-making  process  in  1987,  even  though 
there  was  no  statutory  authority  for  this  penalty  and  the 
explanation  of  this  rule  did  not  disclose  the  origin  of  the 
penalty.   It  seems  that  this  harsh  penalty  appeared  from  nowhere 
and  was  used  to  increase  the  financial  burden  on  one  disaster- 
stricken  producer.   This  legislation  should  include  specific 
language  that  does  not  allow  the  FCIC  to  have  the  dual  coverage 
payback  penalty. 

3 .  Livestock  Feed  Assistance 

Past  disaster  bills  have  focused  significantly  on  providing 
compensation  to  producers  of  cash  grain  crops  who  suffer  disaster 
losses.   One  group  of  agricultural  producers  who  are  consistently 
left  out  of  federal  relief  dollars  are  livestock  pi^oducers.   The 
current  emergency  livestock  feed  assistance  program  allows 
livestock  producers  feed  assistance  only  after  the  entire  county 
where  the  producer  resides  has  lost  4  0  percent  of  its  available 
feed  supply.   This  threshold  is  very  hard  to  meet,  and  therefore 
the  program  is  not  available  very  often,  and  when  it  is,  the 
requirements  are  complicated  and  the  relief  is  not  effective. 


213 


The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

Page  7 

April  5,  1994 


The  proposed  crop  insurance  legislation  continues  to  exclude 
livestock  producers  by  addressing  only  cash-crop  insurance. 
Although  livestock  producers  can  purchase  insurance  for  feed 
grains,  insurance  is  generally  unavailable  for  forage  and  hay 
losses.   While  cash  crop  producers  will  be  able  to  protect 
themselves  from  future  disaster  losses  under  this  legislation, 
livestock  producers  cannot  purchase  similar  protection  for  their 
commodities. 

This  is  important  because  the  current  emergency  livestock  feed 
assistance  program  is  funded  through  annual  disaster 
appropriations.   If  this  legislation  is  adopted,  the  authority  to 
pass  future  disaster  bills  is  repealed.   Unless  language  is 
included  that  will  protect  the  interests  of  livestock  producers, 
the  emergency  livestock  feed  program  could  not  be  funded  because 
the  authority  to  do  so  would  be  repealed. 

4.   The  Emergency  Conservation  Program 

Another  disaster  program  that  is  available  only  during  natural 
disasters  is  the  Emergency  Conservation  Program  (ECP) .   The  ECP 
provides  cost  share  assistance  to  producers  to  help  restore 
conservation  structures  that  were  damaged  as  a  result  of  a 
natural  disaster.   The  ECP  is  only  available  through  a 
Congressional  appropriation.   If  the  federal  crop  insurance 
reform  legislation  repeals  the  authority  to  pass  future  disaster 
bills,  this  useful  program  might  not  be  funded  to  assist 
producers  who  lost  valuable  conservation  structures. 

We  thank  this  Committee  for  holding  these  field  hearings  and 
maintaining  its  commitment  to  improving  the  federal  crop 
insurance  program. 

Respectfully  submitted, 

FARMERS'  LEGAL  ACTION  GROUP,  INC. 


p2t 


Bruce  M.  Kleven 
Attorney  at  Law 

BMK/tr 


214 


UVGITIG  Mayor  William  V.  Weber 


11  eSE  Park  Street 

Luveme.  MN  56156-1730 

APR   n  *    189*  Home  507/2B3-2444 

Oflioe  507/283-2388 
Fax  507/283-4869 


April    1,    1994 


The  Honorable  Congressman  Tim  Johnson 

515  South  Dakota  Ave. 

Sioux  Falls,  South  Dakota  57102 

Dear  Honorable  Tim  Johnson: 

I  appreciate  your  efforts  to  understand  the  situation  of  our 
area  farmers  following  last  year's  flooding  and  the  efforts 
of  your  subcommittee  in  its  work  on  federal  crop  insurance 
reform. 

I  would  like  to  formally  welcome  you  and  members  of  your 
delegation  to  Luveme,  and  thank  you  for  selecting  Luveme 
as  a  location  of  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and 
Rural  Development  field  hearing  on  federal  crop  insurance 
reform  to  be  held  on  April  5th. 

I  am  sure  the  subcommittee  will  have  a  good  opportunity  to 
hear  from  area  farmers  as  they  offer  input  on  how  the 
program  can  be  restructured  to  better  accommodate  their 
needs . 

Once  again,  thank  you  for  your  concern  and  support. 


WILLIAM  V.  WEBER 
MAYOR 

WVW:rf 


Th«Cil|fclLuv<n«l»inA«nn1i>»Ac<anE9Ui<0|i|i«imitt|rEmplO)ti 


215 


Comments  and  Suggestions  on 

Crop  Insurance  Refonn 

from  Greg  Wheelock, 

Crop  Insurance  Services 

P.O.  Box  3123 

Mankato,  MN  56002-3123 

507-388-5367    •    Fax  507-388-3431 

1.  While  prevented  planting  coverage  has  been  added,  a  3  day  reporting  requirement  is 

too  stringent.  The  last  thing  on  farmers'  minds  will  be  reporting  in  every  3  days. 

2.  Complexity  and  time  requirements  of  MPCI  are  too  excessive  for  many  agents.  If 
these  agents  are  expected  to  exert  their  energies  and  abilities  in  promoting  MPCI  to 
meet  the  target  of  insuring  80%  of  potential  acres,  their  commissions  cannot  be  cut 
year  after  year. 

a)  For  example,  for  1994  most  agents  w^ill  receive  1.5%  of  base  premium  less 
because  most  companies  pass  the  entire  expense  reimbursement  reduction  by 
FCIC  to  their  agents.  Thus,  if  the  average  agent  received  15%  of  base  premium  in 
1993,  then  a  1.5%  of  base  premium  reduction  in  said  commissions  equates  to  a 
10%  reduction  in  income. 

It  won't  take  long  for  agents  to  realize  they  can  make  more  money  selling  lines 
other  tiian  MPCI  if  their  commissions  are  reduced  further,  and  thus  your  80% 
participation  target  won't  be  realized. 

b)  $50  -  $100  per  farmer  for  the  50/60  catasbrophic  policy  is  an  unreasonable 
amount  of  compensation  for  agents  and  companies  to  process  the  same  amoimt 
of  paperwork  and  pay  for  added  expenses  (additiorul  computer  programming 
requirements;  additiorul  training  of  company  vmderwriters,  field  staff  and 
agents;  and  extra  auditing  requirements). 

Also  as  $50-$100  provides  no  incentive  for  an  independent  agent  to  complete  said 
paperwork,  then  the  "job"  reverts  to  ASCS  to  process  the  policy.  I  doubt  if  an 
ASCS  employee  has  any  incentive  to  provide  more  than  basic  or  minimum 
service  to  an  insured.  Thus,  as  no  one  has  incentive  to  work  with  an  insured  to 
obtain  optionzd  units  with  coverage  based  on  actual  production  history,  the 
insured  will  become  disastisfied,  the  negative  attitudes  toward  'Tederal  Crop" 
wil  continue,  and  your  80%  participation  goal  won't  be  reached. 

c)  Remove  the  proposal  508  (b)  (4)  to  waive  the  $50  -  $100  "premium"  for  limited 
resource  farmers.  As  harsh  as  this  may  sound,  if  a  farmer  can't  afford  $100  for 
this  coverage,  chances  are  he/she  shouldn't  be  farming  anyway. 

3.  Added  land  rules  need  to  be  relaxed /revised  to  accoimt  for  land  added  in  the  last 
three  years.  It  is  disheartening  that  land  added  in  1991, 1992  or  1993  may  have 


216 


T  yields  of  65%  to  90%,  yet  if  the  same  land  is  added  in  1994,  it  most  likely  would 
receive  a  100%  T  yield.  Consideration  should  be  given  to  "grandfather"  in  land 
recently  acquired  by  (existing)  insureds. 

4.  Suggest  the  50/60  catastrophic  coverage  be  based  on  a  program  similar  to  GRP  as 
this  is  meant  to  replace  the  disaster  programs  which  are  administered  on  a  county- 
wide  basis.  While  the  coverage  is  essentially  free,  it  should  be  shown  that  said 
coverage  is  meant  only  to  replace  disaster  assistance  and  that  "buying  up"  to 
additional  coverage  is  a  cost  effective  risk  management  tool.  This  may  create  an 
incentive  for  both  the  insured  and  agent  to  work  together  in  a  long-lasting 
relationship. 

5.  Mcmy  of  the  new  applicants  for  1994  (because  of  disaster  requirements)  state  they 
have  not  Ccuried  MPCi  coverage  or  have  dropped  MPCI  coverage  because  65% 
doesn't  cover  enough,  75%  is  too  expensive,  and  com  coverage  is  too  expensive, 
espedeilly  in  relation  to  soybearis.  While  I  may  not  have  the  answers  to  these 
problems,  the  farmers'  voices  in  these  matters  must  at  least  be  heard  before  they  can 
be  addressed.  In  short,  higher  coverage  options  need  to  be  more  affordable. 

6.  To  insure  that  claims  are  paid  as  timely  as  possible,  suggest  guidelines  be  set  for 
companies  as  to: 

a)  The  ratio  of  adjusters  to  policies 

b)  Whether  claims  must  be  "verified"  after  adjustment  and  if  so  recommend  the 
ratio  of  verifiers/ auditors  to  policies. 

c)  Exact  loss  adjustment  procedures  defined  before  losses  set  in  (too  much 
interpretation  in  1993  concerning  wet  com  and  drying  changes). 

d)  Recourse  for  the  insured  when  claim  is  not  paid  within  30  days  as  stated  in 
policy  provisions. 

7.  While  most  agents  educate  others  as  much  as  possible  about  MPCI,  their  resources 
are  limited.  Much  of  the  negative  attitude  towards  MPCI  is  due  to  ignorance.  Many 
of  the  people  that  farmers  turn  to  for  advice,  such  as  barJcers,  accountants, 
commodity  brokers,  ASCS  and  Extension  employees,  financial  advisors,  and  the  like, 
do  not  fully  understand  MPCI  and  what  it  can  or  cjinnot  do  as  a  risk  management 
tool  A  large  scale  training  program  must  be  offered  to  these  professior\als  so  they 
can  at  least  extend  "educated  advice"  about  MPQ. 

8.  Remove  proposal  508  (d)  (3)  to  allow  companies  to  pass  on  any  savings  in  expense 
reimbursement  to  the  producer  by  reducing  premiums.  The  proposal  h<is  several 
inherent  problems. 

a)  Economies  of  scale  normally  dictate  that  the  largest  companies  have  the 
lowest  costs  «md  covdd  pass  more  savings  on  to  the  insured  than  smaller 
companies  thus  creating  vmfair  competition.  The  big  get  bigger  and  the  small 
get  smaller. 


217 


b)  Smaller  companies,  in  order  to  compete  with  larger  more  efficient  companies 
may  begin  "cutting  corners"  on  adjustment,  audits  and  underwriting  in  an 
effort  to  cut  expenses.  Premium  is  reduced,  but  so  is  service  and  quality. 

c)  In  the  Midwest,  most  coverage  is  at  65%  and  is  reasonably  priced.  Does  this 
level  really  need  to  be  subsidized  by  more  efficient  companies?  I  don't  think 
so.  Let  the  rates  come  down  by  themselves  through  greater  participation 
(80%  target)  and  broader  diversification  of  risk. 

d)  In  the  long  run,  by  showing  that  a  company  is  well  run  and  efficient,  its 
expense  reimbursement  ft-om  FCIC  will  likely  drop.  If  OMB  sees  a  company 
can  afford  to  pass  on  savings  to  the  farmer,  they  wiU  think  the  expense 
reimbursement  is  too  high  and  thus  lower  it.  Net  result:  income  drops  and 
premiums  rise.  There  is  no  longer  any  savings  to  pass  on  to  farmers  uitless 
the  company  again  lowers  commission  to  agent. 

9.  Agents  and  comparues  need  recourse  through  other  goverriment  agencies  such  as 
ASCS  and  FmHA  for  collection  of  unpaid  MPCl  premiim^.  It  makes  no  sense  that 
farmers  can  continue  to  collect  other  USDA  benefits  when  their  subsidized  MPCI 
premium  remains  unpaid.  There  is  a  need  to  offset  unpaid  MPCI  premiums  from 
other  govenunent  assistance  programs  such  as  deficiency  payments  at  ASCS. 

10.  Rather  than  creating  an  additional  MPQ  program  with  the  50/60  catasfa-ophic 
coverage,  improve  what  we've  got  now  and  just  stop  creating  ad  hoc  disaster 
programs!  When  farmers  and  their  bankers  realize  the  government  is  not  going  to 
keep  "bailing  tiiem  out"  they'U  resort  to  tiie  self-help  risk  management  program  we 
now  have  with  MPQ. 

11.  If  disaster  programs  continue,  make  MPQ  a  requirement  regardless  of  the  amount 
collected  from  disaster  payments  and  require  that  MPQ  be  carried  for  more  than 
just  or\e  year. 


REVIEW  OF  THE  ADMINISTRATION'S  FED- 
ERAL CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  PRO- 
POSAL 


THURSDAY  APRIL  21,  1994 

House  of  Representatives, 
Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit, 

AND  Rural  Development, 
Committee  on  Agriculture, 

Washington,  DC. 

The  subcommittee  met,  pursuant  to  notice,  at  10:30  a.m.,  in  room 
1300,  Longworth  House  Office  Building,  Hon.  Tim  Johnson  (chair- 
man of  the  subcommittee)  presiding. 

Present:  Representatives  Long,  Minge,  Pomeroy,  Thurman, 
SarpaUus,  HilUard,  Baesler,  Combest,  Allard,  Ewing,  and  Dickey. 

Staff  present:  Joseph  Muldoon,  associate  counsel;  Gary  R.  Mitch- 
ell, minority  staff  director;  Jan  Rovecamp,  clerk;  Anne  Simmons, 
Dwight  Fettig,  Merv  Yetley,  and  David  Ebersole. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  TIM  JOHNSON,  A  REPRESENT- 
ATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  SOUTH  DAKOTA 

Mr  Johnson.  We  will  bring  the  Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural 
Development  Subcommittee  to  order.  I  apologize  for  running  a  few 
minutes  late.  I  was  testifying  in  the  Raybum  Building,  and  that 
caused  some  complications.  j    •   •  a.    4-     ' 

The  purpose  of  today's  hearing  is  to  review  the  administration  s 
crop  insurance  reform  proposal.  We  have  heard  from  Gene  Moos 
and  Ken  Ackerman  in  our  initial  hearing,  and  we  also  heard  trom 
producers,  crop  insurance  agents,  and  lenders  during  a  field  hear- 
ing held  in  the  gentleman  from  Minnesota,  Mr.  Mmge  s  district. 

As  you  are  all  aware,  our  Government  is  involved  in  a  dual  sys- 
tem—one of  crop  insurance,  the  other  of  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  pay- 
ments. Frankly,  neither  of  them  work  as  well  as  they  ought  to. 

One  goal  of  the  1980  overhaul  of  the  crop  insurance  program  was 
to  eliminate  the  need  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs.  Clearly,  this 
has  not  occurred.  Congress  has  authorized  ad  hoc  disaster  pro- 
grams every  year  since  1986.  rr  u-n- 

The  Federal  Government  has  spent  an  average  of  $1.7  billion  an- 
nually for  crop  insurance  and  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  during  the 
past  10  years.  Producers  are  disenchanted  with  the  crop  insurance 
program,  as  evidenced  by  the  fact  that  participation  is  limited. 
Only  30  percent  of  the  eligible  acreage  is  enrolled.  And  when  they 
do  experience  crop  losses,  coverage  is  often  perceived  to  be  inad- 
equate. 

(219) 


81-128  0-94 


220 

Ad  hoc  disaster  programs  are  unpredictable  in  that  they  require 
emergency  appropriations  which,  in  turn,  generally  require  large 
regional  disasters  that  are  subject  to  the  political  whims  of  the  mo- 
nient.  Producers  cannot  budget  for  it,  and  it  makes  financial  plan- 
ning for  them  and  for  lending  institutions  virtually  impossible. 

We  have  the  two  programs  purportedly  working  side  by  side  to 
help  producers,  but  in  many  respects  they  are  working  at  cross 
purposes.  The  very  existence  of  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  under- 
mines producer  willingness  to  invest  in  crop  insurance  and,  in  fact, 
many  producers  all  too  often  do  not  take  out  crop  insurance  be- 
cause they  believe  that  the  Federal  Government  will  bail  them  out 
by  offering  free  ad  hoc  disaster  payments. 

I  commend  this  administration  for  taking  a  comprehensive  ap- 
proach to  reform,  offering  one  program  that  combines  catastrophic 
and  higher-level  insurance  coverage  for  all  currently  insurable 
crops,  with  standing  disaster  for  noninsurable  crops,  and  solves  the 
many  problems  that  have  been  enumerated  here. 

This  subcommittee  must  now  examine  the  details  of  the  adminis- 
tration's bill.  Above  all,  any  crop  insurance  proposal  must  be  fis- 
cally and  actuarially  sound  and  within  our  budget  requirements. 
Producers  must  be  convinced  of  two  things:  One,  that  their  out-of- 
pocket  costs  for  insurance  must  be  commensurate  with  potential  in- 
demnities they  may  earn;  second,  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  are,  in- 
deed, a  thing  of  the  past. 

It  is  essential  that  Congress  goes  beyond  merely  restating  its  op- 
position to  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  if  this  reform  is  going  to  work. 
Part  and  parcel  of  any  effective  reform  will  have  to  include  changes 
in  budget  rules  that  will  make  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  exceed- 
ingly difficult  to  come  by. 

There  are  many  other  concerns  that  have  been  expressed  to  me 
about  the  administration's  proposal,  and  they  can  be  discussed 
later  in  this  hearing. 

We  are  all  anxiously  awaiting  action  by  the  conferees  on  the  fis- 
cal year  1995  budget  resolution  to  determine  how  much  money  we 
will  have  to  work  with  in  implementing  the  reform  proposal. 

Mr.  Combest  and  I  have  been  in  touch  with  the  conferees,  as 
have  OMB  Director  Panetta,  Chairman  de  la  Garza,  Mr.  Roberts, 
and  a  number  of  other  Members  who  want  to  see  this  improvement 
happen.  Pending  the  outcome  of  the  conference  and  floor  action,  I 
plan  on  being  as  aggressive  as  possible  in  moving  H.R.  4217 
through  this  subcommittee.  I  will  continue  to  work  with  Chairman 
de  la  Garza  and  other  members  of  the  committee  as  this  legislation 
moves  to  full  committee.  I'd  like  to  welcome  today's  witnesses.  I 
look  forward  to  their  testimony. 

A  lot,  again,  does  depend  on  the  outcome  of  the  budget  negotia- 
tions. If  the  budget  numbers  come  out  too  short,  this  reform  simply 
will  not  be  a  viable  option.  But  I  think  at  this  point  we  need  to 
continue  to  proceed  on  the  assumption  that  we  will  have  the  fiscal 
resources  necessary  to  make  this  a  real  alternative  and  a  real  re- 
form. 

Now,  I  recognize  my  colleague,  Mr.  Combest,  for  any  opening 
statement  he  might  choose  to  make. 


221 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  LARRY  COMBEST,  A 
REPRESENTATIVE  IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  TEXAS 

Mr.  COMBEST.  Mr.  Chairman,  thank  you. 

I  would  like  to  join  you  as  per  your  statement  on  an  aggressive 
consideration  of  this  legislation  as  it  moves  forward — something 
that  is  well  overdue. 

Mr.  Chairman,  it  looks  as  if  you  have  put  together  a  great  group 
of  witnesses  with  great  expertise  in  Federal  multiperil  crop  insur- 
ance and  how  it  affects  agricultural  producers  around  the  country. 
I  am  especially  interested  in  getting  the  perspective  from  agricul- 
tural lenders  as  well  as  local  professional  insurance  agents. 

About  3  weeks  ago,  during  the  Easter  recess,  Mr.  Chairman,  I 
held  a  town  meeting  in  Lubbock,  Texas,  that  was  attended  by 
about  200  farmers  and  insurance  industry  representatives.  They 
came  together  to  hear  Ken  Ackerman,  the  Manager  of  the  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Corporation,  explain  Secretary  Espy's  proposal. 

Knowing  that  crop  insurance  is  a  useful  tool  for  farmers  in  west 
Texas,  I  was  encouraged  by  the  number  of  farmers  who  attended. 
I  believe  most  of  them  went  away  from  that  meeting  with  a  gen- 
erally positive  outlook  about  the  possibilities  and  benefits  of  this 
program. 

Although  there  will  be  adjustments  made  before  we  send  the  bill 
to  the  President — one  of  which  obviously  is  to  get  enough  money 
to  properly  fund  it — I  believe  the  program  changes  offered  so  far 
are  greatly  workable.  Even  faced  with  the  necessity  of  adding  $1 
billion  on  budget  to  fund  this  proposal,  it  is  sound  fiscal  policy. 

The  fact  is:  Wherever  bad  weather  affects  a  critical  mass  of 
Members'  districts,  we  have  been  reaching  out  and  declaring  an 
emergency  and  grabbing  an  extra  billion  or  so  every  year  for  disas- 
ter assistance.  That  cannot  continue 

I  look  forward  to  the  testimony  of  all  the  various  groups  today. 
There  will  be  mginy  particular  concerns  which  I  believe  can  ade- 
quately be  addressed  so  that  this  may  be  a  truly  comprehensive  re- 
form effort. 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  would  also  ask  unanimous  consent  to  put  in  two 
very  short  statements  that  were  given  to  me  at  the  Lubbock  meet- 
ing that  I  had  mentioned — one  from  the  Plains  Cotton  Growers  and 
one  from  the  Texas  Wheat  Producers  Association. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Without  objection. 

Mr.  COMBEST.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

[The  prepared  statements  of  the  Plains  Cotton  Growers  and 
Texas  Wheat  Producers  appear  at  the  conclusion  of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  We  are  anticipating  a  journal  vote  at  about  11 
today,  so  opening  statements — we  can  keep  them  reasonably  brief, 
but  nonetheless  I  appreciate  that  people  may  have  some  opening 
remarks  they  choose  to  make. 

Ms.  Long. 

Ms.  Long.  No. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Allard. 


222 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  WAYNE  ALLARD,  A  REP- 
RESENTATIVE IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  COLO- 
RADO 

Mr.  Allard.  Mr.  Chairman,  I'd  just  like  to  associate  myself  with 
both  your  comments  and  those  made  by  the  ranking  republican  of 
this  subcommittee. 

As  a  member  of  the  Budget  Committee,  I  would  like  to  see  some 
predictability  in  the  budgeting  process.  I  think  that  is  what  we  are 
striving  for  here  in  this  committee — to  have  some  predictability  not 
only  in  the  Federal  budget,  but  also  in  insurers,  when  they  are 
looking  at  their  budgets,  as  well  as  agricultural  producers  and 
other  financial  institutions  that  may  be  making  loans  to  agricul- 
tural interests. 

So  I  am  interested  and  glad  to  see  that  we  are  moving  along  on 
this  particular  issue,  because  I  think  it  is  important,  if  we  are 
going  to  have  responsible  budgeting  at  the  Federal  level  and  so  our 
agricultural  growers  can  have  some  expectations  of  what  is  ex- 
pected of  them  if  they  find  themselves  in  a  disaster,  and  it  is  based 
upon  more  or  less  what  they  perceive  would  be  their  needs  as  far 
as  insurance  coverage  is  concerned. 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you. 

I  have  a  couple  of  letters  to  submit  for  the  record. 

[The  letter  from  Mr.  Panetta  and  the  letter  from  the  American 
Agriculture  Movement,  et  cetera,  appear  at  the  conclusion  of  the 
hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Sarpalius. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  HON.  BILL  SARPALIUS,  A 
REPRESENTATIVE  IN  CONGRESS  FROM  THE  STATE  OF  TEXAS 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I,  too,  want  to  com- 
mend you  for  the  witnesses  you  have  today.  I  am  especially  anxious 
to  hear  the  comments  from  the  lending  institutions  that  are  here — 
different  banks — to  see  if  they  feel  this  plan  is  satisfactory  to  cover 
the  loans  that  they  make  to  producers,  and  also  to  get  their  opin- 
ions on  whether  or  not  they  think  producers  should  have  additional 
coverage.  I'm  anxious  to  find  out  how  much  that  additional  cov- 
erage would  cost,  and  also  if  the  appraisals  that  are  made  when 
losses  occur — and,  in  their  opinion,  if  they  feel  like  they  feel  those 
appraisals  are  satisfactory  to  cover  their  losses. 

Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  We  are  going  to  be  having  a  journal  vote  some 
time  around  11,  and  I  anticipate  numerous  other  votes  during  the 
course  of  the  day,  which  will  necessarily  cause  some  disruption,  but 
I  would  caution  the  members  of  the  subcommittee  that  I  want  to 
keep  the  time  spent  on  votes  to  an  absolute  minimum.  We  will 
recommence  the  hearing  very  quickly  after  voting  on  each  instance, 
so  do  come  back  as  quickly  as  we  can  because  we  are  not  going  to 
allow  the  disruptions  to  cause  more  problem  than  they  already  will. 

Also,  I  have  a  prepared  statement  from  Mr.  Pomeroy  for  the 
record. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Pomeroy  follows:] 


223 


Opening  Statement 

Congressman  Earl  Pomeroy 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural  Development 

April  21,  1994 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  look  forward  to  today's  hearing  to  learn 
more  about  the  reaction  of  the  key  players  in  this  debate  -- 
commodity  groups,  farm  organizations,  bankers,  and  providers  of 
insurance  --to  the  Administration's  proposal  to  reform  the  crop 
insurance  system. 

This  issue  is  of  enormous  importance  to  my  state. 

•  North  Dakota  ranks  first  in  participation  in  the  nation  -- 
measured  by  base  acres  enrolled  --  for  most  commodities 
grown  in  the  state. 

•  North  Dakota  producers  have  positive  and  productive 
relationships  with  insurance  agents. 

The  result  of  the  private-public  sector  partnership  is  a 
crop  insurance  product  that  is  attractive  to  producers  and 
works  well  for  them. 

Nevertheless,  the  product  could  be  improved,  the 
participation  rate  could  be  higher,  the  coverage  could  be  a 
better  buy  for  the  value  --  and  all  of  these  MUST  be  achieved  by 
Congress  if  we  are  to  ask  producers  to  give  up  access  to  ad  hoc 
disaster  assistance. 

Mr.  Chairman,  you  all  know  that  I  supported  changing  the 
budget  rules  to  shift  the  baseline  to  combine  ad  hoc  and 
mandatory  spending.   I  firmly  believe  that  the  House  Budget 
Committee  did  the  right  thing  --in  terms  of  accountability  to 
taxpayers,  of  strengthening  the  system  for  producers,  and  of 
trying  to  move  toward  a  system  where  each  producer  has  more 
control  over  his  or  her  individual  risk. 

However,  I  also  believe  the  House  Budget  Committee  did  not 
go  far  enough.   Yesterday,  I  sent  a  letter  to  the  budget 
conferees  signed  by  15  members  of  the  Agriculture  Committee  on 
both  sides  of  the  aisle  who  want  to  see  crop  insurance  receive 
full  funding.   Without  knowing  whether  the  proposal  will  have 
full  or  partial  funding,  I  fear  that  our  discussions  today  are  a 
bit  speculative.   Nonetheless,  many  of  the  issues  we  will  discuss 
today  are  part  and  parcel  of  the  existing  system  and  should  be 
addressed  whether  this  committee  considers  legislation  this  year 
or  next.   I  look  forward  to  the  testimony  today. 


224 

Mr.  Johnson.  Welcome,  Mr.  Odom.  Your  full  statement  is  re- 
ceived for  the  record.  You  may  choose  to  summarize  or  however  you 
choose  to  go  about  it. 

Because  we  have  a  very  long  list  of  witnesses  today,  we  will 
abide  by  the  5-minute  rule — ^the  green  light,  and  then  to  the  yellow 
and  red.  I  won't  gavel  anybody  down,  but  when  you  do  see  the  red 
light  come  on,  be  thinking  of  winding  up  your  remarks. 

Why  don't  you  proceed. 

STATEMENT  OF  BOB  ODOM,  COMMISSIONER,  LOUISIANA  DE- 
PARTMENT OF  AGRICULTURE  AND  FORESTRY,  AND  PRESI- 
DENT, NATIONAL  ASSOCIATION  OF  STATE  DEPARTMENTS 
OF  AGRICULTURE 

Mr.  Odom.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  am  Bob  Odom,  commissioner  of  the  Louisiana  State  Depart- 
ment of  Agriculture  and  also  president  of  the  National  Association 
of  State  Departments  of  Agriculture.  I  appreciate  the  opportunity 
of  coming  before  you  this  morning  on  what  I  think  is  a  very,  very 
important  subject. 

At  the  same  meeting  in  Texas  with  Ken — he  left  Texas  and  went 
to  Louisiana  and  spent  2  days  there  meeting  with  farmers  in  about 
four  different  areas  throughout  our  State.  I  thought  the  discussions 
were  very  good.  The  interest  is  there,  and  it  is  obvious  that  we 
need  a  change. 

The  disaster  program  and  the  insurance  program  both  working 
side  by  side  are  not  what  our  farmers  need  in  order  to  provide  the 
security  that  we  need  in  order  to  make  the  loans  in  order  to  stay 
in  business. 

One  of  the  problems  that  I  would  mention  is  in  our  State  and  in 
some  of  the  other  States.  From  investigations  in  court  actions,  we 
have  had  misuse  of  crop  insurance.  We  have  had  some  people  in 
some  States  that  have  farmed  for  crop  insurance.  That  is  not  good 
for  the  mainstream  farmer,  nor  is  it  good  for  agriculture,  in  gen- 
eral. 

Many  farmers  throughout  this  country  need  a  crop  insursmce 
program  designed  for  the  mainstream,  low-risk,  commercial  farmer 
who  is  interested  in  financial  protection  in  case  of  a  loss  due  to 
drought,  floods,  or  natural  disasters,  and  we  need  a  program  that 
farmers  can  afford. 

The  proposed  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  pro- 
vides the  framework  to  meet  this  need,  and  also  provides  the  posi- 
tive change  needed  if  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program  is  to  sur- 
vive. 

Additionally,  the  proposal  eliminates  the  uncertainty  of  farmers 
receiving  assistance  from  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  by  providing 
catastrophic  risk  protection  that  is  part  of  the  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram. 

Providing  disaster  assistance  on  an  ad  hoc  basis  as  we  do  today 
tends  to  discourage  participation  in  the  crop  insurance  program. 
The  possibility  that  a  farmer  will  receive  some  type  of  assistance 
even  if  he  does  nothing  to  protect  himself  from  a  loss  sends  a  very 
strong  signal  that  crop  insurance  is  an  unnecessary  expense.  It  is 
widely  accepted  that  we  cannot  continue  to  have  both  programs  be- 


225 

cause  of  the  cost  and  because  of  the  inequities  in  the  assistance  to 
provide  poor  and  current  disaster  programs. 

Farmers  prefer  a  comprehensive  crop  insurance  program  that 
will  help  meet  the  financial  security  needs  on  an  individual  basis 
rather  than  the  uncertainty  of  an  ad  hoc  disaster  program  depend- 
ent upon  wide  area,  multistate  disaster  and  congressional  approval 
of  funds. 

I  support  this  part  of  the  proposal  which  provides  a  permanent 
base  level  of  support  at  a  nominal  cost  to  the  farmers,  yet  costs  no 
more  than  has  been  average  cost  to  the  taxpayer  over  the  last  10 
years  or  so  in  both  disaster  and  insurance  programs. 

Specifically  as  it  relates  to  the  proposal,  I  support  the  following 
concepts  that  have  been  included: 

One,  a  comprehensive  Federal  crop  insurance  program  must 
meet  the  needs  of  mainstream,  low-risk  producers  by  offering  them 
financial  security  in  cases  of  drought,  flood,  natural  disasters,  and 
must  have  incentives  to  attract  those  producers  to  the  program  to 
insure  a  wide-spread  participation. 

For  example,  premium  discounts  should  be  offered  to  those  farm- 
ers with  good  experience.  Consequently,  farmers  who  consistently 
have  losses  should  be  placed  in  high-risk  pools  and  taken  out  of  the 
actuary  database  to  calculate  the  premium. 

Additionally,  significant  premium  discounts  for  high  level  of  cov- 
erage are  critical  in  order  to  attract  participation  at  those  high  lev- 
els of  coverage  which  are  needed  to  make  the  program  more  fiscally 
sound.  It  is  my  understanding  that  these  incentives  will  be  in- 
cluded in  this  program. 

Insurance  coverage  should  be  on  the  actual  production  history  of 
an  individual  farmer  on  proven  3delds — proven  through  the  farm 
service  center  when  the  reorganization  structure  is  completed  rath- 
er than  to  insurance  companies  through  private  agencies.  This  will 
reduce  any  attempt  to  assign  production  history  to  a  farm  on  the 
production  that  does  not  occur. 

Again,  it  is  very  important  that  we  put  it  on  an  individual  prov- 
en yield  and  not  on  some  parish  or  some  county  basis  that  tends 
to  lead  to  farmers  farming  for  crop  insurance  rather  than  for  their 
own  production. 

Farmers  should  have  the  option  of  buying  the  level  of  coverage 
they  determine  best  meets  their  needs  on  an  individual  basis. 
Under  the  proposal,  farmers  may  purchase  additional  insurance 
coverage  providing  high  yields  or  price  protection  levels  above  the 
basic  catastrophic  risk  protection  for  additional  premiums. 

The  FCIC  has  stated  that  farmers  will  have  more  flexibility  on 
jrields  and  price  and  unit  structure  than  is  currently  available,  with 
the  assurance  that  this  program  will  be  more  farmer-friendly,  with 
new  products  and  new  flexibility.  Incentives  are  provided  through 
premium  discounts  at  high  levels  to  encourage  greater  participa- 
tion, which  I  feel  is  extremely  important  to  the  success  of  the  pro- 
gram. 

Premiums  for  the  buy-up  coverage  must  be  reasonable  and  af- 
fordable for  the  risk  involved  in  order  to  enlist  the  low-risk  farmers 
into  the  program.  Farmer  records  should  be  identified  by  farm  se- 
rial number  and  Social  Security  number.  And  ad  hoc  disaster  as- 


226 

sistance  for  all  crops  eligible  for  crop  insurance  should  be  elimi- 
nated. 

I  support  the  catastrophic  risk  protection  program  offered  in  the 
proposal  at  a  50  percent  loss  in  yield  indemnified  at  60  percent  of 
the  expected  market  price.  I  do  not  feel  that  a  lower  base  level  cov- 
erage will  meet  the  needs  of  farmers  who  choose  not  to  purchase 
buy-out  levels  of  coverage. 

A  base  level  of  coverage  that  is  too  low  will  not  provide  the  farm- 
ers with  significant  financial  coverage  to  see  him  through  a  crop 
loss,  and  will  only  encourage  calls  for  an  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance 
to  make  up  the  difference.  This  will  find  ourselves  right  back  where 
we  are  today. 

I  also  support  the  noninsurance  assistance  program  that  covers 
those  crops  for  which  crop  insurance  coverage  is  not  offered  today. 
Replacing  the  ad  hoc  disaster  program  with  uncertainties  and  the 
catastrophic  risk  protection  program  for  a  noninsurance  assistance 
program  which  contains  a  protection  is  critical  to  this  proposal. 

With  both  programs  offered,  available  to  the  fanners  who 
produce  crops  eligible  for  crop  insurzince,  Federal  crop  insurance 
and  ad  hoc  disaster,  a  conflict  exists  which  creates  uncertainty  and 
provides  a  disincentive  for  low-risk  producers  to  participate  in  a 
crop  insurance  program,  thereby  weakening  the  whole  program. 

The  lack  of  participation  creates  a  high  loss  ration  to  premium 
earned  creating  the  need  to  increase  rates,  which  further  aggra- 
vates the  participation  problem.  Combining  these  two  programs 
into  one  eliminates  uncertainty  and  meets  the  needs  of  farmer  par- 
ticipation in  their  financial  planning  and  banking  relationship. 

Mr.  Chairman,  thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to  participate  in 
this  very  important  heziring  today  and  allowing  me  to  express 
NASDA's  support  for  the  administration  proposal,  Federal  Crop  In- 
surance Reform  Act  of  1994. 

The  current  program  is  not  serving  the  needs  of  mainstream 
commercial  farmers,  and  a  total  reformation  of  this  program  is 
needed. 

Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Odom  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Commissioner  Odom,  for  your  views 
and  the  views  of  NASDA.  I  particularly  appreciate  your  emphasis 
on  the  concern  for  actuarial  soundness  and  the  emphasis  in  the 
program. 

Let  me  ask  you:  In  1980,  Congress  reformed  crop  insurance  and 
said  "never  again"  to  ad  hoc  crop  disaster  pajmients.  We  know 
what  happened  after  that. 

This  time  we  are  saying  we  really  mean  it,  we  are  going  to 
change  the  budget  rules  so  that  future  ad  hoc  programs  would  have 
to  be  funded  either  by  higher  taxes  or  by  cuts  in  other  spending. 

How  much  credibility  does  that  have  out  in  the  countryside  in 
Louisiana?  Do  farmers  really — are  they  going  to  believe  us  when 
we  say  this  time  there  is  not  going  to  be  an  ad  hoc  disaster  pay- 
ment so  you'd  better  sign  up  for  crop  insurance? 

Mr.  Odom.  I  believe  that  if  we  see  the  disaster  provision  put  into 
the  bill  as  we  see  it  here  today  and  we  require — and  I  know  that 
requiring  is,  in  a  lot  of  terms  of  farmers,  is  a  nasty  term,  but  I  do 


227 

feel  that  for  the  price  that  they  are  saying — $50,  no  more  than 
$100 — that  it  ought  to  be  mandatory  in  the  program. 

Under  that  scenario,  and  for  it  to  be  successful,  we've  got  to 
make  sure  that  program  develops  an  opportunity  for  that  farmer — 
that  mainstream  farmer  who  wishes  to  buy  up  75  or  85  percent 
coverage — to  have  that  opportunity  at  a  reasonable  premium. 

The  reason  that  ratio  has  been  so  great  is  we  have  not  had  in 
the  program,  in  my  State  and  a  lot  of  the  other  States,  that  farmer 
that  has  always  been  in  the  top  of  the  production  that  would  make 
the  program  fiscally  sound.  We  have  had  too  many  people  in  the 
program  to  farm  for  crop  insurance. 

As  long  as  we  have  that,  we  will  not  have  a  program.  That's  why 
it  is  important,  again,  to  have  it  by  Social  Security  number,  have 
it  on  individual  yield.  If  you  put  it  on  individual  yield  and  you  con- 
tinue to  have  a  bad  year,  you  are  not  dependent  on  that  average, 
you're  dependent  on  your  5deld.  It  has  got  to  be  proven. 

We  have  proven  yields  for  years  at  ASCS  offices,  and  it  has  not — 
it  ought  to  be  on  a  proven  record.  I  think  that  would  put  the  fiscal 
soundness  in  the  program,  that  farmers  will  see  that  it  is  sound. 
And  yes,  I  believe  that  we  will  see  that  it  is  real.  And  yes,  I  believe 
that  they  will  participate  in  the  program. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Combest. 

Mr.  Combest.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  have  no  questions. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Ms.  Long. 

Ms.  Long.  I  don't  have  any  questions  either. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Sarpalius. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  Mr.  Commissioner,  you  have  indicated  in  your 
statement  and  just  a  while  ago  your  concerns  basically  of  farmers 
who  would  probably  farm  the  program,  or  abuse  the  program, 
which  does  occur. 

In  your  opinion,  do  you  think  if  we  provide  this  insurance  pro- 
gram for  more  producers — do  you  think  the  bill  is  strong  enough, 
or  this  legislation  that  we  are  looking  at,  or  program  we  are  look- 
ing at,  is  strong  enough  to  discourage  farmers  from  farming  the 
program? 

Mr.  Odom.  I  don't  think  you'll  ever  stop  all  the  thieves.  I  think 
that  we've  got  to  do  some  other  things  to  make  sure  that  happens. 
I  would  like  to  see  a  mechanism.  I  support  a  mechanism  that  a  lot 
of  people  may  not  support,  but  I  think  we  need  to  involve  county 
agents  in  this  thing.  I  think  somebody  needs  to  go  and  make  sure 
that  all  the  farmers  that  are  signing  up  are  carrying  on  normal 
farming  activities. 

If  we  put  it  on  an  individual  farmer's  yield,  if  that  yield  contin- 
ues to  go  down  that  coverage  has  got  to  go  down,  and  it  depends 
upon  what  that  production  is. 

I  think  that  will  help  solve  that  problem. 

Yes,  I  think  we'll  always  have  somebody  misuse  any  program, 
but  I  think  we'll  get  the  majority  of  the  farmers  that  will  not.  And 
I  think  today  that  we've  got  the  majority  of  the  farmers  participat- 
ing. Unfortunately,  those  that  are  farming  for  the  program  are  the 
ones  that  get  newsworthy. 

I  think  the  adjusting  of  the  claims  is  as  important  as  the  cov- 
erage, and  I  think  that  we've  got  to  work  some  things  out  in  the 
adjusting  of  the  claims  to  make  sure  that  whoever  adjusts  the 


228 

claims — ^whether  it  is  a  county  agent,  whether  it  is  somebody  else 
doing  it — ^that  a  normal  farming  activity  is  carried  on. 

I  happen  to  be  elected  as  commissioner  of  agriculture.  One  of  the 
things  that  I  happened  to  have  done  before — -I  was  in  a  consulting 
business.  I  did  a  lot  of  crop  damage  evaluation  work  for  most  of  the 
major  insurance  companies  on  pesticide  damage.  One  of  the  things 
that  had  to  be  is  that  you  had  to  prove  what  that  production  would 
have  been  on  that  farm  under  normal  circumstances  when  that  loss 
was  there  and  not  on  some  other  type  of  average  or  basis,  and 
that's  what  we've  got  to  do  in  the  crop  insurance  program. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Allard. 

Mr.  Allard.  No  questions,  Mr.  Chairman.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Minge. 

Mr.  Minge.  Thank  you.  I  have  a  couple  of  questions. 

I  appreciate  your  being  here  on  behalf  of  not  only  Louisiana,  but 
other  States. 

I  have  reviewed  the  statistics  over  the  last  decade  for  the  pay- 
outs under  Federal  crop  insurance  compared  to  the  income  that  has 
come  in  from  different  sections  of  the  country,  some  county-by- 
county,  and  we  have  some  dramatic  regional  disparities,  and  even 
disparities  within  States. 

There  is  a  fear  that  if  the  Federal  Government  does  not  subsidize 
Federal  crop  insurance  to  a  very  heavy  extent,  that  certain  crops 
in  certain  areas — and  I  think  that  perhaps  your  part  of  the  country 
is  favored  somewhat  more  than  the  upper  Midwest  where  I  come 
from  in  this  regard — it  would  be  very,  very  difficult  to  finance  crop 
insurance  with  premiums  in  the  South  and  the  Southeast. 

Do  you  have  any  observations  on  that? 

Mr.  Odom.  The  mainstream  farmer  in  the  South  and  Southeast 
does  not  participate  in  crop  insurance  program,  and  I  think  that's 
the  reason  you  see  the  difference  in  the  loss  ratio. 

We  have  to  have  a  program  that  gets  those  involved.  I  would  say 
in  sugar  production  you  have  probably  got  less  than  5  percent.  In 
cotton,  I  would  say — and  I  haven't  seen  these  figures — ^you've  prob- 
ably got  less  than  15  percent.  I'm  talking  about  Louisiana  specifi- 
cally now. 

A^ain,  the  problem  that  is  there  is  that  when  we  put  it  on  a  par- 
ish average,  most  of  those  farmers  in  a  disaster  year  have  to  make 
better  than  the  parish  average  to  stay  in  business.  That's  why  the 
program,  the  way  it  has  been  designed,  has  tended  to  give  an  in- 
centive to  farm  for  crop  insurance  rather  than  farm  for  the  produc- 
tion, and  we've  got  to  take  that  out  of  it.  If  we  don't  take  that  out 
of  it,  I  don't  care  what  we  do — ^we  still  won't  have  a  program  that 
is  fiscally  sound. 

Farmers  in  my  State  and  farmers  throughout  this  country  have 
got  to  have  a  program  that  bankers  are  satisfied  with  in  order  to 
be  able  to  have  the  loans  in  order  to  be  able  to  stay  in  production 
agriculture.  That's  why  I  came  back  and  said  a  few  minutes  ago 
I  think  this  proposal  is  in  the  right  direction. 

I  think  we've  got  to  look  at  the  adjusting  side  of  it,  as  well,  and 
make  sure  it  follows,  and  I  think  that  can  be  done  administra- 
tively, but  it  has  got  to  follow  along  with  it. 


229 

If  we  jfind  somebody  misusing  the  program,  he  needs  to  be 
brought  to  task  and  brought  to  task  severely  because  that  affects 
all  of  the  farmers. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Do  you  think  that  farmers  in  the  South  and  South- 
east will  participate  in  the  program  rather  than  rebel  and  say  we 
can't  afford  crop  insurance  because  the  premiums  would  be  too 
high  given  the  frequency  of  a  hurricane  system  coming  through, 
which  is  so  devastating  compared  to  the  less  common  threat  of  that 
type  of  an  occurrence  in  some  of  the  other  parts  of  the  country? 

Mr.  Odom.  Yes.  But  I  think  one  other  thing — I  think  when  we 
look  at  the  premiums,  if  we  looked  at  the  premiums  today  he  can't 
afford — the  mainstream  farmer  can't  afford  it  because  the  risk  ratio 
is  not  there.  We  are  going  to  end  up  having  to  look  at  a  premium 
incentive  for  that  85  percent  carrier.  In  most  of  the  cases,  that  85 
percent  carrier  is  going  to  be  a  less  risk  of  loss  than  somebody 
down  into  a  lower  range,  because  if  you  look  at  his  production 
record — and  we  are  going  to  have  to  look  at  that.  We  are  going  to 
have  to  look  at  what  his  record  has  been,  and  then  we  know  actu- 
arially how  sound  that  insurance  for  that  individual  farmer  would 
be. 

But  yes,  I  think  that  if  we  got  a  premium  that  was  reasonable 
to  get  him  involved — and  one  of  the  things  I  see  this  does  with  ev- 
erybody participating  is  it  builds  that  database  that  we've  got  to 
have. 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Let  me  ask  another  question  before  my  time  expires. 
I  am  also  very  concerned  that  the  Federal  Government  is  having 
trouble  financing  the  Federal  crop  insurance  subsidy.  The  Senate 
has  balked  at  this. 

I  know  in  Minnesota  we  have  a  $600  million  budget  surplus,  and 
they  are  trying  to  figure  out  what  to  do  with  it — have  a  tax  holi- 
day, or  what  are  they  going  to  do  up  there?  That's  a  happy  prob- 
lem. 

The  question  I  am  going  to  pose  to  my  Grovemor  and  State  legis- 
lature is:  Is  the  State  of  Minnesota  prepared  to  participate  or  join 
hands  with  the  Federal  Government  in  Federal  crop  insurance  or 
some  other  program  which  is  important  to  our  State?  I  would  ask 
you,  as  a  representative  of  the  State  of  Louisiana  or  other  State  ag- 
ricultural commissioners,  if  you  think  that  a  State-Federal  partner- 
ship is  in  the  cards  at  all  with  respect  to  this  problem  if  we  have 
trouble  trying  to  come  up  with  the  money  that  all  of  us  recognize 
we  have  to  have  for  a  good  crop  insurance  program? 

Mr.  Odom.  In  my  State  I  am  looking  at  $1  million  below  last 
year's  spending,  51  positions  below  last  year's  position  level.  It 
would  be  awful  tough  to  come  with  a  new  program. 

As  you  know,  we  have  a  sajdng  in  Louisiana,  "We've  been  so  rich, 
so  happy,  so  fat,  so  dumb,  and  all  so  long  it  has  been  hard  for  us 
to  make  other  changes."  Now  we  are  trying  to  do  that.  I  think  it 
would  awfully  tough  at  this  time  to  make  that  change. 

I  believe  that  if  we  can  put  the  expenditures  that  we  have  spent 
in  the  disaster  programs  and  in  the  crop  insurance  that  we  can 
make  it  fiscally  sound,  and  I  would  have  to  say  that  under  the  con- 
ditions that  I  see  other  States  in — and  I  know  that  some  of  the 
other  States  are  in  the  same  shape  that  we  are  in — it  would  be  a 
better  way  to  go.  That  would  be  a  tough  issue  for  all  the  States. 


230 

Mr.  MiNGE.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Ewing. 

Mr.  EwiNG.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Commissioner,  I  represent  central  Illinois.  I'm  not  thinking  about 
buying  extra  insurance,  but  I  am  thinking  about  the  disaster  provi- 
sions of  this  proposal,  the  50  percent  proposal.  Many  times,  even 
when  we  have  a  very  bad  year,  the  crop  5deld  doesn't  fall  below  50 
percent. 

What  would  you  think  in  your  State  of  allowing  for  some  options 
where  maybe  they  would  have,  instead  of  the  50  percent  production 
with  the  60  percent  payout,  have  a  60  percent  loss  with  only  a  40 
percent  payout?  Do  you  think  more  producers  would  find  that  at- 
tractive? 

Mr.  Odom.  I'd  have  to  look  at  the  economics  of  that.  Until  I  sat 
down  and  looked  at  how  the  60  percent  and  40  percent  economi- 
cally worked  out,  I  really  don't  know. 

Mr.  EwiNG.  You  mentioned  options — and  I  don't  want  to  inter- 
rupt your  thought  there,  but  to  me  this  is  the  kind  of  option  we 
could  give  to  producers  to  select  that  which  is  going  to  give  them 
the  most  protection. 

Mr.  Odom.  The  biggest  concern  that  I  have  had — and  the  medi- 
ans— we  had,  again,  four  or  five  medians  there.  The  farmers  want 
to  see  a  premium  that  is  affordable.  To  me,  if  we  could  come  with 
a  premium  for  that  75  percent  coverage  and  85  percent  coverage 
that  was  affordable,  it  would  be  a  better  option  than  increasing  the 
disaster  provision  of  it. 

I  think  what  we  are  looking  at  is  disaster  provision  that  has  kind 
of  been  based  on  what  we  have  been  able  to  receive  in  the  past  his- 
tory on  disaster  as  disaster  has  been  provided. 

See,  the  advantage  that  an  individual  farmer  has  got  on  this  pro- 
gram, as  I  understand  it,  over  the  other  disaster  program  is  that 
the  other  disaster  program  was  on  parish  average.  This  is  going  to 
be  on  an  individual  farmer's  average,  so  that  guy  that  makes  a 
much  higher  production,  that  farmer's  average  is  going  to  have  an 
equal  opportunity  at  that  50  percent  than  he  would  have  had  be- 
fore. To  me,  that  helps  the  program,  but  I  can't  answer  the  other. 
I  just  don't  know  the  answer. 

Mr.  EwiNG.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Baesler  has  gone  to  vote. 

Mrs.  Thurman. 

Mrs.  Thurman.  Mr.  Commission,  I'm  Karen  Thurman  from  Flor- 
ida. I  have  asked  many  of  my  different  associations  and  groups  in 
Florida  to  kind  of  look  over  this  bill,  and  they  have  some  concerns, 
particularly  in  the  area  of  specialty  crops  because  of  the  issue  of 
trees.  In  fact,  one  of  our  subcommittees  had  a  hearing  on  that,  and 
we  had  people  from  all  over  this  country  to  speak  on  some  of  those 
kinds  of  things. 

Have  you  all  done  anything  with  the  specialty  crops  issue?  In 
particular,  do  you  feel  comfortable  with  the  way  that  coverage  is 
under  here? 

Mr.  Odom.  We,  too,  have  some  specialty  crops — strawberries — 
similar  to  you  and  some  of  the  other  producers.  In  the  insurance 
coverage  it  would  be  the  same  offer  offered  under  specialty  crops. 


231 

Crops  are  being  considered.  I  don't  have  that  list.  I  don't  remember 
what  they  are. 

But  the  advantage  that  I  see,  again,  is  this  will  give  those  farm- 
ers at  least  a  known  disaster  or  an  ad  hoc  disaster  provision  that 
they  know  they  are  going  to  get  a  50  percent  and  a  60  percent 
price.  They  are  not  going  to  have  to  depend  upon  it  being  large 
enough  or  big  enough  for  a  national  disaster  or  for  the  money  to 
be  provided  by  Congress. 

I  am  told  by  the  administration  that  they  are  going  to  continue 
to  work  on  those  crops  and  bringing  them  into  the  program.  To  me 
that's  an  advantage. 

Mrs.  Thurman.  With  the  other  issue  of  some  of  the  specialty 
crops  or  trees  where,  in  fact,  there  is 

Mr.  Odom.  Did  you  say  trees? 

Mrs.  Thurman.  Fruit-bearing  tree  of  some  sort.  Something  like 
citrus.  That  comes  to  mind — where  the  fruit  actually  is  being  cov- 
ered, however  if  the  tree  is  damaged  and  killed  it  is  a  5-year  pro- 
duction issue  for  them  because  they  have  to  replant  the  tree,  and 
then,  of  course,  it  is  a  5-year  period  of  time — maybe  less  than  that. 
That  is  a  big  concern  for  them  in  these  kinds  of  programs. 

Mr,  Odom.  You  know,  we  have  just  a  little  bit  of  an  area  that 
grows  a  little  naval  orange. 

Mrs.  Thurman.  We  don't  recognize  it,  but  that's  OK. 

Mr.  Odom.  I  understand.  The  problem  that  we  have  there  is  that 
we  have  the  freeze.  We  have  a  freeze  that  will  come  through,  and 
about  5  or  6  years  ago  it  totally  wiped  that  industry  out  and  there 
was  very  little  protection  and  very  little  coverage,  and  that  is  a 
concern  for  us. 

I'm  not  sure  that  would  be  addressed  in  the  insurance.  The  only 
part  that  would  be  protected  as  far  as  I  see  here  would  be  in  the 
ad  hoc  disaster  provision. 

Mrs.  Thurman.  Just  so  you'll  know,  when  folks  came  from  all 
across  the  country  on  this  particular  issue  there  was  a  lot  of  con- 
cern about  that  because  there  evidently  had — before  I  was  here, 
there  had  been  conversation  that  it,  in  fact,  was  being  taken  care 
of;  however,  when  the  rules  were  done  evidently  that  kind  of  crop 
went  out  of  there.  So  I  just  bring  that  to  the  attention  that  we  have 
actually  given  some  language  to  talk  about  that,  so  if  you  can  help 
us  through  we'd  appreciate  it.  And  then  we  might  talk  about  the 
naval. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  have  been  advised  that  our  staff  has  been  work- 
ing with  the  nurserymen  and  the  fresh  fruit  and  vegetable  folks 
and  will  get  comments  for  the  record  from  the  nurserymen  directly, 
and  the  gentlewoman  from  Florida  may  want  to  consult  with  Mr. 
Limbaugh  to  see  what  else  is  going  on  in  the  citrus  industry. 

Mrs.  Thurman.  I  can't  respond  to  that. 

Mr.  Johnson.  We  have  had  a  10  minute  warning. 

Mr.  Pomeroy,  do  you  have  anything. 

Mr.  Pomeroy.  Yes.  I'll  be  brief.  I  think  we  can  get  it  in  easily. 

First,  Mr.  Chairman,  I  want  to  commend  you  for  this  hearing 
and  the  series  of  hearings  you  have  had.  I  apologize  that  another 
meeting  prevented  me  from  attending  the  opening. 

I  have  an  opening  statement  I'd  like  included  in  the  record,  but 
I  won't  read  it. 


232 

Mr.  Johnson.  Without  objection,  your  prepared  statement  was 
placed  in  the  record. 

Mr.  POMEROY.  Thank  you.  Commissioner,  I  used  to  be  a  State  in- 
surance commissioner,  and  I  can  report  some  familiarity  with  the 
loss  adjustment  issues  that  you  allude  to.  I  do  think  that  the  loss 
adjustment  is  something  that  we  need  to  look  at  should  this  pro- 
gram move,  making  certain  that  losses  are  being  adjusted  in  a  uni- 
form way  and  that  companies  are  not  competing  for  business  based 
on  relative  leniency  in  loss  adjustment.  That  will  be  very  important 
to  making  this  program  actuarially  sound. 

I  particularly  agree  with  the  part  of  your  testimony  found  on 
page  three  where  you  talk  about  the  importance  of  bringing  in  par- 
ticipation, increasing  participation,  particularly  at  the  higher  lev- 
els, and  that  the  subsidy  for  the  buy-out  is  really  a  critical  piece 
of  this  picture  if  we  are  going  to  make  the  reform  proposal  work. 

Would  you  care  to  elaborate  on  that  just  a  bit? 

Mr.  Odom.  If  we  don't  get  85  to  90  percent  participation,  it  is 
going  to  be  hard  to  ever  make  the  program  actuarially  sound,  be- 
cause what  you  are  going  to  be  getting  in  that  is  the  producers  that 
are  in  the  top  area  that  are  going  to  have  very  smaJl  ratio,  based 
on  the  fact — and  I'm  speaking  of  my  State  now  because  I  am  famil- 
iar with  that — ^based  on  the  fact  that  in  the  past  we  have  had  it 
on  a  parish  average,  and  on  a  parish  average  the  3deld  production 
did  not  affect  that  loss  ratio. 

If  we  get  those  top  producers  that  are  in — ^and  that's  what  we 
have  to  do — we  will  see  it,  I  believe,  much  more  actuarially  sound, 
and  then  we  know  then  from  the  history  of  the  record  of  all  of  the 
farmers  what  that  premium  has  got  to  be  in  order  to  make  it  actu- 
arially sound. 

What  I  see  as  the  Federal  side  of  it  is  then  coming  in  with 
enough  dollars  to  make  it  cheap  enough  to  be  affordable  so  that 
farmer  can  stay  in  business  and  then  that  bank  there  is  com- 
fortable with  him  to  make  the  loan  so  he  can  stay  farming. 

Mr.  PoMEROY.  It's  absolutely  right  and  absolutely  essential.  If 
this  is  funded  at  an  insufficient  level,  we'll  merely  be  basically 
prefunding  catastrophic  coverage,  doing  nothing  to  meet  the  insur- 
ance needs  of  production  agriculture.  And  that  is  going  to  have  a 
resulting  farm  credit  implication,  as  well,  which  I  think  could  be 
very  serious. 

Mr.  Odom.  You're  absolutely  right. 

Mr.  PoMEROY.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  Commissioner  Odom,  for  your  work 
with  us  on  the  subcommittee  today.  We  appreciate  your  insights. 

I  have  asked  Ms.  Long  of  Indiana  to  vote  early  and  then  come 
directly  back  to  pick  up  chairing  this  subcommittee  so  that  we  min- 
imize the  gap  of  time.  I  am  going  to  go  vote,  but  that  should  keep 
the  gap  to  a  minimum. 

The  second  panel  is:  Mr.  Phil  Bums,  president  of  Farmers  and 
Merchants  National  Bank  of  West  Point  Nebraska,  on  behalf  of  the 
ABA;  Larry  Diedrich,  president  of  the  American  Soybean  Associa- 
tion of  Elkton,  South  Dakota;  Mr.  James  F.  Hart,  president  and 
CEO,  Hand  County  State  Bank  of  Miller,  South  Dakota  on  behalf 
of  the  Independent  Bankers  Association;  Mr.  Chuck  Merja  of  Sun 
River,  Montana,  secretary-treasurer  of  the  National  Association  of 


233 

Wheat  Growers;  Mr.  Myrl  Mitchell,  chairman  of  the  crop  insurance 
advisory  task  force,  National  Cotton  Council,  of  Lenorah,  Texas; 
Ms.  Katherine  Ozer,  director  of  National  Family  Farm  Coalition  of 
Washington,  D.C.;  Mr.  Doyl  Rahjes  of  Agra,  Kansas,  president  of 
Kansas  Farm  Bureau,  and  board  member  of  American  Farm  Bu- 
reau Federation  of  Washington,  D.C.;  and  Mr,  Lee  Swenson,  presi- 
dent of  the  National  Farmers  Union  of  Washington,  D.C. 

We  would  appreciate  your  coming  forward.  However,  I  am  going 
to  recess  the  subcommittee  momentarily  to  take  care  of  this  vote. 
Hopefully  we  will  be  back  in  action  very  soon. 

[Recess  taken.] 

Ms.  Long  [assuming  chair].  We  will  reconvene,  and  we  are  going 
to  take  Larry  Diedrich  first  because  he  has  to  catch  a  flight. 

We  will  begin  with  Larry  Diedrich. 

STATEMENT  OF  LARRY  DIEDRICH,  PRESIDENT,  AMERICAN 

SOYBEAN  ASSOCIATION 

Mr.  Diedrich.  Thank  you.  I  appreciate  it. 

Good  morning.  My  name  is  Larry  Diedrich,  as  you  indicated,  and 
I  am  a  soybean,  com,  and  hog  producer  from  Elkton,  South  Dakota, 
and  currently  serve  as  president  of  the  American  Soybean  Associa- 
tion. 

We  do  appreciate  the  opportunity  today  to  testify  on  behalf  of  the 
Federal  crop  insurance  program  and  to  propose  a  few  improve- 
ments on  the  program. 

Soybean  producers  traditionally  have  not  been  participating  at 
the  level  that  they  probably  should  be  in  the  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram. There  are  many  reasons  for  that,  but  part  of  it  is  the  percep- 
tion, as  was  indicated  earlier  this  morning,  that  better  farmers — 
it  is  not  a  good  value  for  them,  and  that  the  people  that  are  taking 
crop  insurance  are  taking  it  with  the  intention  on  using  the  crop 
insurance. 

However,  I  think  over  the  last  couple  of  years,  with  record  losses 
resulting  from  drastic  weather  patterns,  coupled  with  improve- 
ments that  have  been  made  in  the  program,  this  attitude  has 
changed  with  soybean  producers.  Many  are  reconsidering  the  op- 
tion of  crop  insurance. 

My  brother  and  I  are  examples  of  that.  We  will  be  new  partici- 
pants in  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program  this  year  for  the  first 
time,  insuring  both  our  soybeans  and  corn. 

We  have  found  several  improvements  in  the  program,  including 
the  late  and  preventive  planning  coverage  for  soybeans,  and  with 
our  records  we  are  able  to  utilize  the  actual  production  history 
jdelds,  which  helps  benefit  us  considerably. 

However,  I  could  recommend  changing  current  policy  for  drilled 
soybeans.  It  currently  costs  25  percent  more  to  cover  drilled  soy- 
beans as  opposed  to  conventional  row-planted  soybeans,  even 
though  drilled  soybeans  produce  higher  5delds. 

Many  producers  in  our  region  plant  with  the  drill  because  of  the 
no-till,  which  is  coming  into  practice.  We  feel  we  should  not  be  pe- 
nsdized  for  updating  and  improving  our  efficiencies. 

Soybean  producers,  as  well  as  other  farmers,  need  risk  manage- 
ment tools  to  provide  income  security  and  stability.  The  Federal 
crop  insurance  program  could  and  should  be  a  useful  means  for 


234 

doing  just  that.  The  administration's  reform  proposal  is  a  step  in 
the  right  direction.  Producers  do  need  protection  from  catastrophic 
disaster. 

Under  current  budget  constraints,  ad  hoc  Federal  disaster  assist- 
ance will  become  harder  and  harder  to  count  on.  The  administra- 
tion's proposal  guarantees  basic  coverage  for  catastrophic  disasters 
to  all  producers  at  a  very  minimum  cost.  It  also  gives  the  farmers' 
lenders  assurance  of  guaranteed  protection  against  extreme  disas- 
ters. 

The  administration's  catastrophic  plan  in  itself  does  not  offer 
complete  risk  management.  We  must  improve  the  current  crop  in- 
surance program  to  accomplish  this.  It  is  my  understanding  the  ad- 
ministration's proposal  will  continue  to  offer  the  options  of  addi- 
tional coverage  at  the  65  and  75  percent  levels  at  slightly  below 
current  cost. 

Many  of  our  members  would  favor  adding  the  option  of  an  85 
percent  coverage,  as  was  indicated  earlier  this  morning.  In  addi- 
tion, all  graded  yields  should  be  based  on  actual  production  history. 

Test  counties  in  24  saving  producing  States  now  offer  the  group 
risk  plan.  Although  participation  has  not  been  great  and  it  is  too 
early  to  really  assess  how  this  program  is  going  to  work,  we  do 
have  some  concerns  with  this  particular  test  plan  by  fact  that  if  a 
small  amount  of  farmers  in  one  side  of  the  county  have  either  a 
flood  or  hail  or  something  like  that  and  it  affects  their  production 
considerably,  whereas  the  whole  county  is  not  affected  a  great  deal, 
those  people  would  not  be  covered  to  the  extent  that  they  need  to 
be,  so  it  does  have  some  weaknesses  in  that  area.  I  will  admit  that 
views  on  this  do  vary  region  by  region. 

Views  and  concerns  regarding  the  provisions  in  the  administra- 
tion's reform  package  vary  region  by  region,  as  producers.  However, 
I  would  like  to  mention  three  special  significances  mentioned  by 
our  membership. 

First,  in  the  deUvery  of  the  program:  Opinions  differ  on  the  pre- 
ferred choice  of  delivery  for  crop  insurance.  As  you  know,  most  pro- 
ducers in  my  region  would  prefer  private  companies  handling  crop 
insurance.  However,  in  the  South  where  there  have  been  problems 
with  some  agents  and  companies,  many  producers  feel  ASCS  or  the 
proposed  Farm  Service  Agency  should  manage  these  insurances. 

My  hope  is  that,  regardless  of  who  offers  the  insurance,  that  it 
be  handled  consistently  and  that  handlers  be  responsible  and  ac- 
countable for  policies,  as  was  mentioned  also  earlier. 

Second,  when  we  talk  about  linkage  of  crop  insurance  to  farm 
programs:  currently  under  the  proposal  it  is  a  very  minimal  fee  to 
sign  up  for  the  crop  insurance,  but  farmers  do  have  concerns  that 
it  is  the  program  now,  we  do  not  know  what  that  program  is  going 
to  be  in  the  future,  and  there  are  concerns  that  if  we  set  the  prece- 
dence of  mandating  a  linkage  to  farm  programs  that,  as  this  pro- 
gram may  change,  that  precedence  may  stay  with  it.  There  is  some 
concern  in  that  area. 

In  the  area  of  price  selections,  many  of  our  members,  particularly 
in  the  South,  are  not  satisfied  with  the  current  pricing  formula  sys- 
tem. They  favor  price  selection  more  reflective  of  local  prices.  For 
example,  the  highest  price  selection  in  my  State  is  $6.  That  is  a 
fair  price  for  me.  However,  $6  is  probably  not  the  right  price  for 


235 

down  in  Louisiana.  They  may  need  $6.50  to  cover  their  higher 
input  cost  and  better  reflect  their  market  basis. 

If  there  are  suggestions,  there  may  be  a  suggestion  to  change 
that  and  make  sure  we  have  a  wide  enough  price  range  to  adapt 
to  every  farmer's  needs. 

I  do  appreciate  this  opportunity  to  be  here  today  and  to  express 
some  views  and  concerns  of  the  U.S.  soybean  producers  regarding 
the  Federal  crop  insurance  program.  I  do  not  envy  the  committee's 
challenge  as  you  tackle  the  growing  need  to  improve  our  system 
and  wean  producers  from  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance. 

I  would  be  happy  to  provide  additional  information  on  other  as- 
pects of  the  proposal  or  the  current  crop  insurance  program  as 
needed. 

Thanks  again  for  this  opportunity, 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Diedrich  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Ms.  Long.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Diedrich. 

Since  you  do  have  a  very  tight  time  constraint,  if  there  are  any 
questions  we  will  present  those  for  you. 

Mr.  Diedrich.  I  appreciate  that. 

Ms.  Long.  There  are  no  questions,  so,  without  objection,  if  any 
do  come  up  with  other  members  as  they  return  from  the  vote,  we 
will  submit  them  to  you  and  your  response  will  be  submitted  for 
the  record 

Mr.  Diedrich.  Thank  you  very  much. 

Ms.  Long.  Thank  you.  Our  next  panelist  is  Mr.  Phil  Bums. 

STATEMENT  OF  PHIL  BURNS,  PRESIDENT,  FARMERS  AND 
MERCHANTS  NATIONAL  BANK,  WEST  POINT,  NE,  ON  BEHALF 
OF  THE  AMERICAN  BANKERS  ASSOCIATION 

Mr.  Burns.  Thank  you.  Madam  Chairman. 

Members  of  the  subcommittee,  I  am  pleased  to  be  here  today  on 
behalf  of  the  Americ£m  Bankers  Association  to  participate  in  this 
hearing  regarding  H.R.  4217,  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform 
Act  of  1994. 

My  name  is  Phil  Bums,  and  I  am  president  of  the  Farmers  and 
Merchants  National  Bank  in  West  Point,  Nebraska,  and  we  are  lo- 
cated about  50  miles  northwest  of  Omaha.  I  currently  serve  on  the 
American  Bankers  Association  Agricultural  Bankers  Agricultural 
Bankers  Executive  Committee.  My  bank  has  $65  million  in  assets, 
and  a  loan  portfolio  of  $50  million,  of  which  about  $35  million  are 
loans  directly  to  agricultural  producers.  Crops  in  our  service  area 
include  com,  soybeans,  and  alfalfa. 

Like  many  other  banks  across  the  Nation,  we  own  a  full-service 
insurance  agency  which  we  bought  about  4  years  ago;  however,  we 
have  been  selling  crop  insurance  for  the  past  10  years,  as  we  en- 
tered that  business  several  years  before  we  bought  the  full-line  in- 
surance agency. 

As  many  of  you  know,  the  American  Bankers  Association  is  the 
national  trade  and  professional  association  for  America's  commer- 
cial banks,  from  the  smallest  to  the  largest.  ABA's  members  rep- 
resent about  90  percent  of  the  industry's  total  assets.  Approxi- 
mately 94  percent  of  ABA  members  are  community  banks  like  ours 


236 

with  assets  of  less  than  $500  miUion.  Over  half  of  ABA's  12,000 
members  have  important  agricultural  concerns. 

It  is  good  to  be  here  today  to  make  a  brief  statement  and  to  an- 
swer any  questions  you  may  have. 

To  begin,  the  banking  industry  would  like  to  commend  Chairman 
Johnson,  Congressman  Combest,  and  the  entire  subcommittee  for 
looking  at  ways  in  which  we  can  effectively  address  crop  insurance 
and  disaster  assistance  issues.  Further,  America's  small  and  large 
banks  support  adequately  funded  crop  insurance  reform  at  the  Fed- 
eral level. 

Your  interest  in  improving  the  crop  insurance  program  by  pro- 
viding reliable  catastrophic  coverage  on  the  basis  of  individual 
farmer's  needs  and  reducing  unreliable  ad  hoc  agricultural  disaster 
programs  is  a  good  move  for  our  Nation's  farmers  and  for  the  rural 
communities  about  which  we  are  all  concerned. 

Emphasis  on  crop  insurance  sales  through  the  private  sector 
wherever  possible  is  also  a  step  in  the  right  direction. 

Banks  across  the  country  are  primarily  concerned  about  the 
availability  of  crop  insurance  which  can  be  consistently  and  effi- 
ciently used  as  collateral.  We  know  that  dependable  crop  insurance 
can  and  frequently  does  mean  the  difference  in  whether  banks  are 
able  to  approve  operating  loans  and  other  types  of  credit  for  farm- 
ers who  are  struggling  to  stay  ahead  in  high-risk  situations  and  in 
challenging  agricultural  markets.  ! 

Like  many  other  banks,  our  bank  is  an  active  participant  in  j 
Farmers  Home  Administration  guaranteed  lending  programs.  ! 
Farmers  Home  requires  the  purchase  of  crop  insurance  before  I 
loans  can  be  processed.  ; 

We  join  other  banks  across  the  country  in  looking  for  ways  to  : 
help  beginning  farmers  and  ranchers,  in  particular,  who  are  often  ; 
high-risk  borrowers.  Adequate  crop  insurance  coverage  helps  us  to  ; 
continue  to  serve  these  and  other  customers.  | 

Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  this  subcommittee,  commercial  '! 
banks  join  you  in  looking  for  ways  in  which  cost-effective  and  reli- 
able types  of  crop  insurance  can  be  made  available  at  reasonable   ' 
prices.  Crop  insurance  is  one  of  the  Government-assisted  programs   \ 
utilized  by  commercial  banks  to  effectively  serve  rural  economies,   i 

The  banking  industry  is  interested  in  working  with  you  to  con-  ' 
sider  reasonable  ways  in  which  we  can  continue  meeting  the  var-  : 
ious  needs  of  all  rural  communities.  I 

Mr.  Chairman,  in  closing,  American  bankers  are  interested  in  i 
working  with  you  and  members  of  this  subcommittee  to  advance  an  i 
adequately  funded  and  reliable  crop  insurance  program  which  can  | 
meet  the  various  needs  of  the  farmers  we  serve.  , 

Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  express  the  concerns  of  small  l| 
and  large  banks  across  our  Nation.  ' 

Attached  to  my  printed  statement  are  specific  responses  to  your  ; 
questions  regarding  H.R.  4217.  i 

I  would  be  happy  to  address  any  questions  at  the  appropriate  ;i 
time.  I 

Thank  you.  ' 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Bums  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 


237 

Mr.  Johnson  [resuming  chair].  I  think  Mr.  Diedrich  had  to  leave 
to  catch  a  plane,  as  I  understand,  so  we  will  proceed  next  to  Mr. 
Hart. 

STATEMENT  OF  JAMES  F.  HART,  PRESIDENT  AND  CEO,  HAND 
COUNTY  STATE  BANK,  MILLER,  SD,  ON  BEHALF  OF  THE 
INDEPENDENT  BANKERS  ASSOCIATION  OF  AMERICA 

Mr.  Hart.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  the  subcommittee,  my  name  is 
Jim  Hart.  I  am  president  and  CEO  of  the  Hand  County  State  Bank 
in  Miller,  South  Dakota.  I  am  pleased  to  be  here  today  to  testify 
on  the  administration's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  on  behalf  of 
the  Independent  Bankers  Association  of  America,  better  known  as 
IBAA. 

IBAA  is  the  only  national  trade  association  that  exclusively  rep- 
resents the  views  of  the  Nation's  community  bankers.  I  will  abbre- 
viate my  remarks,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  submit  my  entire  statement 
for  the  record. 

Mr.  Chairman,  let  me  begin  by  congratulating  you  on  your  elec- 
tion as  chairman  of  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit,  and 
Rural  Development.  All  three  of  these  subject  areas — environment, 
credit,  and  rural  development — are  critical  to  the  future  of  the 
State  of  South  Dakota.  So,  from  strictly  a  personal  standpoint,  if 
you  will  excuse  this  expression,  we've  got  you  right  where  we  want 
you. 

But  we  also  thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  making  crop  insurance 
reform  one  of  your  earliest  priorities  in  this  subcommittee  and  for 
scheduling  this  hearing  today. 

Reforming  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program  is  certainly  not 
an  easy  task,  and  we  are  grateful  to  you  for  taking  the  initiative 
to  move  this  process  forward. 

First,  bankers  use  crop  insurance.  Crop  insurance  is  important 
to  agricultural  bankers  because  many  of  us  use  it  to  collect  collat- 
eral on  operating  loans.  To  put  it  very  simply,  we  would  rather 
lend  on  a  contract  than  a  promise. 

A  crop  insurance  policy  is  an  effective  and  reliable  backstop  for 
agricultural  loans,  while  ad  hoc  disaster  payments,  which  may  or 
may  not  be  there  when  needed,  are  not. 

Your  proposal  is  fundamentally  sound.  Is  the  reform  legislation 
on  the  table  perfect?  No.  Not  by  any  means.  Is  it  IBAA  supported? 
Yes,  100  percent. 

While  some  of  us  may  want  to  take  around  the  edges  of  the  pro- 
posal, the  underlying  concept  that  combines  disaster  relief  and  crop 
insurance  to  form  one  catastrophic  protection  program  for  all  farm- 
ers is  such  an  improvement  over  the  existing  system  that  it  should 
not  be  jeopardized  by  our  desire  to  make  it  perfect. 

Farm  subsidies  are  in  decline,  Mr.  Chairman.  At  last  year's  Agri- 
cultural Outlook  Conference,  Secretary  of  Agriculture  Mike  Espy 
said,  "I  have  seen  the  handwriting  on  the  wall.  U.S.  budget  support 
to  agriculture  will  continue  to  decline.  They  can  scream,  they  can 
curse,  they  can  lambast,  and  sometimes  even  cause  delays,  but  the 
fact  is  that  U.S.  budget  support  for  agriculture  will  continue  to  de- 
cline." 


238  ' 

I 

This  was  never  more  evident  than  during  last  year's  appropria-  ; 
tions  process  when  two  very  popular  and  traditional  farm  pro-  ' 
grams — the  wool  and  mohair  program  and  the  honey  program —  '< 
were  abolished.  What  is  next?  Tobacco?  Peanuts?  Cotton?  Rice?  ; 
Wheat?  It  is  anybod/s  guess.  i 

With  this  prospect  being  laid  directly  on  the  table,  it  becomes  i 
even  more  imperative  for  farmers  and  ranchers  to  begin  to  manage  j 
their  farm  risks  more  prudently.  i 

Having  said  that,  Mr.  Chairman,  let  me  briefly  address  severed  i 
features  of  the  bill  in  more  detail  and  make  some  recommendations  : 
for  making  the  package  a  more  effective  risk  management  program  | 
for  our  Nation's  agricultural  community.  1 

First,  repeal  disaster  authority.  Authority  for  ad  hoc  disaster  pro-  i 
grams  must  repealed.  Without  this,  no  reform  package  will  work.  I 
It  is  just  that  simple.  So  long  as  farmers  and  ranchers  know  that  i 
if  financial  disaster  strikes  they  can  easily  count  on  the  Federal  i 
Government  to  bail  them  out,  there  is  no  incentive  for  them  to  pur-  : 
chase  crop  insurance — and  who  can  blame  them? 

If  Congress  passes  everywhere  just  crop  insurance  reform  pro-  i 
posal  but  fails  to  terminate  the  authority  for  ad  hoc  disaster  pro-  | 
grams,  the  reform  proposal  simply  will  not  work.  There  will  be  no  i 
incentive  for  farmers  to  self-protect,  and  a  vicious  cycle  of  annual  ■ 
ad  hoc  relief  programs  will  continue.  ! 

Second,  cross-compliance  is  also  a  key.  We  strongly  support  the  j 
cross-compliance  features  of  the  proposal  and  feel  that  this  is,  too,  i 
a  key  to  the  program's  success.  You  cannot  go  out  and  buy  a  house  j 
today  and  get  a  loan  without  first  buying  fire  insurance.  You  can't  , 
buy  a  car  off  a  lot  without  auto  insurance. 

If  the  Federal  Government  invests  in  the  farmer/rancher  through 
subsidized  loans,  deficiency  payments,  CRP,  or  anything  else,  the  i 
Government  has  the  right  to  protect  that  investment  by  requiring  i 
producers  to  carry  crop  insurance. 

Three,  we  believe  price  competition  is  good.  We  support  the  pro-  3 
vision  that  allows  more  efficient  insurance  companies  to  reduce  i 
rates  charged  to  farmers  and  ranchers.  Price  competition  is  fun-  c 
damental  to  the  free  market  system.  It  has  worked  in  every  sector  i 
of  our  economy  and  has  ensured  American's  the  highest  quality  ; 
product  and  service  at  the  lowest  possible  prices.  We  believe  price  : 
competition  would  have  the  same  effect  on  crop  insurance.  |' 

We  believe  dual  delivery  system  is  a  concern.  Along  these  lines,  '5 
while  we  support  the  feature  of  the  bill  that  requires  farmers  to 
purchase  higher  coverage  policies  exclusively  from  private  agents,  ) 
we  have  some  concerns  about  delivering  the  basic  catastrophic  cov-  1 
erage  programs  through  Federal  offices.  r 

Many  of  us  remember  when  crop  insurance  was  sold  in  ASCS  of-  \\ 
fices.  This  was  not  a  good  situation.  ASCS  employees  did  not  have  |' 
at  that  time — and  probably  will  not  have  in  the  future — expertise  li 
nor  the  incentive  to  deliver  these  products  in  an  efficient,  conscien-  c 
tious  manner.  The  resultant  attitude  will  be,  in  my  opinion,  the  \i 
same,  and  many  producers  will  not  get  adequate  guidance  on  other  ]i 
buy-up  opportunities  that  might  better  suit  the  individual  require-  n 
ments. 

We  should  make  crop  insurance  funds  mandatory.  We  support 
moving  crop  insurance  from  discretionary  to  the  mandatory  account  i: 


239 

to  make  it  less  vulnerable  to  political  manipulation.  Under  current 
law,  the  crop  insurance  program  is  a  hostage  to  the  appropriations 
process.  If  crop  insurance  is  going  to  be  the  only  risk  protection 
program  available  to  farmers  and  ranchers,  they  must  have  the  full 
faith  and  backing  of  the  Federal  Government  by  moving  it  over  to 
the  entitlement  accounts. 

The  IBAA  supports  supplemental  products,  Mr.  Chairman.  We 
believe  that  expanded  authority  should  be  given  to  the  private  sec- 
tor to  develop  programs  and  policies  to  provide  higher  levels  of  pro- 
tection at  affordable  prices. 

One  concept  IBAA  has  endorsed  is  the  concept  of  disappearing 
deductibles  under  which  the  deductible  grows  smaller  as  losses 
grow  larger,  so  that  if  a  farmer  has  100  percent  loss,  he  or  she 
would  receive  100  percent  indemnity. 

Another  idea  is  converting  the  program  from  jdeld  basis  to  in- 
come basis.  Buying  dollar  coverage  per  acre  is  a  concept  easily  un- 
derstood by  both  the  producers  and  the  lenders,  and  it  provides  an 
insured  catastrophe  in  which  credit  could  be  easily  assessed. 

In  conclusion,  the  administration's  crop  insurance  program  will 
take  the  public/private  partnership  that  already  exists  and 
strengthen  it  to  the  benefit  of  our  Nation's  farmers  and  ranchers 
and  the  communities  they  serve.  In  the  process,  it  will  save  tax- 
payers over  $750  million  over  5  years.  That  would  be  hard  to  beat. 

We  hope  that  you  will  take  advantage  of  this  opportunity  to  pro- 
vide long-term  protection  to  American  agriculture,  including  farm- 
ers, ranchers,  lenders,  agribusiness,  and  Main  Street  America  shop 
owners  by  approving  the  administration's  crop  insurance  reform 
proposal. 

Thank  you  again,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  the  opportunity  to  testify  on 
behalf  of  our  Nation's  community  bankers.  I  would  be  happy  to  re- 
spond to  any  questions  you  may  have. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Hart  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Hart. 

We  will  proceed  next  to  Mr.  Merja. 

STATEMENT  OF  CHUCK  MERJA,  SECRETARY/TREASURER, 
NATIONAL  ASSOCIATION  OF  WHEAT  GROWERS 

Mr.  Merja.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

My  name  is  Chuck  Merja,  and  I  am  from  Sun  River,  Montana. 

We,  on  our  farm,  have  utilized  crop  insurance  since  well  before 
the  last  reform  in  the  early  1980's.  We  raise  wheat  and  barley. 

I  want  to  thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to  present  our  views 
today  to  the  subcommittee.  I  am  serving  as  secretary/treasurer  of 
the  National  Association  of  Wheat  Growers.  That  association  has 
felt  that  a  Federal  crop  insurance  program  that  was  revised  and 
workable  has  been  a  long-time  goal  of  our  association,  and  we  sup- 
port the  reform  proposal  contained  in  the  administration's  1995 
budget  request. 

I  would  remind  you,  55  years  ago  the  first  commodity  covered  by 
Federal  crop  insurance  was  wheat.  We  are  familiar  with  the  ad- 
ministration's proposal  and  think  that  it  is  a  very  good  starting 
point  for  a  viable  program. 


240 

In  standing  behind  the  fundamental  concept  that  provides  for 
low-level  catastrophic  coverage  of  all  farm  program  participants, 
we  are  taking  a  bold  step  that  many  of  us  have  previously  been  un- 
willing to  take.  But  we  think,  with  continued  budget  pressures  fac- 
ing all  Grovemment  programs  and  the  solid  policy  reasons  favoring 
an  insurance  approach  to  disaster  relief,  we  believe  the  time  is 
right  to  consider  change  to  a  single,  predictable  approach  to  disas- 
ter relief. 

The  administration's  approach  reflects  truthful  budgeting,  budget 
discipline,  and  good  public  policy,  improved  risk  management  op- 
tions for  farmers,  and  reduced  cost  for  taxpayers.  However,  the  Na- 
tional Wheat  Growers  is  unwilling  to  step  completely  away  from 
standard  disaster  authority  unless  and  until  the  program  is  proved 
to  be  effective. 

Extensive  debate  has  already  occurred  as  to  who  delivers  this 
program.  I  think  I  have  even  learned  a  little  bit  more  here  today 
about  that  from  Mr.  Diedrich. 

In  Montana  we  are  very  comfortable,  and  in  the  wheat  country 
we  are  very  comfortable  with  a  dual  delivery  system.  In  my  State 
I  would  predict  that  the  agents  would  be  the  deliverers  because  we 
have  a  fair  coverage  of  agents,  and  also  90-some  percent  of  our 
acres  are  involved  in  crop  insurance.  In  other  areas — even  in  other 
wheat  areas — that  isn't  the  case,  and  so  ASCS  may  be  a  better  de- 
livery system  in  those  areas. 

We  are  concerned  about  linkage.  We  understand  the  issue  of 
linkage,  but  we  are  concerned  that  the  costs  remain  as  they  are 
and  not  begin  to  reflect  risk  acreage  or  crops.  As  Mr.  Diedrich  said, 
if  we  change  the  program  and  continue  the  linkage,  there  is  some 
concern  that  we  will  get  tied  into  a  program  that  may  or  may  not 
be  adequate  or  something  that  we  care  to  participate  in. 

With  regard  to  new  crops,  we  understand  that  FCIC — and  would 
encourage  FCIC  within  its  limits  to  look  at  new  crops.  One  that  we 
would  suggest  is  for  seed  wheat.  We  have  many  producers  that 
raise  wheat  that  is  of  significantly  higher  value  than  current  mar- 
ket price  elections  and  are  not  able  to  insure  that  entire  risk. 

National  Wheat  Growers  participated  in  a  crop  insurance  task 
force  2  years  ago  that  recommended  the  4-year  building  to  10  ac- 
tual production  history  plan.  As  such,  we  are  supportive  of  how  the 
plan  benefits  producers  with  good  production  history  who  have 
been  blessed  with  good  production  in  the  past  few  years. 

However,  the  change  to  the  new,  more  aggressive  APH  formula 
has  not  been  without  pain.  Whether  or  not  a  reform  package  moves 
through  Congress,  the  highest  priority  for  FCIC  should  be  to  de- 
velop and  implement  an  affordable  catastrophic  yield  clause  that 
puts  the  brakes  on  yield  declines  for  producers  with  multiple  cata- 
strophic losses. 

I  would  just  point  out  that  in  1984,  1985 — since  the  reform  pack- 
age went  through,  in  1984,  1985,  1988,  and  1992,  my  particular 
county  was  declared  a  disaster  county.  I'm  still  using  those  yields 
in  my  APH  election,  even  though  we  have  recognized,  through  the 
disaster  status,  disaster  recognition,  that  those  were  significant 
anomalies  in  the  weather. 

At  the  same  time,  the  administration's  decision  to  base  cata- 
strophic yield  coverage  from  individual  APH  jdelds  as  opposed  to 


241 

counting  averages  is  a  vital  and  important  component  of  the  cur- 
rent reform  package.  Again,  whether  or  not  reform  goes  through, 
we  think  that  FCIC  should  implement  a  de  minimis  yield  clause. 
Lack  of  that  really  causes  problems  in  small  grain  country. 

We  would  also  encourage  FCIC  to  use  its  authority  to  become 
even  more  customer  oriented,  and  issues  that  would,  in  our  mind, 
come  to  the  friend  there  would  be  the  seed  wheat  policy,  the  de 
minimis  jdeld,  and  maybe  a  look  at  a  gross  revenue  insurance  of 
some  sort.  We  think  they  could  do  that  without  having  authority. 
They  already  have  authority  to  do  that. 

In  that  regard,  more  flexibility  in  the  market  price  election  would 
be  very  helpful,  too.  There  really  needs  to  be  a  better  mechanism 
to  deal  with  the  different  values  of  wheat  that  we  raise  in  this 
country. 

Thank  you  very  much.  I  would  take  any  questions. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Merja  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Merja. 

We'll  turn  next  to  Mr.  Mitchell. 

STATEMENT  OF  MYRL  MITCHELL,  CHAIRMAN,  CROP  INSUR- 
ANCE ADVISORY  TASK  FORCE,  NATIONAL  COTTON  COUNCIL 
OF  AMERICA 

Mr.  Mitchell.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

My  name  is  Myrl  Mitchell.  I'm  a  cotton  producer  and  ginner  from 
Lenorah,  Texas,  and  I  utilize  the  multiperil  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram as  a  risk  management  tool  for  my  operation. 

I  serve  as  a  member  of  the  board  of  directors  of  the  National  Cot- 
ton Council  and  as  chairman  of  its  crop  insurance  advisory  task 
force.  We  commend  you  for  holding  this  hearing. 

In  the  interest  of  time,  I  will  summarize  my  written  testimony. 

The  National  Cotton  Council  supports  the  concepts  included  in 
the  Secretary  of  Agriculture's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal.  Obvi- 
ously, the  Devil  is  in  the  details.  I  must  caution,  however,  that 
many  cotton  producers  are  skeptical  that  a  workable  crop  insur- 
ance program  can  be  developed. 

It  is  critical  that  FCIC  staff  continue  to  listen  carefully  to  reason- 
able concerns  and  develop  provisions  that  truly  make  the  crop  in- 
surance program  useful  to  all  farmers.  It  is  not  possible  to  design 
a  one-size-fits-all  policy. 

We  are  actively  working  with  other  commodity  groups  seeking 
full  funding  for  the  plan.  Without  adequate  funding,  the  new  pro- 
gram cannot  provide  improved  risk  management  for  producers. 
While  our  industry  supports  the  administration's  catastrophic  pro- 
gram as  the  principal  mechanism  for  reform,  we  also  maintain  that 
flexibility  with  different  coverage  options  is  necessary  to  increase 
participation  and  meet  specific  regional  and  crop  needs. 

Most  cotton  farmers  would  be  interested  in  the  higher  levels  of 
coverage.  In  fact,  many  irrigated  operators  are  interested  in  cov- 
erage at  95  percent  of  actual  yield.  Consequently,  we  would  support 
efforts  to  further  reduce  the  cost  of  higher  levels  of  coverage.  While 
skeptical  of  the  precedent,  producers  have  generally  accepted  the 
voluntarily  mandatory  aspect  of  the  plan,  which  requires  payment 


242 

of  a  $50  processing  fee  for  coverage  for  participating  in  farm  pro- 
grams. 

We  support  the  option  for  producers  to  buy  the  basic  level  of  cov- 
erage at  its  local  farm  service  agency  or  through  private  insurance 
agents.  We  understand  buy-up  coverage  would  only  be  available 
through  private  insurance  agents. 

Mr.  Chairman,  in  anticipation  of  action  on  crop  insurance  reform 
this  session,  the  cotton  industry  has  hosted  or  participated  in  a  se- 
ries of  meetings  throughout  the  cotton  belt  to  hear  comments  from 
producers  on  the  Secretarj^s  reform  plan.  I  participated  in  a  ses- 
sion in  Lubbock  organized  by  Mr.  Combest  and  one  in  Abilene  or- 
ganized by  Mr.  Stenholm.  FCIC  Manager  Ken  Ackerman  and  mem- 
bers of  his  staff  attended  each  meeting.  The  remainder  of  my  testi- 
mony will  focus  on  common  concern  raised  in  those  sessions. 

First,  producers  believe  that  the  program  should  include  a  cata- 
strophic yield  adjustment  when  calculating  actual  production  his- 
tories which  include  years  with  disaster  provided  their  was  a  work- 
man-like effort.  Thanks  to  encouragement  from  members  of  this 
committee,  FCIC  has  recognized  this  problem  and  has  developed  an 
actuarially  sound  proposal  that  is  under  consideration.  Upon  initial 
review  by  our  industry,  FCIC's  approach  has  merit. 

Second,  the  addition  of  a  harvest  incentive  and  a  de  minimis 
yield  would  enhance  the  operation  of  crop  insurance  in  many  areas. 
One  suggestion  would  be  to  allow  producers  to  harvest  the  crop  and 
not  count  the  production  equated  the  cost  of  harvest  against  any 
loss  for  crop  insurance  payment  purposes. 

Consideration  could  also  be  given  for  third  party  verification  on 
zero  or  disaster  yields. 

In  addition  to  improving  the  program,  harvest  incentives  benefit 
the  processing  and  marketing  industry  segment.  On  the  other 
hand,  a  reasonable  de  minimis  3deld  provision  would  help  in  areas 
which  lose  their  crop  early  in  the  season. 

Third,  there  are  optional  products  that  could  further  enhance  the 
value  of  crop  insurance  to  the  producer.  One  of  the  points  made  at 
many  of  the  regional  meetings  was  the  need  to  have  programs  that 
will  entice  producers  to  buy  up  or  offer  them  alternative  coverage. 

One  concept  particularly  interesting  to  our  industry  is  a  program 
based  on  insuring  cost  of  production.  We  have  received  encourage- 
ment from  FCIC  to  continue  to  pursue  this  approach. 

Consideration  should  also  be  given  to  premium  setting  flexibility 
on  irrigated  operations  which  constitute  lower  risk.  We  also  sup- 
port a  provision  allowing  individuals  to  transfer  actual  production 
histories  to  similarly  classed  farms  rather  than  being  assigned  an 
insured  yield  of  65  percent.  We  believe  participation  would  increase 
if  these  matters  received  attention. 

Fourth,  often  losses  in  crop  quality  are  more  economically  dev- 
astating than  production  losses.  Improvements  in  the  quzdity  ad- 
justment provisions  for  cotton  are  needed  to  make  it  more  effective. 

Fifth,  the  administration  proposal  should  address  farm  units — 
that  is  fields  and/or  sections.  While  we  realize  that  unit  coverage 
could  impact  how  the  subsidy  is  distributed,  we  maintain  that  con- 
sideration of  smaller,  better-defined  units  will  improve  the  program 
and  make  it  more  effective.  We  strongly  support  unit  coverage  be 


243 

offered  as  a  means  to  entice  producers  to  buy  up  from  the  basic  cat- 
astrophic coverage. 

For  crop  insurance  reform  to  be  successful,  credibiHty  must  be  re- 
stored to  the  program.  Abuse  of  the  program  must  be  minimized. 
FCIC  recognizes  this  HabiHty  and  is  seeking  ways  to  strengthen  its 
review.  We  support  effective  oversight  so  that  benefits  accrue  to 
those  who  deserve  it. 

Thank  you  again,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  allowing  me  to  present  tes- 
timony here  today  on  behalf  of  the  cotton  industry. 

I  would  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions  you  or  other  members 
of  the  subcommittee  might  have. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Mitchell  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Mitchell. 

We  will  turn  next  to  Ms.  Ozer, 

STATEMENT  OF  KATHERINE  OZER,  DIRECTOR,  NATIONAL 
FAMILY  FARM  COALITION 

Ms.  Ozer.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

My  name  is  Kathy  Ozer.  I'm  the  director  of  the  National  Family 
Farm  Coalition,  which  represents  39  family  farm  and  rural  advo- 
cacy organizations  around  the  country.  We  were  formed  in  1986  to 
provide  both  a  link  and  a  voice  for  family  farmers  in  the  debate 
over  Federal  farm  and  food  policy. 

I  have  testimony  in  addition  to  mine  to  submit  for  the  record 
from  two  of  our  members  groups:  Dakota  Rural  Action  in  South 
Dakota,  and  Dakota  Resource  Council  in  North  Dakota.  I  would 
ask,  if  it  is  possible,  to  leave  the  record  open  for  additional  com- 
ments. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Without  objection. 

Ms.  Ozer.  I  am  testifying  here  today  to  strongly  support  a 
change  in  the  way  Federal  Government  prepares  for  and  responds 
to  disasters  which  strike  at  the  livelihood  of  family  farmers.  Farm- 
ers need  a  farm  policy  that  works  and  a  disaster  and/or  insurance 
program  that  is  both  accessible  and  affordable. 

NFFC  supports  the  USDA  proposed  disaster  and  crop  insurance 
program  with  a  few  changes.  In  particular,  in  response  to  one  of 
your  questions,  we  support  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act 
of  1994  provision  that  would  require  catastrophic  coverage  for  par- 
ticipants in  any  USDA  farm  program. 

The  package  of  coverage  needs  to  provide  at  least  a  certain  level 
of  economic  security  for  producers  of  all  crops  in  all  regions. 

An  issue  that  has  come  up  by  many  of  the  witnesses  already 
today  is  the  whole  issue  of  the  funding  for  that  program.  We  would 
raise  that  also  as  an  issue  in  terms  of  whether  the  actual  funds  are 
an  entitlement  in  the  budget  in  exchange  for  removing  the  emer- 
gency off-budget  nature  of  current  agricultural  disaster  proposals. 

If  this  is  not  the  case,  there  is  certainly  the  risk  that  the  funds 
would  not  be  available,  which  would  undermine  this  whole  system. 

The  other  major  question  that  has  been  raised  by  our  disaster 
task  force  that  has  reviewed  the  proposal  is:  What  happens  before 
the  catastrophic  disaster  coverage  kicks  in?  Our  understanding  is 
that  private  crop  insurance  sold  through  crop  insurance  agents  or 
ASCS  would  be  available. 


V 


244 

The  critical  question,  however,  is:  At  what  price?  Our  concern  is 
the  price  to  the  farmer  struggling  to  meet  cash  flow  and  budget 
projections,  and  to  the  Federal  Government  in  the  form  of  the  sub- 
sidy payments  to  provide  the  actual  insurance  premium. 

It  is  in  this  area  that  many  of  our  farm  leaders  who  have  worked 
on  these  issues  for  many  years  have  come  up  with  a  possible  pro- 
posal that  would  help  farmers  self-insure  against  some  of  their  pos- 
sible losses.  It  would  be  through  an  expansion  or  a  revised  version 
of  the  current  farmer-owned  reserve  that  would  actually  establish 
a  level  of  a  grain  reserve  that  could  be  accessed  if  a  certain  loss 
level  was  met. 

This  is  an  issue  that  we  have  not  totally  fleshed  out,  but  our 
sense  would  be  that  when  a  farmer  had  a  certain  loss  level,  that 
could  be  accessed.  In  addition,  a  farmer  could  also  be  enrolling  in 
the  private  crop  insurance  program,  but  this  would  be  basically  at 
a  middle  level. 

We  would  ask  the  subcommittee  to  actually  look  at  some  of  the 
costs  to  the  Federal  Grovemment  of  what  the  crop  insurance  cov- 
erage and  the  return  in  terms  of  farm  income  would  be  in  that  mid- 
dle range  before  you  hit  that  50  percent  loss  level,  but  in  between 
in  sort  of  that  50  to  70  percent  range.  I  think  that  is  the  area 
where  there  are  the  most  concerns  since  that  is  the  kind  of  level 
of  loss  that  most  producers  are  incurring  with  too  frequent  regular- 
ity. 

The  other  concern  that  has  been  raised  is:  Who  actually  needs 
to  be  covered  in  this  whole  program  both  in  terms  of  disaster  cov- 
erage and  the  crop  insurance  availability?  One  of  the  issues  that 
came  up  this  past  year  and  continues  to  be  a  concern  is:  What  hap- 
pens to  fgirmers  who  have  made  a  transition  in  their  farming  prac- 
tices? What  happens  to  the  farmer  who  is  now  producing  for  a  local 
farmers'  market  and  has  lost  some  of  those  4  to  10  years  or  that 
length  of  reporting  and  is  actually  more  involved  in  the  actual  mar- 
keting of  their  product  as  opposed  to  the  wholesale  marketing? 
How  are  some  of  those  issues  addressed? 

Another  concern  relates  to  minority  farmers  who  have  histori- 
cally been  underrepresented  in  both  access  to  farm  credit  and  Fed- 
eral farm  programs.  How  do  we  ensure  that  they  do  have  access 
to  the  types  of  disaster  programs  that  we  are  looking  at? 

Another  issue  relates  to  contract  growers  who,  in  many  cases, 
have  not  been  adequately  covered  as  a  result  of  their  whole  con- 
tractual relationship  and  who  actually  own  the  Uvestock  or  the 
poultry  as  opposed  to  the  time  and  the  energy  and  the  expenses 
that  have  been  put  into  the  process? 

Those  are  some  of  the  issues  that — ^we  want  to  make  sure,  as  the 
group  representing  family  farmers,  that  those  are  some  of  the  types 
of  farmers  that,  in  fact,  are  getting  adequately  covered  by  the  pro- 
grams. 

In  my  written  summary  I  go  into  testimony  in  more  detail,  but 
one  of  our  concerns  is  that  there  were  certain  constituencies  in 
groups  of  farmers  who  did  not  get  the  kind  of  benefits  that  they 
needed  during  the  existing  dissister  program.  How  do  we  make  sure 
that  gets  corrected  in  the  new  program? 

An  issue  raised  before  had  to  do  with  some  of  the  cotton  quality 
issues.  We  would  say  that's  a  major  issue  in  terms  of  hay  quality. 


245 

What  happens  in  terms  of  the  availabUity  of  feed  for  livestock  pro- 
ducers who  have  not  themselves  incurred  a  massive  loss  but  they 
are  paying  the  price  through  their  various  other  inputs  that  they 
need? 

Another  issue  is  the  whole  availability  of  information  to  farmers 
about  the  existing  disaster  programs.  We  would  urge  the  Depart- 
ment to  be  much  more  aggressive  in  getting  that  information  out 
both  to  farmers  who  need  access  to  those  programs  and  to  their 
own  employees  who  need  to  be  disseminating  that  information  and 
being  the  on-the-ground  experts  when  there  are  problems  and  is- 
sues raised. 

We  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  testify  today.  We  strongly  sup- 
port a  comprehensive  approach  to  both  disaster  and  farm  policy. 
We  will  work  in  whatever  way  we  can  to  try  and  push  for  increased 
appropriations  for  this  imp>ortant  program  and  work  through  the 
budget  process,  but  we  remain  very  concerned  about  shifting  away 
from  what  we  have  now  and  into  something  else  unless  there  is  a 
sense  that  it,  in  fact,  will  solve  many  of  the  problems  that  we  have 
in  front  of  us. 

Thanks  for  this  oppK)rtunity. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Ms.  Ozer  and  testimony  of  Dakota 
Rural  Action  and  Dakota  Resource  Council  appear  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you. 

We  will  go  next  to  Mr.  Doyle  Rahjes. 

STATEMENT  OF  DOYLE  RAHJES,  PRESmENT,  KANSAS  FARM 
BUREAU,  AND  BOARD  MEMBER,  AMERICAN  FARM  BUREAU 
FEDERATION 

Mr.  Rahjes.  Thank  you,  Mr,  Chairman. 

I  am  Doyle  Rahjes.  I  am  the  president  of  the  Kansas  Farm  Bu- 
reau and  on  the  board  of  directors  of  the  American  Farm  Bureau 
Federation,  and  I  am  a  producer  from  Agra  Kansas. 

I  certainly  want  to  thank  you  and  the  members  of  this  sub- 
committee for  the  opportunity  for  us  to  be  here  today  and  what  you 
have  done  previous  to  this  in  getting  the  information  together  for 
you  to  move  forward  in  this  very,  very  important  area. 

I  would  like  to  begin  by  indicating  to  you  that  we  generally  sup- 
port this  proposal  as  set  forth  in  H.R.  4217.  We  have  prefiled  our 
statement,  and  I'm  not  going  to  read  the  statement.  I'm  going  to 
make  a  few  comments  and,  of  course,  be  ready  for  questions  if  need 
be. 

I  would  want  to  tell  you  that  in  our  last  annual  meeting,  which 
was  held  in  January  of  this  year  in  Fort  Lauderdale — ^that's  the 
American  Farm  Bureau  Federation — ^we  continued  to  affirm  our  po- 
sition that  both  the  disaster  program  and  the  Federal  crop  insur- 
Eince  program  should  be  put  together.  I  think  this  leads  me  to  a 
conmient  that  I  would  maJte  regarding  whether  or  not  farmers  are 
going  to  accept  it  or  not. 

First  of  all,  actuarial  soundness  is  extremely  imjwrtant  for  this 
program  to  work.  I  was  on  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Improve- 
ment Commission  in  the  late  1980's,  and  certainly  this  is  one  of  the 
things  that  came  up  through  that  commission.  We  still  have  not 
been  able  to  achieve  it. 


246  1 

But  let  me  say  that  if  the  signal  is  sent  by  Congress  to  the  Amer-  j 
ican  public — specifically,  to  farmers  and  ranchers — ^that  this  is  a  ; 
budget  item,  and  that  there  is  not  going  to  be  an  outside-the-budg-  j 
et  appropriation  for  disaster,  the  farmers  will  hear  it.  They  will  | 
hear. 

There  is  going  to  be  some  action  by  the  Congress  when  a  disaster  j 
occurs,  and  then  whether  there  is  an  off-budget  appropriations  that  i 
will  be  made  for  disaster,  and  then,  in  fact,  that  it  is  denied,  then  i 
the  farmers  will  believe  it.  I  think  that's  a  p>oint  that  we  need  to  I 
remember  as  we  look  at  the  success  of  this  program  which  we  i 
think  should  be  actuarially  sound. 

We  do  have  a  few  reservations  about  the  program  that  I  would  \ 
like  to  mention  to  you.  Most  of  them  are  around  the  eligibility  \ 
tests.  We  are  concerned  that  basically  they  may  be  unnecessary. 

First  of  all,  we  believe  that  the  program  should  be  voluntary.  The  i 
reason:  If  it  is  voluntary,  then  you  are  going  to  have  people  partici-  j 
pating  in  a  program  that  they  feel  good  about. 

And  £is  we  think  about  the  linkage  that  is  tied  to  Farmers  Home,  | 
Federal  crop,  and  other  price  support  programs,  we  feel  that  this 
is  a  tjrpe  of  coercion  that  certainly  will  not  help  the  program  to  be- 
come actuarially  sound.  The  participation  will  not  be  there  unless 
absolutely  forced,  and  we  just  don't  believe  that  is  in  order. 

Means  testing  is  unattractive  at  any  level.  The  $2  million  means 
test  sounds  big,  and  it  is,  but  I  would  remind  the  committee — and 
many  of  you  will  remember — ^that  the  $100,000  means  test  was 
tried  in  the  previous  farm  bill,  and  there  was  a  lot  of  difficulty  with 
it. 

I  just  indicate  to  you  that  it  is  going  to  create  an  area  that  i>eople 
are  going  to  be  concerned  about,  and  when  they  look  for  budget 
cutting  and  that  sort  of  thing,  that  would  be  a  place  to  look.  So 
means  testing  certainly  is  not  attractive. 

Pa5anent  limitations  are  troublesome  when  we  think  about  the 
$100,000  limitation.  Certainly  that  could,  in  the  minds  of  some — 
when  you  look  at  a  tremendous  disaster  progrsim  that  comes  across 
this  country,  $100,000  may  not  be  enough.  So  that  could  at  least 
crack  the  door  open  for  an  off-budget  type  of  appropriation,  and 
therefore  create  the  old  problem  again  that  participation  really  is 
not  necessary  in  this  program. 

I  think  there  are  otner  areas  that  we  look  at — ^reliance  on  a  yield 
ELS  opposed  to  a  dollar  basis  for  pay-outs.  There  is  no  question  that 
this  can  skew  the  program  to  the  lesser  productive  acres,  and  we 
believe  that  if  you  would  go  on  a  dollar  baisis  that  this  certainly 
would  take  that  out  of  the  picture  and  it  would  not  be  a  temptation 
to  use  those  under-productive  acres. 

Another  area  that  we  would  mention,  which  has  been  brought  up" 
by  the  member  of  your  committee  from  Florida — just  as  a  technical 
observation — specialty  crops  certainly  do  need  to  be  considered,  es- 
pecially as  it  relates  to  those  crops  which  may  not  produce  in  one 
year,  and  also  those  crops  that  may  produce  severaJ  harvests  in  one 
year. 

With  that,  Mr.  Chairman,  I  would  stand  for  questions. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Rahjes  api)ears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Rahjes. 


247 

Joining  us  today  in  lieu  of  Mr.  Swenson  is  Ms.  Nancy  Danielson, 
who  is  a  legislative  analyst  at  the  National  Farmers  Union. 

STATEMENT  OF  LELAND  SWENSON,  PRESIDENT,  PRESENTED 
BY  NANCY  F.  DANIELSON,  LEGISLATIVE  ANALYST,  NATIONAL 
FARMERS  UNION 

Ms.  Danielson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  don't  apologize  for  who  I  am,  but  I  am  sorry  that  Lee  Swenson 
couldn't  be  here  this  morning.  He  was  hoping  to  be  able  to  testify 
himself. 

I  am  a  lifelong  member  of  the  National  Farmers  Union,  and  I  am 
here  to  tell  you  that  we  are  generally  very  supportive  of  the  provi- 
sions of  H.R.  4217. 

The  testimony  today  will  address  10  issues:  Repeal  of  the  ad  hoc 
disaster,  establishment  of  catastrophic  coverage,  linkage  to  farm 
programs,  the  delivery  system,  industry  competition,  assistance  for 
uninsurable  crops,  actuarial  soundness,  budget  authority,  adequacy 
of  higher  levels,  and  the  advisory  committee  created  by  this  legisla- 
tion. 

First  of  all,  we  are  generally  supportive  of  the  repeal  of  ad  hoc 
disaster  but,  like  Mr.  Diedrich,  we  would  condition  that  on  the  fact 
that  catastrophic  coverage  remain  at  £in  affordable  price.  We  also 
suggest,  as  the  bill  does,  to  keep  the  authority  for  uninsurable 
crops. 

Second,  as  to  the  adequacy  of  catastrophic  coverage,  we  like  the 
fact  that  this  bill  allows  producers  to  choose  between  using  APH 
or  using  area  yield.  We  would  like  to  go  one  step  further  and  re- 
quire that  both  are  offered.  As  is  currently  in  the  bill,  it  says  the 
producer  may  choose  as  long  as  both  are  offered,  but  we  would  like 
to  require  that  both  be  offered. 

Like  Mr.  Merja,  we  would  like  to  have  disaster  declared  years  ex- 
cluded from  APH. 

We  would  also  like  to  make  one  additional  improvement.  We 
would  like  the  price  election  to  be  up  to  100  percent  of  the  expected 
market  price  rather  than  60  percent  of  the  expected  market  price. 
We  feel  that  if  the  coverage  is  too  low,  it  won't  actually  meet  the 
goal  of  obviating  the  need  for  disaster  assistance. 

I  guess  one  additional  question  that  I  had  that  is  not  in  our  testi- 
mony is  the  question  as  to  whether  or  not  catastrophic  assistance 
will  be  available  even  if  only  one  producer  in  a  county  suffers  a  dis- 
aster. I  would  hope  that  it  would  be  available. 

The  third  issue,  linkage  to  the  farm  programs:  You  will  note  in 
the  special  order  of  business  that  we  have  attached  to  our  testi- 
mony that  our  delegates  at  our  national  convention  supported  hav- 
ing it  as  a  benefit  of  farm  program  participation,  and  they  even 
went  as  far  as  to  support  requiring  the  catastrophic  level.  But, 
again,  they  would  be  supportive  as  long  as  the  cost  of  participation 
is  limited  to  the  currently  proposed  $50  per  crop  per  county,  with 
a  cap  of  $100  per  producer  per  county. 

Four,  as  to  the  delivery  system,  the  question  of  dual  delivery 
raises  some  additional  issues.  First  of  all,  who  will  do  the  adjust- 
ing? Who  will  pay  the  administrative  cost  if  the  producer  first  ob- 
tains coverage  from  the  farm  service  agency  and  then  goes  on  to 
the  private  agent? 


248 

We  also  support  waiving  the  administrative  fee  for  those  who! 
sign  up  for  coverage  greater  than  the  catastrophic  level.  We  believe 
it  is  very  important  to  encourage  producers  to  sign  up  for  a  level 
of  coverage  greater  than  that  catastrophic  level. 

Five,  we  support  the  provision  which  allows  industry  competi- 
tion. We  like  the  fact  that  insurance  companies  are  allowed  to  offer 
up  to  85  percent  of  APH  or  95  percent  of  area  yield.  We  think  this 
more  closely  approaches  the  cost  of  production,  and  we  think  that's 
a  very  positive  inclusion. 

Six,  we  do  support  providing  a  permanent  disaster  program  for 
uninsurable  crops  or  crops  where  the  catastrophic  level  is  not  avail- 
able. But  we  think  that  you  should  require  that  a  crop  have  some 
history  on  land  before  it  can  be  insured.  What  this  will  do  is  pre- 
vent a  farmer  from  speculating  on  some  new  crop  that  has  never 
been  grown  on  that  land  before,  with  the  knowledge  that  they  can 
always  receive  crop  insurance.  We  believe  this  will  add  actuarial 
soundness  to  the  program. 

We  support  the  goal  of  approaching  actuarial  soundness,  and  we 
believe  using  APH  will  really  help  out  in  achieving  that  goal. 

We  certainly  hope  that  the  budget  authority  will  be  granted  as 
requested  by  the  administration,  and  we  would  point  out  that 
would  achieve  savings  of  $750  million  up  to  $1  billion  over  a  5-year 
period. 

As  to  the  adequacy  of  higher  levels  of  coverage,  we  support  allow- 
ing producers  to  choose  up  to  65,  75,  and  80  percent  levels  of  cov- 
erage, and  we  recommend  that  a  premium  subsidy  is  offered  to  en- 
courage producers  to  choose  these  higher  levels.  I  don't  believe 
that's  in  the  current  bill,  and  we  hope  that  will  be  added. 

We  like  the  fact  that  loss  of  yield  and  preventive  planning  is  cov- 
ered. We  would  like  to  add  quality  loss  coverage,  and  we  would  also 
point  out  that  separate  units  are  important.  For  example,  dry  land 
wheat  should  not  be  treated  the  same  as  irrigated  wheat  in  looking 
at  yield  coverage. 

We  support  the  addition  of  a  Federal  advisory  committee,  but  we 
would  like  to  ask  that  at  least  one-half  of  those  people  on  the  board 
be  family  farmers. 

In  summary,  I'd  like  to  say  that  I  think  this  bill  might  be  suc- 
cessful for  the  very  example  that  our  president  from  the  Minnesota 
Farmers  Union  gave.  He  pointed  out  that  even  though  he  tradition- 
ally buys  a  low  level  of  catastrophic  crop  insurance  program,  he 
has  never  been  able  to  collect  on  that,  even  last  year  when  he  had 
the  worst  disaster  ever.  He  thinks  the  fact  that  a  program  like  this 
will  provide  him  that  coverage,  he  can  then  use  his  additional  dol- 
lars which  he  would  have  spent  on  the  low-level  coverage  to  buy 
up. 

If  there  are  other  producers  in  the  midwest  where  participation 
is  traditionally  lower  that  have  the  same  feeling,  then  I  believe 
your  will  be  very  successful  in  getting  the  widespread  participation. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Swenson  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you. 

I  want  to  thank  all  the  members  of  this  panel.  I  think  your  in- 
sights are  very  helpful  to  the  committee. 


249 

Let  me  just  ask  a  question  to  those  of  you  who  may  choose  to 
respond. 

All  of  us  would  like  to  have  as  much  premium  subsidy  as  pos- 
sible for  the  buy-up,  because  I  think  we  all  agree  that  in  most 
cases  catastrophic  coverage  is  not  going  to  be  entirely  adequate. 

On  the  other  hand,  there  is  a  possibility  that  we  may  not  have 
the  money  to  utilize  that  the  administration  has  requested.  We 
may  come  in  with  less  money  than  what  the  White  House  wants, 
what  Mr.  Espy  wants. 

If  something  had  to  give,  would  you  recover  that  financial  short- 
age by  reducing  the  level  of  the  catastrophic  coverage  and  retaining 
a  partial  subsidy  for  the  higher  coverage?  Or  would  you  use  the 
money  first  of  all  to  make  sure  that  50  percent  catastrophic  cov- 
erage is,  in  fact,  provided  and  pare  away  some  of  the  subsidy  for 
the  buy-up? 

It  is  a  choice  no  one  wants  to  have  to  make,  but  if  you  were  con- 
fronted with  that  kind  of  choice,  I  wonder  if  any  of  you  have  any 
comments  or  if  it  is  too  awful  a  possibility  to  even  consider. 

Mr.  Merja.  Mr.  Chairman,  at  first  glance  I  would  ask  you  to 
keep  the  money  in  the  buy-up  instead  of  in  the  catastrophic  cov- 
erage for  the  reason  that  people  still  are  going  to  need  to  make 
management  decisions,  and  they  can  choose  to  make  those  manage- 
ment decisions  after  the  catastrophic  coverage  is  there  and  so  mini- 
mize the  money  in  the  catastrophic  coverage  and  put  the  money 
where  people  are  already  using  the  crop  insurance. 

Ms.  OzER.  I  would  have  to  disagree  because  it  seems  like  if  the 
money  isn't  there  we  won't  have  an  adequate  catastrophic  program, 
so  we  have  to  figure  out  what  is  that.  If  the  alternative  is  removing 
the  ad  hoc  disaster  situation,  we  could  be  caught  in  a  very  precar- 
ious situation  of  many  farmers  having  neither  access  if  they  have 
a  major  disaster  nor  having  any  catastrophic  coverage  if,  in  fact, 
the  premium  levels  are  so  high. 

I  think  we  have  to  be  clear  about  the  base  and  establish  the  cata- 
strophic level.  That's  where  our  farmers,  in  looking  at  this  pro- 
posal, came  up  with  this  idea  of  some  kind  of  grain  reserve  or  some 
kind  of  self  insurance  that  maybe  would  cost  less  than  the  pre- 
mium payments. 

It  is  something  that  is  just  a  concept  and  we  need  to  do  a  lot  of 
work  on,  but  I  think  the  sense  is  there  needs  to  be  some  different 
options,  and  we  don't  want  to  be  in  a  position  that  if  the  buy-up 
insurance  is  too  expensive  it  is  not  going  to  be  accessible,  just  like 
the  current  system.  But,  on  the  other  hand,  you  want  to  have 
something  when  you've  got  a  very  catastrophic  situation  or  we'd  be 
in  very  dire  straits. 

Ms.  Danielson.  Mr.  Chairman,  Farmers  Union  would  also  sup- 
port keeping  the  money  at  the  catastrophic  level.  I  was  also  very 
interested  this  morning  in  the  comment  made  by  Mr.  Ewing  to  sug- 
gest that  perhaps  you  should  allow  farmers  to  choose  using  a  40 
percent  deductible  and  then  getting  a  40  percent  payout  instead  of 
having  a  50  percent  deductible  and  getting  a  60  percent  payout  be- 
cause many  people  live  in  areas  where  having  a  50  percent  deduct- 
ible means  that  they  will  never  collect. 

Mr.  Rahjes.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  would  respond  like  this:  Let's  not 
lose  sight  of  the  target.  The  target  is  to  become  actuarially  sound 


250 

in  this  program.  The  balance  is  critical.  If  we  use  too  much  in  the 
catastrophic  area,  then  we  wind  up  not  being  able  in  the  other  area 
to  keep  the  balance. 

As  we  look  at  the  disaster  program  as  we  have  seen  it  in  the 
past,  and  as  we  look  at  the  number  of  dollars  that  have  been  used, 
a  critical  balance  has  to  be  there.  There  is  no  question  that  the  cat- 
astrophic program  is  very  important  to  participation,  but  at  the 
same  time  I  think  that  our  moneys  can  be  used  again  by  giving  the 
producer  options — and  as  many  options  as  you  possibly  can — to 
allow  them  to  place  that  where  they  want  to  use  it. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  appreciate  your  insights  on  this.  Obviously,  opin- 
ions differ.  We  are  sort  of  talking  about  an  abstract  issue  here  be- 
cause we  don't  have  a  dollar  amount,  and  obviously  we'd  have  to 
have  the  CBO  number  crunchers  work  to  see  what  kind  of  menu 
of  options  we  would  have  before  us.  It  may  be  a  little  bit  of  a  com- 
bination of  both.  It  is  hard  to  know,  but  I  appreciate  your  insights 
on  that. 

I  also  appreciate  your  observations  on  crop  quality.  I  am  re- 
minded a  little  bit  of  the  health  care  debate,  however,  where  there 
is  no  end  of  things  that  we  would  all  like  to  see  in  the  minimum 
level  of  coverage  but,  again,  it  is  going  to  be  partially  budget  driv- 
en. It  is  going  to  come  down  to  how  much  money  we  have  got  to 
use. 

I  think  those  points  are  well  taken. 

Mr.  Ewing,  any  questions  or  comments? 

Mr.  Ewing.  One  comment  to  Mr.  Rahjes.  I  know  that  you  are 
from  the  district  of  our  ranking  minority  member,  Pat  Roberts,  and 
he  asked  me  to  specifically  give  you  his  best  regards  and  his  apolo- 
gies for  not  being  able  to  be  here  today  for  your  testimony. 

The  other  point  that  I  would  like  to  make — and  it  really  isn't  a 
question,  just  a  point.  I  have  raised  the  issue  about  changing  or 
giving  options  in  the  catastrophic  coverage,  whether  you  have  50 
percent  coverage  with  60  payout  or  have  a  60  percent  coverage  and 
pay  out  at  a  lesser  level.  We  are  not  trying  to  change  the  financial 
requirements,  because  we  know  the  USDA  has  their  problems  with 
that,  but  they  have  run  some  figure  which  tell  us  that  it  may  not 
be  any  more  expensive  to  have  this  option. 

I  would  like  all  of  you  to  consider  that  and  possibly  submit  addi- 
tional information,  if  you  choose,  to  the  committee  indicating  how 
you  feel  about  that,  because  I  think  there  are  places  in  the  country 
that  could  be  very  beneficial  and  could  be  attractive  to  more  pro- 
ducers. 

Thank  you. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Mr.  Sarpalius. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I'd  like  to  commend  our  guests  today  on  the  testimony  that  they 
gave. 

This  is  a  difficult  issue  in  trying  to,  as  the  chairman  mentioned, 
determine  quality  of  crops.  Some  of  you  are  talking  about  the  prob- 
lems of  irrigation  farmers  versus  dry  land  farmers.  You  also  have 
the  problem  of  areas  where  you  do  have  droughts,  and  also  areas 
where  you  have  a  lot  of  hail.  A  lot  of  areas  of  the  country  don't 
have  much  hail.  In  my  area  we  do.  Some  of  my  farmers  think  this 


251 

is  a  real  bargain  just  from  the  standpoint  of  being  able  to  cover 
their  crops  from  hail  damage. 

All  of  you — not  all  of  you,  but  most  of  you  talked  about  the  cost 
of  production  versus  yields,  concern  about  if  we  do  base  it  on  yields, 
how  does  that  affect  a  producer's  average  5delds.  That,  to  me,  is  a 
real  dilemma  that  we  have  got  to  try  to  get  a  real  answer  to. 

I  wanted  to  ask,  first  of  all,  Mr.  Hart — in  your  testimony  you 
talked  about  real  concern  about  ASCS  being  involved  in  the  pro- 
gram. You  commented  about  how  you  felt  like  they  would  put  this 
program  kind  of  at  the  bottom  of  the  list  because  of  their  work 
load.  I  would  like  for  you  to  elaborate  a  little  more  on  that.  If  we 
did  include  ASCS  more  actively  involved  in  this  program,  what  is 
the  answer?  Are  we  looking  at  additional  staff,  or  what? 

Mr.  Hart.  Well,  are  these  people  trained,  first  of  all,  to  basically 
sell  the  farmer?  They  come  in  and  they  sign  up  for  the  basic  cov- 
erage, but  are  they  going  to  be  trained  enough  to  sell  them  on 
maybe  they  should  go  talk  to  the  insurance  agent  across  the  street 
about  increasing  their  coverage?  Are  they  going  to  want  to  take  the 
time  to  do  it? 

Sure,  maybe  it  is  part  of  their  job  definition  or  job  description, 
but  how  much  time  and  effort  are  they  going  to  put  into  it?  You 
are  going  to  have  to  train  the  people  because  they  are  going  to 
have  a  lot  of  questions.  If  they  are  going  to  try  to  get  the  farmer 
to  buy  more  coverage  from  the  insurance  agent,  the  farmers  are 
going  to  ask  that  ASCS  employee  questions.  They  need  to  be 
trained  enough  to  answer  them.  This  is  going  to  take  more  time. 

One  of  the  things  I  think  is  going  to  be  put  on  the  back  burner — 
I  think  this  program  has  been  tried  once  before,  and  I  think  the 
ASCS  tried  to  present  an  insurance  program  and  it  didn't  work 
very  well  at  all.  The  people  just  didn't  have  any  interest  and  didn't 
have  any  incentive  to  sell  it.  It  was  one  of  those  extra  duties  that 
they  had  to  do,  and  they  did  it  when  they  had  time  and  they 
thought  about  it. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  From  an  individual  who  is  here  speaking  for 
many  banks  across  the  country,  do  you  see  this  program  as  one 
that  would  discourage  banks  from  giving  loans  or  encouraging 
them  for  giving  loans  and  protecting  their  investment? 

Mr.  Hart.  I  think  it  would  encourage  them,  because,  like  I  said 
in  my  statement,  we  know  that  these  people  have  the  insurance, 
have  the  money  in  place.  Personally,  I  feel  we  should  go  to  a  cost 
basis  rather  than  a  production  basis  so  maybe  the  cash  flow — they 
know  what  they  have  to  have  to  come  back  to  make  their  cost  of 
production.  We  feel  more  comfortable  making  the  loan,  and  I  think 
the  farmer  should  feel  more  comfortable  in  purchasing  it.  He  knows 
he  is  going  to  get  so  much  return.  And  it  might  encourage  him  to 
look  at  the  program  a  little  closer. 

I'd  make  one  other  comment.  Chairman  Johnson  asked  about 
where  we  should  put  the  money.  I  believe  it  should  be  left  in  the 
catastrophic  program  to  encourage  people  to  sign  up  for  it.  Maybe 
in  future  years  you  could  take  the  money  and  wean  it  out.  As  more 
people  get  more  religion  or  believe  in  the  program,  they  are  going 
to  find  out  the  disaster  program  is  a  thing  in  the  past.  As  more 
people  start  utilizing  the  program,  maybe  you  can  change  the  flow 
of  money  around  a  little  bit.  But  I  think  right  now  we  should  en- 


81-128  0-94-9 


252 

courage  as  many  people  as  we  can  to  take  the  program  and  sign 
up  for  it. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  That  brings  another  issue — mandatory  coverage. 
Some  of  you  testified  against  that.  How  else  are  you  going  to  have 
broad  participation  unless  you  have  mandatory  coverage? 

Mr.  Hart.  I  think  if  a  person  expects  something  and  is  using  the 
various  Government  programs,  he  should  have  some  protection. 
The  Government  should  have  protections.  In  fact,  all  the  farmers 
should  protect  themselves.  We  won't  lend  money  to  a  person  to  buy 
a  house  unless  he  has  house  insurance.  We  won't  lend  money  to  a 
person  to  buy  a  car  unless  he  has  car  insurance.  If  the  Federal 
Government  is  going  to  subsidize  these  people  in  some  way,  the 
Government  should  have  some  protection  and  the  farmers  should 
be  willing  to  take  that  protection. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  Would  Einybody  else  Uke  to  comment? 

Mr.  Mitchell.  If  I  may,  I  reside  just  a  little  ways  south  of  where 
you  live,  and  adversity  will  cause  people — and  I'm  not  advocating 
adversity,  but  if  you  think  that  you  want  to  be  standing  up  ready 
to  take  out  Federal  crop  insurance,  that  adversity  hits  you  a  year 
or  two — I  know,  because  I've  got  friends  in  the  cotton  industry  that 
said  it  won't  work  for  us.  But,  unfortunately,  a  year  or  two  of  ad- 
verse weather — I'm  talking  about  natural  disasters — and  they  are 
ready  to  take  it  out. 

As  I  said,  I'm  not  advocating  anybody  having  adverse  weather, 
but  it  will  put  people  in  line  to  buy  the  insurance. 

Ms.  OZER.  We  would  agree  that  there  needs  to  be  mandatory  par- 
ticipation. I  would  just  say  that  in  terms  of  reorganization  and  the 
whole  farm  services  agency,  we  would  hope  that  there  would  be  the 
kind  of  training  that  would  be  clear  with  folks  working  with  ASCS 
that  we  are  talking  about  the  catastrophic  portion. 

Part  of  the  job  may  be  to  be  clear  that  the  other  pieces  are  avail- 
able, but  it  won't  be  the  job  of  the  ASCS  employee  to  be  promoting. 
It  would  be  the  job  of  making  sure  that  people  know  that  it  is 
available.  The  crop  insurance  industry  I'm  sure  will  continue  to 
promote  its  availability.  But  adequate  training  is  essential. 

Mr.  Rahjes.  If  I  may  respond  with  regard  to  the  mandatory  ver- 
sus voluntary.  I  spoke  of  options  before  and  the  option  level  being 
there  within  the  program,  itself,  as  presented. 

It  is  pretty  obvious  that  those  who  may  not  want  to  participate 
to  begin  with  will  be  much  more  apt  to  want  to  participate  if  they 
can  have  the  choice  of  where  they  want  to  place  their  money,  even 
if  it  is  subsidy,  if  they  can  control  where  the  coverage  and  the  em- 
phasis on  the  coverage  they  want. 

There  is  no  question  that  the  catastrophic  coverage  is  very,  very 
important — nobody  is  doubting  that — ^but  give  the  farmer  the  op- 
tion where  he  wants  to  put  it. 

Mr.  Burns.  Congressman,  I  would  concur  that  mandatory  par- 
ticipation is  probably  a  good  concept  as  a  part  of  this  legislation, 
partly  because  it  is  such  a  minimum  cost  when  we  are  talking 
about  $50  per  crop  per  county  with  a  maximum  of  $100  per  pro- 
ducer. As  a  lender,  I  don't  know  of  any  customers  that  we  have 
that  would  opt  out  of  the  program  because  of  the  cost. 

I  think  it  would  tend  to  encourage  broad  participation,  particu- 
larly in  buy-up  insurance  that  might  come  after  the  basic  coverage. 


253 

which  would  help  make  it  actuarially  sound,  which  is  an  important 
part  of  the  success  of  the  entire  program. 

Mr.  Sarpalius.  My  time  is  out,  but  there  are  a  lot  of  gray  areas 
within  this  plan,  but  I  really  think  we  are  finally,  for  once,  begin- 
ning to  get  more  of  a  consensus  than  I  have  ever  seen  since  I  have 
been  on  this  committee.  But  there  are  a  lot  of  unanswered  ques- 
tions like  the  buy-up — how  much  is  it  going  to  cost? — and  the  prob- 
lems we  discussed  on  the  cost  of  production  versus  average  jdelds. 

I  commend  the  chairman  of  this  committee,  and  I  am  convinced 
that  we  will  eventually  reach  a  consensus. 

I  thank  each  one  of  you  for  your  testimony. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Just  so  that  there  is  no  confusion,  the  Chair  would 
clarify  things  a  bit  hopefully. 

As  the  crop  insurance  reform  bill  stands,  it  would  not  cover  hail 
loss  per  se.  The  hail  industry  remains  in  place.  But  it  would  cover 
other  kinds  of  disasters.  The  design  of  the  plan  is  to  assure  every 
farmer  of  roughly  the  equivalent  of  the  kind  of  disaster  payment 
they  now  get  in  years  that  we  do  ad  hoc  disaster  bills.  That  hadn't 
been  said. 

Mr.  Peterson. 

Mr.  Peterson.  I  came  in  late  and  I'll  forego  any  questions.  I 
might  plow  some  ground  that  you  have  already  plowed.  I  got  a  lot 
of  my  questions  asked  in  Minnesota. 

Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  And  I  thank  the  gentleman  from  Min- 
nesota for  coming  down  from  his  district  to  attend  the  field  hearing 
we  had  in  Representative  Minge's  district. 

I  thank  the  members  of  this  panel.  I  think  it  was  a  very  good 
discussion. 

I  think  everybody  would  just  as  soon  avoid  mandatory  anything 
where  possible;  however,  in  this  case  it  is  sort  of  good  news/bad 
news.  The  bad  news  is  it  is  mandatory,  the  good  news  is  it  is  free. 
There  probably  will  be  more  contentious  issues  than  that  that  we 
will  be  dealing  with. 

Thank  you  agEiin  for  your  participation  in  this  panel. 

The  last  panel  is  comprised  of:  Mr.  Michael  Connealy,  Rural 
Community  Insurance  Services  of  Anoka,  Minnesota;  Mr.  John  H. 
Joyce,  who  is  chairman  of  the  American  Association  of  Crop  Insur- 
ers and  president,  Rain  and  Hail  Insurance  Service,  Inc.,  of  West 
Des  Moines,  Iowa,  and  he  is  accompanied  by  Mr.  Robert  W.  Post, 
Jr.,  vice  chairman  of  American  Association  of  Crop  Insurers,  and 
president  of  Domberger/Berry  &  Co.  of  Sioux  Falls,  South  Dakota; 
Mr.  Robert  Parkerson,  president  of  the  National  Crop  Insurance 
Services  of  Overland  Park,  Kansas;  and  Mr.  Thomas  A.  Rudisill, 
chairman,  Crop  Insurance  Research  Bureau,  Inc.,  of  Overland 
Park,  Kzinsas,  and  manager  of  crop  insurance  and  administrative 
services,  North  Carolina  Farm  Bureau  Mutual  Insurance  Company 
in  Raleigh,  North  Carolina. 

We  welcome  all  of  you  to  this  subcommittee.  We  appreciate  your 
patience. 

Again,  we  will  abide  by  the  5-minute  rule  to  expedite  things  a 
bit,  but  feel  free  to  summarize  the  statement  or  read  the  state- 
ment— ^however  you  are  most  comfortable.  But  we  will  try  to  abide 


254 

by  that  time  limitation  in  order  to — ^we  do  have  members  with  air- 
plane flights  and  so  on  that  need  to  be  connected  with. 

Your  entire  statements,  however,  are  received  for  the  record  and 
will  be  shared  with  our  entire  staff  and  with  the  members  of  the 
committee. 

We  will  proceed  first  with  Mr.  Connealy. 

STATEMENT  OF  MICHAEL  CONNEALY  ON  BEHALF  OF  RURAL 
COMMUNITY  INSURANCE  SERVICES,  INC. 

Mr.  Connealy.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  the 
subcommittee. 

On  behalf  of  Rural  Community  Insurance  Services,  we  appreciate 
the  opportunity  to  testify  before  the  subcommittee  concerning  the 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994. 

Rural  Community  Insurance  Services  is  a  wholly-owned  subsidi- 
ary of  Norwest  Corporation,  which  is  a  bank  holding  company. 
Norwest  is  a  principal  provider  of  farm  operating  loans  in  rural 
communities,  and  also  to  businesses  that  support  rural  commu- 
nities, and  we  consider  the  crop  insurance  program  to  be  an  essen- 
tial part  of  the  fabric  of  those  communities. 

It  is  our  hope  that  a  concrete  and  meaningful  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram can  be  continued  by  Congress,  regardless  of  the  reform  act 
underway  and  the  budget  problems  that  accompany  it. 

We  do  believe  that  the  proposed  reform  act  addresses  many  of 
the  concerns  that  we  have  regarding  the  program,  and  we  do  thank 
you  for  the  invitation  and  opportunity  to  share  our  thoughts. 

We  have  submitted  for  the  written  record  the  12  issues  asked  by 
the  subcommittee.  We  won't  go  through  those  issues  one  by  one, 
other  than  we  will  comment  as  regards  the  mandatory  aspect  of 
the  program.  We  are  not  totally  opposed  to  is;  however,  we  have 
looked  at  the  possibility  of  a  waiver  of  some  nature  that  could  be 
considered  to  help  reduce  administrative  costs,  particularly  for  low 
leveraged  producers. 

We  believe  that  a  waiver  may  be  in  order  in  which  the  producer 
forfeits  any  benefits  to  any  sort  of  disaster  or  crop  insurance  dec- 
laration. I  guess,  to  use  the  words  of  Congressman  Peterson  from 
Minnesota,  they  take  a  blood  oath  not  to  accept  a  disaster  pay- 
ment. 

Our  additional  comment  specific  to  the  reform  and  also  the  con- 
ventional crop  insurance  program  are  that  of  a  lender.  Norwest  is 
unique  in  the  business  in  that  we  are  the  second  or  third  leading 
producer  of  crop  insurance  premiums  in  the  country,  and  at  the 
same  time  we  are  the  second  or  third  leading  production  source  for 
operating  loans.  Probably  across  the  country  and  certainly  in  many 
of  the  States — Minnesota,  South  Dakota,  North  Dakota,  Nebraska, 
Iowa — Norwest  is  certainly  an  operating  loan  leader  in  those 
States,  as  well  as  new  entries  into  Indiana,  Texas,  and  New  Mex- 
ico. 

The  crop  insurance  program  is  viewed  as  essential  to  the  credit- 
worthiness of  many  farmers,  and  therefore  to  those  communities. 
If  the  conventional  crop  insurance  program,  as  we  know  it  today, 
were  to  be  eliminated  or  significantly  reduced  as  a  source  of  collat- 
eral, the  availability  of  credit  would  diminish  immediately  and  the 


255 

consequences  of  each  storm  or  drought  would  be  more  adversely 
felt  in  those  rural  communities. 

We  point  out  that  this  is  especially  true  of  younger  farmers  and 
high  leveraged  farmers.  We  question  the  role  of  Government  in 
worrying  about  low  leveraged  farmers  or  wealth  farmers,  and 
where  subsidy  dollars  are  in  question  we  believe  that  they  should 
be  directed  to  those  that  are  most  in  need. 

We  throw  out  for  statistics:  In  1992,  we  recalculated  Norwest's 
national  loan  portfolio  and  found  roughly  775  million  dollars'  worth 
of  loans  which  could  be  described  as  land  loans  or  operating  loans, 
including  Farmers  Home  Administration  guaranteed  loans.  These 
loans  were  limited  to  those  made  with  the  expectations  that  pro- 
ceeds from  the  sale  of  crops  was  going  to  repay  these  loans  plus 
the  interest. 

Norwest  utilizes  a  risk  rating  method  which  scores  the  loan  from 
a  high  of  one,  which  would  be  best,  to  a  low  of  seven.  Operators 
that  are  rated  as  a  one,  a  two,  or  a  three  would  likely  not  be  ad- 
versely affected  by  the  loss  of  a  meaningful  crop  insurance  pro- 
gram. These  loans  amounted  to  $220  million,  or  roughly  28  percent 
of  the  total. 

Loans  rated  as  a  five,  a  six,  or  a  seven  would  most  likely  be 
dropped  from  the  portfolio.  These  would  include  Farmers  Home 
guaranteed  loans,  which  amounted  to  $157  million  of  the  total,  or 
20  percent. 

The  critical  areas — ^those  rated  as  four — many  of  these  also  re- 
quire crop  insurance.  They  would  be  aifected  by  either  a  higher  in- 
terest rate,  reduced  operating  line,  and  in  many  cases  no  loan  at 
all.  The  impact  on  these  50-some  percent  would  be  significant  and 
costly  to  the  borrower,  as  well  as  to  the  rural  communities  in  which 
they  live. 

Norwest's  main  interest  in  the  crop  insurance  program  has  al- 
ways been  as  an  agricultural  lender,  and  our  interest  in  the  reform 
is  also  as  a  lender.  We  do  additionally  have  strong  interest  in  the 
reform  program  that  benefits  the  risk  bearers  and  the  agents,  and 
we  are  also  interested  in  seeing  farmers  with  good  loss  histories  re- 
warded by  lower  premiums  and/or  higher  rates  of  coverage. 

Norwest — and  we  beUeve  other  agricultural  lenders — already  re- 
quires crop  insurance  to  the  vast  majority  of  those  who  have  the 
financial  need.  If  there  were  a  choice  in  the  amount  of  reform,  or 
preference  would  be  to  keep  the  conventional  program  intact — and 
also  enhanced,  since  farmers  are  already  participating  in  that 
area— before  pushing  ahead  with  a  great  deal  of  experimental  re- 
form. 

We  are  especially  cautious  of  reform  aimed  at  the  catastrophic 
level  of  coverage  because  we  see  a  limited  or  no  amount  of  addi- 
tional operating  loans  coming  into  the  market  supported  by  50  per- 
cent coverage,  60  percent  price  selection.  That  amount  of  coverage 
would  not  entice  us  to  loan  money  where  we  were  already  question- 
ing the  loan.  It  would  also  not  increase  the  line  on  those  that  we 
were  lending  money  to.  We  don't  see  it  as  a  viable  backstop  to  an 

operating  loan.  ,      „t    i.  u     i-x  j 

I  think  with  that  we'll  conclude  our  remarks.  We  have  submitted 
a  written  statement  for  the  written  record  and  would  be  happy  to 
take  questions  at  the  end  of  the  panel  discussion. 


256 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Connealy  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 
Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Connealy. 
We'll  move  next  to  Mr.  Joyce. 

STATEMENT  OF  JOHN  H.  JOYCE,  CHAIRMAN,  AMERICAN  ASSO- 
CIATION OF  CROP  INSURERS,  ACCOMPANIED  BY  ROBERT  W. 
POST,  JR.,  VICE  CHAIRMAN 

Mr.  Joyce.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  the  sub- 
committee for  the  opportunity  to  present  our  views  on  H.R.  4217, 
the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  of  1994.  These  summary  views  are 
expressed  on  behalf  of  the  American  Association  of  Crop  Insurers, 
a  voluntary  trade  membership  association  of  the  private  crop  insur- 
ance industry.  Our  members  represent  approximately  60  percent  of 
the  multiple  peril  premium  written  in  the  United  States. 

We  find  ourselves  presented  with  perhaps  the  greatest  oppor- 
tunity to  improve  the  crop  insurance  program.  At  no  time  have  we 
seen  such  a  consensus  for  reform  or  apparent  willingness  to  merge 
the  ad  hoc  disaster  payment  approach  into  an  improved  crop  insur- 
ance program. 

No  matter  what  legislation  is  passed  by  Congress,  a  reformed 
crop  insurgmce  program  can  only  reach  its  objective  if  there  is  a 
complete  new  mindset  on  all  facets  of  the  program  on  the  part  of 
USDA,  FCIC,  FSA,  the  companies,  the  farmers,  and  Congress.  We 
must  focus  on  a  greatly  simplified  program,  both  for  catastrophic 
coverage  and  additional  coverages  that  will  be  available. 

Overall,  we  believe  that  at  least  a  one-third  reduction  in  admin- 
istrative requirements  to  the  crop  insurance  program  could  be 
achieved  without  adversely  affecting  the  program.  At  the  same 
time,  we  are  working  cooperatively  with  the  administration  in  sup- 
port of  this  program,  we  have  been  presented  with  a  draft  reinsur- 
ance agreement  that  adds  many  new  costly  programs  that  we  can- 
not see  any  benefit  to  either  the  farmer  or  to  anyone  in  the  pro- 
gram. 

These  requirements  would  amount  to  almost  some  additional  un- 
funded mandates,  which  I  think  this  committee  and  Congress  has 
heard  many  times  before.  Unless  USDA,  FCIC,  and  the  industry 
are  willing  to  work  on  completely  reevaluating  the  need  and  exist- 
ence of  all  current  administrative  burdens,  neither  the  current  pro- 
gram nor  a  reformed  program  can  be  delivered  effectively. 

The  objective  of  any  crop  insurance  program  must  be  the  provi- 
sion of  incentives  and  opportunities  for  farmers  that  permit  them 
to  adequately  and  affordably  manage  their  production  risk.  In 
achieving  that  chief  objective,  universal  availability  of  a  cata- 
strophic coverage  at  little  or  no  charge  will  not  be  sufficient. 

Only  through  significant  involvement  of  private  industry  can  we 
expect  to  deliver  crop  insurance  and  to  add  the  additional  cov- 
erages necessary  to  meet  the  needs.  The  administration's  reform 
proposal  deserves  positive  consideration  by  budget,  appropriations, 
and  agricultural  committees.  However,  in  order  to  help  the  pro- 
gram achieve  its  maximum  effectiveness  we  feel  that  a  number  of 
refinements  need  to  be  made.  Three  specific  areas  of  refinement 
are  necessary:  Program  simplification,  program  delivery,  and  rea- 
sonable return  on  private  capital  invested. 


257 

It  is  vitally  important  that  whatever  simplification  measures  are 
adopted  for  the  catastrophic  level  should  also  flow  through  the  rest 
of  the  program.  Otherwise,  a  major  disincentive  for  participation  at 
higher  levels  of  coverage  will  be  created. 

The  simplification  process  would  start  by  requesting  this  commit- 
tee to  look  at  the  areas  of  the  buy-up  protection  from  the  50/60  and 
the  integration  from  that  to  whatever  the  maximum  levels  of  pro- 
tection offered  are.  Maybe  one  suggestion  might  be  to  buy  up  to — 
the  first  limited  buy-up  would  be  to  a  50/100.  That  might  be  one. 

We  also  believe  very  strongly  that  this  catastrophic  protection 
safety  net  cannot  have  any  holes  in  it  such  as  could  be  created  by 
the  nonstandard  classification  system. 

One  of  the  most  frequent  comments  about  the  crop  insurance 
program  is  that  it  doesn't  provide  enough  coverage.  While  we  have 
heard  much  discussion  and  the  legislation  would  allow  for  many 
higher  levels  of  coverage,  we  would  also  suggest  that  there  are 
other  options  such  as  disappearing  deductibles  that  could  be  offered 
by  the  program  at  a  much  reduced  price. 

Given  the  proper  incentives,  reasonable  opportunities  for  return 
on  capital  throughout  the  program,  and  appropriate  Grovemment 
backing,  USDA  and  farmers  would  be  amazed  at  the  explosion  of 
crop  insurance  products  that  could  be  developed  by  the  private  sec- 
tor to  fill  the  holes  in  these  programs.  We  applaud  the  FCIC  for 
approving  one  of  these  programs  to  date  and  look  forward  to  more. 

As  we  contemplate  adding  approximately  1.4  million  participants 
to  the  program,  the  streamlining  and  reduction  of  administrative 
burden  for  FCIC,  the  companies,  the  agents,  and  particularly  the 
farmer  participants  becomes  even  more  important.  We  believe 
there  should  be — again,  we  say  there  could  be  a  one-third  reduction 
of  administrative  requirements  without  adversely  affecting  the  pro- 
gram. 

In  the  are  of  program  delivery,  we  are  in  strong  support  of  the 
administration's  proposed  reliance  on  the  private  sector.  This  maxi- 
mizes the  impact  of  limited  Federal  dollars  and  recognizes  the  pref- 
erences and  convenience  of  farmers  in  obtaining  their  crop  insur- 
ance coverage  at  the  same  place  as  they  obtain  the  rest  of  their 
farm  insurance. 

We  also  believe  that  the  catastrophic  protection  alone  is  not  suffi- 
cient to  save  the  farm  for  most  borrowers  when  disaster  strikes. 
We  strongly  believe  that  professional  counselling  to  quantify  risks 
and  match  them  with  the  right  insurance  coverage  is  indispensable 
for  this  program  to  succeed. 

At  a  minimum,  we  strongly  suggest  that  farmers'  risk  manage- 
ment needs  could  best  be  met  if  farmers  are  required  to  visit  a  pri- 
vate agent  prior  to  being  able  to  obtain  a  catastrophic  policy  at  the 
USDA  office.  ,  - 

The  last  comment  would  be  relative  to  the  cost  of  mvolvement  oj 
a  duplicate  delivery  system  in  addition  to  crop  insurance.  We  would 
ask  the  committee  to  strongly  consider  that  option  only  on  an  as- 
needed  basis  and  allow  the  funding  that  might  be  used  in  this  area 
to  be  added  to  program  benefits. 

We  also  believe  that  the  necessity  for  administrative  expense  re- 
imbursement to  handle  this  program  is  critical.  While  many  of  the 
suggestions  as  to  the  change  in  coverage  attachment  points,  such 


258 

as  one  that  was  raised  here  this  morning  several  times  of  going  to 
60/40  rather  than  50/60 — I  think  we  have  to  balance  out  the  need 
for  coverage  and  the  need  for  options  with  the  simplicity  in  the 
costing  necessary  so  that  every  farmer  can  say  that  they  under- 
stand the  program.  This  goes  back  to  the  complexity  issue. 

There  is  also  strong  justification  for  some  type  of  expense  reim- 
bursement supplements  in  years  like  1995  if  this  program  is  passed 
when  the  industry  tries  to  undertake  a  significant  retooling  of  all 
the  operations  to  accommodate  a  reform  program. 

We  would  also  suggest  to  this  committee  that  FCIC  and  Grovern- 
ment  remember  that  you  have  some  strong  private  partners  more 
than  willing  to  go  to  bat;  however,  we  must  have  a  reasonable  re- 
turn on  capital  to  continue  to  expand  these  programs. 

In  conclusion,  we  have  a  unique  opportunity  this  year.  We  be- 
lieve the  administration  has  set  before  Congress  a  framework  for 
reform  that  will  work  if  refined  and  implemented  in  a  manner 
which  capitalizes  on  the  existing  public/private  partnership.  We 
cannot  emphasize  strongly  enough  that  the  reform  program  will 
achieve  its  objectives  if  everyone  involved  approaches  with  a  new 
mindset. 

Private  sector  will  deliver  day  in  and  day  out,  and  we  look  for- 
ward to  working  with  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  this  committee  and 
USDA  for  whatever  changes  may  be  necessary 

Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Joyce  appears  at  the  conclusion 
of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Joyce. 

Mr.  Parkerson. 

STATEMENT  OF  ROBERT  PARKERSON,  PRESIDENT,  NATIONAL 

CROP  INSURANCE  SERVICES 

Mr.  Parkerson.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  our  opportunity 
to  appear  here  today  on  behalf  of  NCIS,  which  is  National  Crop  In- 
surance Services. 

NCIS  has  been  serving  the  crop  insurance  industry  in  one  form 
or  another  since  1915.  Our  organization  continually  evolves  around 
the  needs  of  the  crop  insurers.  We  were  organized  for  primarily 
three  reasons:  One,  to  gather  and  analyze  crop  insurance  statistics 
so  that  we  could  create  the  appropriate  premium,  and  that  could 
be  developed  to  be  delivered  to  the  consumer;  also,  to  develop  a 
standard  policy  so  that  both  the  consumer  and  the  agent  under- 
stand the  product  that  is  being  sold;  and  to  deliver  loss  of  judgment 
procedures  that  are  acceptable  to  all  combined. 

I'll  make  this  brief,  since  I  see  the  writing  on  the  wall — or  the 
old  clock.  And  we  still  have  other  people  to  hear  from. 

While  we  may  not  all  agree  on  every  detail  of  the  proposal,  the 
industry  will  work  to  improve  the  package,  keeping  an  eye  on  the 
actuarial  soundness  and  the  underwriting  and  the  delivery  system. 

We  believe  that  most  all  segments — ^the  producers,  the  commod- 
ity groups,  and  the  insurance  industry — stand  strongly  behind  this 
action. 

We  feel  that  the  administration's  approach  reflects  sound  budget 
discipline  for  all,  to  include  the  taxpayer,  along  with  sound  risk 
management  for  the  American  farmer. 


259 

The  industry  has  made  a  great  deal  of  commitment  to  this  pro- 
gram over  the  last  14  years  and  would  like  to  remain,  I  believe,  a 
key  part  of  this  program.  However,  should  the  social  aspects  over- 
take sound  business  practice  and  sound  insurance  principles,  then 
I  think  the  industry  would  have  to  look  at  some  of  this  proposal. 

We  have  submitted  a  statement  in  writing,  Mr.  Chairman,  and 
I  will  leave  it  at  that. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Parkerson  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  'Riank  you,  Mr.  Parkerson. 

Mr.  Rudisill. 

STATEMENT  OF  THOMAS  A.  RUDISILL,  CHAIRMAN,  CROP 
INSURANCE  RESEARCH  BUREAU,  INC. 

Mr.  Rudisill.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  come  as  chairman  of  the  Crop  Insurance  Research  Bureau, 
whose  members  vary  from  large  to  small  companies,  some  MPCI 
writers,  and  some  who  are  not,  but  write  private  crop  insurance 
coverages  and  are  very  interested  in  the  program. 

As  our  written  testimony  indicates,  the  reform  program  is  a  con- 
cept, and  we  think  it  meets  most  needs  for  disaster  protection,  com- 
bined with  risk  management  for  the  farmer. 

To  function  satisfactorily,  some  fine  tuning  will  be  necessary  and 
the  areas  of  this  need  are  currently  being  addressed  by  FCIC  and 
industry  people,  along  with  others,  and  we  feel  like  they  are  work- 
ing diligently  to  that  end. 

I'll  mention  just  a  very  few  of  the  concerns  that  we  have  that 
were  not  included  in  my  written  testimony. 

One,  the  bill  may  be  a  little  bit  specific  in  some  areas  where  it 
could  be  more  effectively  left  to  some  regulatory  handling  and  the 
flexibility  that  would  go  with  that.  One  example  would  be  the  APH 
formula.  Perhaps  that  would  be  best  left  out  of  the  bill  and  handled 
administratively. 

We  feel  competition  between  companies  should  be  based  on  serv- 
ice rather  than  on  price.  The  provision  allowing  for  certain  compa- 
nies to  save  on  administrative  costs  and  pass  that  on  in  the  form 
of  price  competition  may  be  counter-productive  in  two  ways:  Large 
companies  with  an  economy  of  scale  might  be  able  to  use  this  to 
take  us  toward  more  monopolistic  production  of  this  business  at  a 
time  when  we  have  already  reduced  from  some  50  companies  writ- 
ing this  business  down  to  15  or  less.  We  feel  basically  that  competi- 
tion— a  more  advisable  manner  would  be  to  establish  a  reasonable 
amount  of  allowance  for  administrative  cost  to  provide  prompt,  ac- 
curate, efficient  service  and  let  the  service  be  the  competition. 

We  feel  that  naming  of  specific  perils  should  remain  in  the  act, 
as  opposed  to  the  current  provision  which  would  not  allow  the 
farmer  to  know  exactly  what  he  was  insuring  against.  We  feel 
named  and  specific  perils  are  important. 

We  also  have  some  concerns  about  the  85  percent  level  of  cov- 
erage which  others  favor.  The  reason  for  this  is,  actuarial  sound- 
ness being  one  of  the  primary  objectives  of  the  program,  at  this 
time  the  50  percent  level  of  coverage  is  producing  a  100  percent 
loss  ratio,  the  65  percent  considerably  higher,  and  the  75  percent 
level  is  a  175  percent  loss  ratio.  So  to  move  on  up  to  an  85  or  95 


260 

percent  level  would  exacerbate  the  problem  with  actuarial  sound- 
ness. 

In  conclusion,  we  think  some  adjustments  could  be  made,  are 
necessary,  but  we  favor  the  program  as  presented  and  we  com- 
pliment each  of  the  other  people  and  this  committee  especially  for 
the  opportunity  to  state  our  views. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Rudisill  appears  at  the  conclu- 
sion of  the  hearing.] 

Mr.  Johnson.  Thank  you.  I  appreciate  your  observations  about 
actuarial  soundness.  Obviously,  there  would  be  some  subsidy  re- 
quired. We  want  to  encourage  that  buy-up  to  the  degree  that  we 
can,  but  I  think  it  is  a  good  point  that  left  strictly  to  premium  lev- 
els, it  could  create  an  enormous  premium  burden  if  there  is  not 
some  fairly  substantial  subsidy  for  that  buy-up  encouragement. 

Let  me  ask  you  just  briefly  here — and  I  apologize.  We've  got  a 
vote  pending,  and  I'm  going  to  have  to  excuse  myself  quickly,  and 
I  hate  to  have  you  stay  here  just  for  a  few  more  questions. 

The  purpose  of  the  administration  is  that  we  need  a  dual  deliv- 
ery system  because  there  simply  are  not  enough  agents  across  the 
country — at  least  in  some  portions  of  the  country — to  handle  a 
sign-up  that  currently  is  around  30  percent  and  they  anticipate 
being  around  80  percent. 

Do  you  basically  agree  with  that — that  there  really  is  no  way 
around,  at  least  initially,  a  dual  delivery  system,  at  least  until  the 
private  insurance  system  matures  in  some  regions  of  the  country? 
And  if  there  is  a  dual  delivery  system,  what  level  of  training  do  you 
think  realistically  is  going  to  be  important  for  ASCS  personnel? 
Anybody  on  the  panel  may  take  a  shot  at  that. 

Mr.  CONNEALY.  As  far  as  the  administration's  position  that 
agents  don't  exist  in  certain  areas,  we  are  not  aware  of  where  those 
areas  are.  That  was  the  dialog  we  had  with  them.  They  wanted  to 
insure  that  everybody  was  visited  with  about  the  program.  We 
don't  know  of  a  specific  area,  that  local  agents  couldn't  be  appointed 
and  trained  if  there  was  a  monetary  reason  for  them  to  be. 

We  are  a  national  writer.  In  40-some  States  we  have  agents  ap- 
pointed and  servicing  clients.  We  think  it  was  more  of  a  cost  basis 
that  for  the  free  level  of  coverage  the  agent  wouldn't  be  interested 
in  providing  the  administrative  work,  and  that  the  proposed  FSA 
would  be  a  backstop. 

Our  estimate  on  the  cost  of  that  is  that  it  is  considerably  more 
than  the  value  that  is  going  to  be  received  by  the  Grovemment  for 
appointing  those  FSA's. 

We  had  a  pilot  project,  I  believe,  in  1990  on  training  ASCS  of- 
fices, and  several  million  dollars  were  spent  training  ASCS  people 
to  sell  the  policies,  and  I  believe  they  sold  fewer  than  a  handful. 
So  it  is  questionable. 

By  the  same  token,  the  way  the  administration's  proposal  reim- 
burses expenses  at  the  catastrophic  level,  by  and  large  the  private 
sector,  including  the  agent  force,  would  not  support  it  because 
there  isn't  any  money  to  pay  their  cost. 

Mr.  Johnson.  Any  very  brief  follow-up  on  that? 

Mr.  Joyce.  I  would  concur  with  Mr.  Connealy  and  would  address 
the  issue  of  training.  It  would  be  our  suggestion — and  I  believe  you 
would  find  from  the  Big  I  and  the  PIA  agent  associations  and  many 


261 

other  professional  associations  that  if  you  are  going  to  keep  the 
program  on  an  equal  keel  where  it  is  understandable,  people  know 
what  they  are  buying,  the  service  to  be  expected,  that  the  same  li- 
censing-training  requirements  that  go  into  allowing  an  agent,  both 
at  the  State  level  to  be  certified  to  sell  and  to  meet  the  FCIC  re- 
quirements which  are  in  addition  to  their  State  licensing,  would  be 
absolutely  mandatory,  along  with  equal  administration  of  the  pro- 
gram under  all  terms  simply  to  keep  it  from  being  confusing. 

Mr.  Post.  Just  one  more  thing.  Congressman,  on  the  availability. 
I  do  not  believe  the  farmer  has  any  difficulty,  even  in  the  far 
reaches  of  this  country,  in  finding  an  insurance  agent  for  his  farm 
vehicles  and  his  equipment,  and  I  think  the  same  thing  will  occur 
on  crop  insurance. 

Mr.  Johnson.  I  want  to  thank  the  members  of  the  panel  for  your 
contributions  here.  The  full  written  statements  are  received.  I 
think  it  is  very  helpful. 

I  have  a  vote  on  the  crime  bill.  If  I  am  not  over  there  in  3  min- 
utes I  will  be  recorded  as  being  in  favor  of  crack  cocaine,  and  so 
I  am  going  to  have  to  excuse  myself  to  record  that  vote. 

Thank  you  very  much  for  your  attendance  here. 

With  that,  this  subcommittee  is  adjourned. 

[Whereupon,  at  12:53  p.m.,  the  subcommittee  was  adjourned,  to 
reconvene  at  the  call  of  the  Chair.] 

[Material  submitted  for  inclusion  in  the  record  follows:] 


262 


National  Association  of  State  Departments  of  Agriculture 

1 156  ISthStheet.  N.w.  •  Suite  1020  •  Washington.  DC  20005 
TELEPHONE:  202/296-9630  •  Fax:  202/296-96S6 


OSmON  STATEMENT 


Testimony  of 

Bob  Odom,  Commissioner 

Louisiana  Department  of  Agricnltnre  and  Forestry 

on  bdialf  of  the 

Natioud  Association  of  State  Departments  of  Agriculture 

before  the 

House  Agriculture  Subcommittee  on 

Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

U^.  House  of  Representatives 

April  21,  1994 

re:  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 


Good  morning  Mr.  Chairman,  memben  of  the  Subcommittee.  I  am  Bob  Odom, 
Commissioner  of  the  Lomsiana  Depaitment  of  Agriculture  and  Forestry.  I  also  serve  as 
President  of  the  National  Association  of  State  Departments  of  Agriculture  (NASDA).  I 
appreciate  the  opportunity  to  appear  before  you  today  and  to  offer  my  comments  on  the 
Administration's  proposed  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994."  My  comments  not 
only  reflect  my  own  position  but  also  the  position  taken  by  NASDA  at  their  annual  meeting  held 
Sqrtembcr  13,  1993,  in  Waterville  Valley,  New  Hampshire. 

NASDA  is  the  nonprofit  association  of  public  officials  representing  the  Commissioners, 
Secretaries  and  Directors  of  Agriculture  in  the  fifty  states  and  the  territories  of  American  Samoa, 
Guam,  Puerto  Rico,  and  the  Virgin  Islands. 

Hrst  let  me  say  that  I  support  the  efforts  of  the  Administradon  to  reform  the  federal  crop 
insurance  and  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  and  have  spoken  to  the  Administradon  on  numerous 
occasions  about  my  position  on  die  need  for  change  from  what  we  have  to  offer  to  ^trmers 
today.  The  proposal  before  you  addresses  those  concerns. 

Commercial,  mainstream  farmers  in  my  state  and  odier  states,  for  the  most  part,  are  not 
supporters  of  the  current  federal  crop  insurance  program  and  have  signalled  a  desire  for 
fundamental  reform  of  the  program.  The  current  program  does  not  meet  their  needs  and  the 
premiums  are  excessive  for  the  coverage  provided.  The  current  program  provides  opportunities 
for  widely  known  abuses  by  fermen  who,  year  after  year,  form  just  to  collect  insurance.  Many 
farmers  in  my  state  have  been  indicted  and  convicted  for  various  abuses  under  the  current 
program  and  investigations  are  continuing.  In  fact,  the  loss  ratio  in  Louisiana  is  higher  than  the 
nasda  is  a  nonfrofit  association  of  pubuc  officials  representtng  the  commissioners. 
Secreuries  and  Directors  of  agriculture  in  the  fifty  siates  and  four  terrtpories. 


263 


national  average  for  the  last  ten  years.  We  need  a  crop  insurance  program  designed  for  the 
mainstream,  low  risk  commercial  farmer  who  is  interested  in  financial  protection  in  case  of  a 
loss  due  to  drought,  flood  or  natural  disaster,  and  we  need  a  program  the  farmer  can  afford. 
The  proposed  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994"  provides  the  framework  to  meet 
this  need  and  also  provides  the  positive  changes  needed  if  the  federal  crop  insurance  program 
is  to  survive. 

Additionally,  the  proposal  eliminates  the  uncertainty  of  farmers  receiving  assistance  from 
ad  hoc  disaster  programs  by  providing  catastrophic  risk  protection  as  part  of  the  crop  insurance 
program.  Providing  disaster  assistance  on  an  ad  hoc  basis,  as  we  do  today,  tends  to  discourage 
participation  in  the  crop  insurance  program.  The  possibility  that  a  farmer  will  receive  some  type 
of  assistance,  even  if  he  does  nothing  to  protect  himself  from  loss,  sends  a  very  wrong  signal 
that  crop  insurance  is  an  uimecessary  expense.  It  is  widely  accepted  that  we  cannot  continue  to 
have  both  programs  because  of  cost  and  because  of  inequities  in  the  assistance  provided  through 
the  current  disaster  program.  Farmers  prefer  a  comprehensive  crop  insurance  program  that  will 
help  meet  their  financial  security  needs  on  an  individual  basis  rather  than  the  uncertainty  of  ad 
hoc  disaster  programs  dependent  upon  wide  area  or  multi-state  disasters  and  congressional 
appropriation  of  funds.  I  support  this  part  of  the  proposal  which  provides  a  permanent  basic 
level  of  support  at  nominal  cost  to  the  farmer,  yet  costs  no  more  than  has  been  the  average  cost 
to  the  taxpayer  over  the  last  ten  years  or  so. 

Specifically,  as  it  relates  to  the  proposal,  I  support  the  following  concepts  that  have  been 
included: 

1.  A  comprehensive  federal  crop  insurance  program  must  meet  the  needs  of 
mainstream,  low  risk  producers  by  offering  them  financial  security  in  case  of 
drought,  flood  or  natural  disaster  and  must  have  incentives  to  attract  these 
producers  into  the  program  to  ensure  widespread  participation.  For  example, 
premium  discounts  should  be  offered  to  those  farmers  with  good  experience. 
Conversely,  farmers  who  consistently  have  losses  should  be  placed  in  a  "High 
Risk  Pool"  and  taken  out  of  the  actuarial  data  base  used  to  calculate  premiums. 
Additionally,  significant  premium  discounts  for  higher  levels  of  coverage  are 
critical  in  order  to  attract  participation  at  those  higher,  "buy  up"  levels  of 
coverage  which  are  needed  to  make  the  program  more  fiscally  sound.  It  is  my 
understanding  that  these  incentives  will  be  included  in  this  program. 

2.  Insurance  coverage  should  be  based  on  the  "Actual  Production  History"  of 
individual  farmers  based  on  proven  yields,  proven  through  the  Farm  Service 
Centers,  rather  than  to  the  insurance  company  through  its  private  agents.  This 
will  reduce  any  attempt  to  assign  production  history  to  a  farm  on  which  the 
production  did  not  occur. 

3.  Farmers  should  have  the  option  of  buying  the  level  of  coverage  they  determine 
best  meets  their  needs  on  an  individual  basis.  Under  the  proposal,  farmers  may 
purchase  additional  insurance  coverage  providing  higher  yield  or  price  protection 
levels  above  the  basic  catastrophic  risk  protection,  for  an  additional  premium. 
The  FCIC  has  stated  that  farmers  will  have  more  flexibility  on  yield  and  price 


264 


elections  and  unit  structure  than  is  currently  available,  with  the  assurance  that  the 
program  will  be  more  farmer  friendly,  with  new  products  and  flexibility. 
Incentives  are  provided  through  premium  discounts  at  the  higher  levels  to 
encourage  greater  participation,  which,  I  feel,  is  extremely  important  to  the 
success  of  the  program.  Premiums  for  the  "buy  up"  coverages  must  be 
reasonable  and  affordable  for  the  risk  involved  in  order  to  enlist  the  low  risk 
farmers  into  the  program. 

4.  Farmer  records  should  be  identified  by  Farm  Serial  Number  and  Social  Security 
Number. 

5.  Ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  for  all  crops  eligible  for  crop  insurance  should  be 
eliminated.  I  support  the  catastrophic  risk  protection  program  offered  in  the 
proposal  at  50  percent  loss  in  yield,  indenmified  at  60  percent  of  the  expected 
market  price.  I  do  not  feel  that  a  lower  base  level  of  coverage  will  meet  the  need 
of  farmers  who  choose  not  to  purchase  buy-up  levels  of  coverage.  A  base  level 
of  coverage  that  is  too  low  will  not  provide  the  fanner  with  sufficient  financial 
coverage  to  see  him  through  a  crop  loss  and  will  only  encourage  calls  for  ad  hoc 
disaster  assistance  to  make  up  the  difference.  Then  we'll  find  ourselves  right 
back  where  we  are  today. 

6.  I  also  support  the  noninsured  assistance  program  that  will  cover  those  crops  for 
which  crop  insurance  currently  is  not  offered.  Replacing  the  ad  hoc  disaster 
program,  with  all  its  uncertainties,  with  a  catastrophic  risk  protection  program 
and  a  noninsured  assistance  program  with  certainty  of  protection  is  critical  to  this 
proposal.  When  both  programs  are  offered  or  available  to  fanners  who  produce 
crops  eligible  for  crop  insurance,  i.e.,  federal  crop  insurance  and  ad  hoc  disaster, 
a  conflict  exists  which  creates  uncertainty  and  provides  a  disincentive  for  low  risk 
producers  to  participate  in  the  crop  insurance  program,  thereby  weakening  the 
whole  program.  This  lack  of  participation  creates  a  higher  loss  ratio  to  premiums 
earned,  creating  the  need  to  increase  rates  which  further  aggravates  the 
participation  problem.  Combining  these  two  programs  into  one  eliminates  the 
uncertainty  and  meets  the  need  of  farmers,  particularly  in  their  financial  planning 
and  banking  relationships. 

Mr.  Chairman,  thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to  participate  in  this  very  important  hearing 
today  and  allowing  me  to  express  NASDA's  support  for  the  Administration's  proposed  "Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994."  The  current  program  is  not  serving  the  needs  of 
mainstream,  commercial  farmers  and  a  total  reforming  of  the  program  is  needed.   Thank  you. 


265 


LARRY  DIEDRICH,  PRESIDENT  OF  THE 
AMERICAN  SOYBEAN  ASSOCIATION 

COMMENTS  BEFORE  THE  HOUSE  AGRICULTURE 
SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

APRIL  21,  1994 

Good  Morning.  I  am  Larry  Diedrich,  a  soybean,  corn  and  hog  producer 
from  Elkton,  South  Dakota,  and  currently  serve  as  President  of  the 
American  Soybean  Association.  ASA  appreciates  the  opportunity  to 
comment  today  on  the  federal  crop  insurance  program  and  to  propose 
improvements  in  the  program. 

Soybean  producers  traditionally  have  not  participated  in  the 
current  crop  insurance  program.  Many  have  found  it  not  worth 
purchasing.  There  has  also  been  a  history  of  abuse  in  some  of  our 
producing  areas,  causing  "good"  farmers  to  avoid  participation  on 
the  basis  that  the  "bad  apples"  have  spoiled  the  program  for 
everyone.  However,  record  losses  resulting  from  drastic  weather 
patterns  coupled  with  improvements  in  the  program  in  recent  years 
changed  the  attitude  of  soybean  producers.  Many  are  reconsidering 
the  option  of  crop  insurance. 

My  brother  and  I  are  among  these  new  participants.  For  the  first 
time,  we  are  insuring  our  soybeans  and  corn.  We  have  found  several 
improvements  in  the  program,  including  late  and  prevented  planting 
coverage  for  soybeans.  And  with  our  good  records  we  are  able  to 
utilize  APH  for  yields. 

However,  I  would  recommend  changing  the  current  policy  for  drilled 
soybeans.  It  currently  costs  25%  more  to  cover  drilled  soybeans  as 
opposed  to  conventional  row-planted  soybeans,  even  though  drilled 
soybeans  produce  higher  yields.  Many  producers  in  our  region  plant 
with  a  drill  because  of  our  no-till  practice.  We  should  not  be 
penalized  for  updating  and  improving  our  efficiency. 

Soybean  producers  as  well  as  other  farmers  need  risk  management 
tools  to  provide  income  security  and  stability.  The  Federal  crop 
insurance  program  could  and  should  be  a  useful  means  for  doing  just 
that.  The  Administration's  reform  proposal  is  a  step  in  the  right 
direction.  Producers  do  need  protection  from  catastrophic 
disasters.  Under  current  budget  constraints,  ad  hoc  federal 
disaster  assistance  will  become  harder  and  harder  to  count  on. 

The  Administration's  proposal  guarantees  basic  coverage  for 
catastrophic  disasters  to  all  producers  at  a  minimum  cost.  It  also 
gives  the  farmer's  lenders  assurance  of  guaranteed  protection 
against  extreme  disasters.  Currently,  lending  institutions 
do  not  consider  the  possibility  of  federal  disaster  assistance  as 
true  security  for  their  investment. 

The  Administration's  catastrophic  plan,  in  itself,  does  not  offer 
complete  risk  managment.   We  must  improve  the  current  crop 


266 


-2- 

insurance  program  to  accompli-sh  this.  It  is  my  understanding  the 
Administration's  proposal  would  continue  to  offer  the  options  of 
additional  coverage  at  the  65  percent  and  75  percent  levels  at 
slightly  below  current  cost.  Many  of  our  members  would  favor 
adding  an  option  of  85  percent  coverage.  In  addition,  all  agree 
that  yields  should  be  based  on  actual  production  history. 

Test  counties  in  24  soybean  producing  states  now  offer  the  Group 
Risk  Plan.  Although  participation  has  not  been  great,  and  it  may 
be  too  early  to  measure  its  success,  most  soybean  producers  are 
skeptical  of  the  "one  fits  all"  approach  of  this  plan.  For 
example,  one  farmer  or  several  in  one  part  of  a  large  county  may 
suffer  huge  losses  because  of  a  hail  storm  or  flooding.  The  rest 
of  the  county  may  not  have  the  same  conditions  and  the  county  would 
not  qualify  for  crop  insurance  pay-out.  In  this  instance,  single 
producers  or  small  groups  of  producers  could  be  left  without 
coverage  even  though  their  individual  losses  were  great. 

Views  and  concerns  regarding  other  provisions  in  the 
Administration's  reform  package  vary  by  region  and  even  by 
producer.  However,  I  would  like  to  mention  three  of  special 
significance  to  our  membership: 

Delivery;  Opinions  differ  on  the  preferred  choice  of  delivery  for 
crop  insurance.  Mr.  Chairman,  as  you  probably  know,  most  producers 
in  my  region  would  prefer  that  private  companies  handle  crop 
insurance.  However,  in  the  South  where  there  have  been  problems 
with  some  agents  or  companies,  many  producers  feel  ASCS  or  the 
proposed  Farm  Service  Agency  should  manage  all  insurance.  My  hope 
would  be  that,  regardless  of  who  offers  the  insurance,  it  be 
consistent  and  that  handlers  be  responsible  and  accountable  for 
policies. 

Linkage  to  Farm  Programs;  Mr.  Chairman,  I  am  certain  you  and  most 
of  the  Committee  would  agree  that  farmers  are  independent.  We  just 
do  not  like  mandates,  of  any  kind.  Although,  the  proposed  fee  for 
catastrophic  coverage  is  nominal  for  most  producers,  we  fear 
additional  requirements  could  be  added  down  the  road.  For 
instance,  would  a  cap  be  set  by  law  on  this  payment  or  could  it 
increase  if  costs  are  not  controlled?  Would  it  set  a  precedent  for 
additional  requirements?  We  already  have  linkage  with  our 
conservation  compliance  plans,  and  we  are  hearing  of  other  possible 
requirements  under  environmental  proposals.  Are  we  making 
participation  in  farm  programs  less  and  less  attractive?  These 
questions  need  to  be  asked,  and  answered. 

Price  Election;  Many  of  our  members,  particularly  in  the  South, 
are  not  satisfied  with  the  current  pricing  formula  system.  They 
favor  a  price  selection  more  reflective  of  local  prices.  For 
example,  if  the  highest  price  selection  is  $6.00  per  bushel  for 
soybeans,  that  is  a  fair  price  for  me  in  South  Dakota.  However, 
$6.00  is  not  considered  fair  by  my  friends  in  Louisiana.  They  need 


267 


-3- 


$6.50  to  cover  their  higher  input  costs.  The  price  election 
offered  should  meet  the  needs  of  different  producing  areas. 
Mr.  Chairman,  I  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  be  here  today  and  to 
express  some  of  the  views  and  concerns  of  U.S.  soybean  producers 
regarding  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program.  I  do  not  envy  the 
Committee's  challenge  as  you  tackle  the  growing  need  to  improve  our 
system  and  wean  producers  from  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance.  I  would 
be  happy  to  provide  additional  information  on  other  aspects  of  the 
proposal  or  the  current  crop  insurance  program. 

Thank  you  very  much. 


f . 


?'      ** '  '   ."'  ■' 


268 


STATEMENT  OF  THE  AMERICAN  BANKERS  ASSOCIATION 

Mr.  Chairman  and  Members  of  the  Subcommittee,  I  am  pleased  to  be  here  on 
behalf  of  the  American  Bankers  Association  (ABA)  to  participate  in  this  hearing 
regarding  HR  4217,  the  "Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994."   My  name  is  Phil 
Burns,  president  of  the  Farmers  and  Merchants  National  Bank  in  West  Point,  Nebraska 
located  about  50  miles  northwest  of  Omaha.   I  currently  serve  on  the  American  Bankers 
Association's  Agricultural  Bankers  Executive  Committee.   My  bank  has  S65  million  in 
assets  and  a  $50  million  loan  portfolio,  of  which  $35  million  is  in  agricultural  loans.  Crops 
in  our  service  area  include  com,  beans  and  alfalfa.   Like  many  other  banks  across  the 
nation,  we  own  a  full-service  insurance  agency,  which  we  bought  several  years  ago. 
However,  we  have  been  selling  crop  insurance  for  at  least  10  years,  even  before  the 
insurance  agency  was  purchased. 

As  many  of  you  know,  the  American  Bankers  Association  is  the  national  trade  and 
professional  association  for  America's  commercial  banks,  from  the  smallest  to  the  largest. 
ABA's  members  represent  about  90  percent  of  the  industry's  total  assets.  Approximately 
94  percent  of  ABA's  members  are  community  banks  with  assets  of  less  than  $500  million. 
Over  half  of  ABA's  12,000  members  have  important  agricultural  concerns.  It  is  good 
being  here  today  to  make  a  brief  statement  and  answer  any  questions  you  may  have. 

To  begin,  the  banking  industry  would  like  to  commend  Chairman  Johnson, 
Congressman  Combest,  and  the  entire  Subcommittee  for  looking  at  ways  in  which  we  can 
effectively  address  crop  insurance  and  disaster  assistance  issues.   Further,  America's  small 
and  large  banks  support  adequately-funded  crop  insurance  reform  at  the  Federal  level. 
Your  interest  in  improving  the  crop  insurance  program  by  providing  reliable  catastrophic 
coverage  on  the  basis  of  individual  farmers'  needs  and  reducing  unreliable  ad  hoc 
agricultural  disaster  programs  is  a  good  move  for  our  nation's  farmers  and  the  rural 
communities  about  which  we  are  all  concerned.   An  emphasis  on  crop  insurance  sales 
through  the  private  sector  wherever  possible  is  also  a  step  in  the  right  direction. 


269 


Statement  of  the  Ameiican  Bankers  Association  (page  2) 
HR  4217,  "the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994" 
Thursday,  April  21,  1994 


Banks  across  the  country  are  primarily  concerned  about  the  availability  of  crop 
insurance  which  can  be  consistently  and  efficiently  used  as  collateral.   We  know  that 
dependable  crop  insurance  can,  and  frequently  does,  mean  the  difference  in  whether 
banks  are  able  to  approve  operating  loans  and  other  types  of  credit  for  farmers 
struggling  to  stay  ahead  in  high-risk  situations  and  in  challenging  agricultural  markets. 

Like  many  other  banks,  our  bank  is  an  active  participant  in  Farmers  Home 
Administration  (FmHA)  guaranteed  lending  programs.   FmHA  requires  the  purchase  of 
crop  insurance  before  loans  can  be  processed.   We  join  other  banks  across  the  country  in 
looking  for  ways  to  help  beginning  farmers  and  ranchers  in  particular  who  are  often  high- 
risk  borrowers.   Adequate  crop  insurance  coverage  helps  us  to  continue  serving  these  and 
other  customers. 

Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  this  Subcommittee,  commercial  banks  join  you  in 
looking  for  ways  in  which  cost-effective  and  reliable  types  of  crop  insurance  can  be  made 
available  at  reasonable  prices.  Crop  insurance  is  one  of  the  government-assisted 
programs  utilized  by  commercial  banks  to  effectively  serve  rural  economies.  The  banking 
industry  is  interested  in  working  with  you  to  consider  reasonable  ways  in  which  we  can 
continue  meeting  the  various  needs  of  all  rural  communities. 

Mr.  Chairman,  in  closing,  America's  bankers  are  interested  in  working  with  you 
and  members  of  this  Subcommittee  to  advance  an  adequately-funded  and  reliable  crop 
insurance  program  which  can  meet  the  various  needs  of  the  farmers  we  serve.  Thank 
you  for  this  opportunity  to  express  the  concerns  of  small  and  large  banks  across  our 
nation.   Attached  to  my  printed  statement  are  specific  responses  to  your  questions 
regarding  HR  4217. 

(Attachment  follows:) 


270 


Statement  of  the  American  Bankers  Association  (page  3) 
Thursday,  April  21,  1994 


Responses  to  specific  questions  concerning 
HR  4217,  "the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994" 


! 


o         TTie  American  Bankers  Association  supports  the  availability  of  reliable  crop  j 

insurance.   Crop  insurance  can  make  a  positive  difference  in  whether  marginal  borrowers 
can  get  operating  loans;  < 

o  Regarding  the  $50  catastrophic  coverage  processing  fee  not  to  exceed  $100  p)cr  \ 

grower  per  county,  most  bankers  believe  it  would  be  affordable  to  all  producers. 
Simplification  is  the  key; 

o  It  is  a  good  idea  to  require  producers  to  obtain  at  least  catastrophic  coverage  in         ^ 

order  to  be  eligible  to  participate  in  price  support  and  loan  programs.  This  provision  is 
necessary  if  Congress  has  any  hof)e  of  moving  away  from  ad  hoc  disaster  payments. 

o  The  banking  industry  commends  your  emphasis  on  developing  a  dual  delivery  j 

system  in  which  catastrophic  coverage  can  be  widely  available  from  both  the  private 
sector  and  USDA  service  centers.   Your  emphasis  on  the  availability  of  additional  \ 

coverage  being  available  only  through  the  private  sector  is  a  step  in  the  right  direction; 

o         The  members  of  ABA  believe  that  utilization  of  actual  production  history  over 
multiple  years  to  establish  necessary  coverage  level(s)  is  the  correct  approach;  ^ 

o  Producers  should  be  required  to  insure  all  cropland;  I 

o  Some  farmers,  especially  those  who  are  just  getting  started,  may  be  highly 

leveraged.   We  encourage  you  to  keep  in  mind  that  more  than  75  percent  coverage  may 
be  necessary  in  some  cases.   Producers  should  have  opportunities  to  purchase  , 

supplemental  products;  i 

o  Farmers  who  grow  non-insurable  crops  need  special  coverage  prior  to  planting 

season;  j 

o         ABA  encourages  the  FCIC  to  make  broader  use  of  their  authority  to  back  private      , 
sector  initiatives  like  "market  value  protection,"  which  ties  insurance  to  market  prices  and 
provides  more  protection  to  growers  who  pre-sell  or  hedge  crops  during  growing  seasons.      1 


271 


REVISED   COPY  _  _^.  . 

Testimony  of 

James  F.  Hart 
Miller,  South  Dakota 

on  behalf  of  the 

Independent  Bankers  Association  of  America  (EBAA) 

before  the 

House  Agriculture  Committee 
Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

on 

H.R.  4217 
The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 

Washington,  D.C. 
AprU  21,  1994 


Mr.  Chairman,  Members  of  the  Subcommittee,  my  name  is  James  F.  Hart,  and  I  am 
president  and  CEO  of  the  Hand  County  State  Bank  in  Miller,  South,  Dakota.    I'm  pleased  to 
be  here  today  to  testify  on  the  Administration's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  on  behalf  of 
the  Independent  Bankers  Association  of  America  (IBAA).   I  serve  on  IBAA's  Agriculture- 
Rural  America  Committee,  which  develops  policy  for  IBAA's  6,000  member  bankers  on 
agriculture,  trade,  the  environment,  and  rural  development  issues.    IBAA  is  the  only  national 
trade  association  that  exclusively  represents  the  views  of  our  nation's  community  bankers. 

Mr.  Chairman,  let  me  begin  my  testimony  today  by  congratulating  you  on  your 
selection  as  chairman  of  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development. 
All  three  of  these  subject  areas  —  the  environment,  credit  and  rural  development  ~  are 
critical  to  the  future  of  our  state  of  South  Dakota.    So  from  a  personal  and  parochial 
standpoint,  "we've  got  you  right  where  we  want  you." 

Let  me  also  thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  making  crop  insurance  reform  one  of  your 
earliest  priorities  on  this  subcommittee,  and  for  scheduling  this  hearing  today.   Federal  crop 
insurance  has  been  the  source  of  considerable  controversy  ever  since  the  Crop  Insurance 
Reform  Act  of  1980  broadened  the  scope  of  the  program  in  an  effort  to  achieve  universal 
coverage  and  break  the  malignant  cycle  of  annual  disaster  programs.   So  the  task  of 
reforming  the  program  is  certainly  not  an  easy  one,  and  we  are  grateful  to  you  for  taking  the 
initiative  to  move  the  process  forward. 


272 


IBAA  Supports  Crop  Insurance  Reform 

Mr.  Chairman,  45  percent  of  IBAA's  member  bankers  are  agricultural  bankers 
according  to  the  USD  A  definition.   Equally  important,  a  full  75  percent  of  IBAA  banks  are 
located  in  towns  of  10,000  people  or  less.    So  it  would  not  be  much  of  an  exaggeration  to 
say  that  the  great  majority  of  IBAA  bankers  are  agriculture-dependent.   That  is  why  we  have 
taken  such  an  interest  in  the  Administration's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal,  and  that  is 
why  IBAA  has  worked  with  the  Administration  and  the  crop  insurance  industry  to  come  up 
with  a  program  that  we  think  will  work. 

In  February,  delegates  to  IBAA's  national  convention  adopted  the  following 
resolution: 

Crop  Insurance  and  Disaster  Relief.   Many  IBAA  agricultural  bankers  rely  on 
federally-subsidized  Multiple-Peril  Crop  Insurance  (MPCI)  to  protect  crops  used  as 
collateral  on  operating  loans.    Many  farmers  rely  on  crop  insurance  to  help  reduce 
risk  and  backstop  marketing  programs,  such  as  forward  contracting  and  other  price 
discovery  mechanisms.    However,  it  has  become  apparent  that  we  can  no  longer 
afford  to  support  a  subsidized  crop  insurance  program  and  provide  annual  ad-hoc 
disaster  payments  as  well. 

IBAA  supports  reform  efforts  aimed  at  reducing  reliance  on  disaster  aid  by  providing 
all  growers  of  program  crops  with  a  basic  level  of  crop  insurance  coverage.    To 
facilitate  "buying-up '  with  add-on  MPCI  policies,  IBAA  supports  maintaining  the 
private  sector  delivery  system  in  lieu  of  converting  to  a  government  sales  force.   And 
we  believe  consideration  should  be  given  to  modifying  the  program  from  a  "yield 
protection  program "  to  an  "income  protection  program "  to  make  it  more  predictable 
in  managing  cashflow  and  easier  for  farmers  to  understand. 

Bankers  Use  Crop  Insurance 

As  the  resolution  states,  crop  insurance  is  important  to  agricultural  bankers  because 
many  of  us  use  it  to  protect  collateral  on  operating  loans.   To  put  it  very  simply,  we  would 
rather  lend  on  a  contract  than  a  promise.    A  crop  insurance  policy  is  an  effective  and  reliable 
backstop  for  ag  loans;  ad  hoc  disaster  payments,  which  may  or  may  not  be  there  when 
needed,  is  not. 

Several  years  ago,  IBAA  conducted  a  study  of  leadership  bankers  to  determine 
whether  or  not  they  used  crop  insurance.    While  the  survey  was  admittedly  scientifically 
flawed,  the  results  were  nonetheless  revealing.    More  than  seventy  percent  of  the  bankers 
surveyed  either  required  or  strongly  encouraged  their  farm  loan  borrowers  to  carry  crop 
insurance.   So  this  program  is  nearly  as  important  to  lenders  as  it  is  to  farmers  and  ranchers. 

Proposal  Fundamentally  Sound 

Is  the  reform  proposal  that  is  on  the  table  perfect?  Not  by  any  means.   Does  IBAA 


273 


support  it?  One-hundred  percent! 

Our  position  on  the  Administration's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  is  analogous  to 
our  position  on  their  proposed  CRA  regulations.   The  new  CRA  regulations  are  far  from 
perfect.   But  the  fundamental  concept  embodied  in  the  regulations,  to  streamline  the 
examination  process  for  community  banks  by  creating  a  two-tiered  system,  is  so  sound,  that 
it  should  not  jeopardized  by  quibbling  about  details. 

Similarly,  the  underlying  concept  in  the  Administration's  crop  insurance  reform 
proposal,  that  is  to  combine  disaster  relief  and  crop  insurance  to  form  one  catastrophic 
protection  program  for  all  farmers,  is  such  an  improvement  over  the  existing  system  that  it 
should  not  be  jeopardized  by  our  desire  to  make  it  perfect. 

Farm  Subsidies  In  Decline 

Equally  important,  Mr.  Chairman,  is  the  fact  that  in  all  likelihood,  direct  government 
farm  subsidies  will  disappear  or  decline  substantially.   At  last  year's  Agricultural  Outlook 
Conference,  Secretary  of  Agriculture  Mike  Espy  said: 

*/  have  seen  the  handwriting  on  (he  wall.    U.S.  budget  support  to  agriculture 
will  coniinue  to  decline.    We  can  scream,  we  can  curse,  we  can  lambaste,  and 
sometimes  even  cattse  some  delays  in  the  inevitable.   But  the  fact  is  that  U.S. 
budget  support  for  agriculture  will  continue  to  decline. ' 

This  was  never  more  evident  than  during  last  year's  appropriations  process  when  two 
very  popular  and  traditional  farm  programs  ~  the  wool  and  mohair  program,  and  the  honey 
program  ~  were  abolished.   What  is  next?  Tobacco,  peanuts,  cotton,  rice?   It's  anybody's 
guess. 

With  this  prospect  being  laid  directly  on  the  table,  it  becomes  even  more  imperative 
for  fanners  and  ranchers  to  begin  to  manage  their  farm  risk  more  prudently.   Uncle  Sam 
won't  be  there  forever.    And  the  Administration's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  is  an  idea 
whose  time  has  come,  and  which  has  come  at  the  right  time.   America's  producers  m.ust  take 
hold  of  their  own  destiny,  and  this  proposal  will  give  them  that  opportunity. 

Having  said  that,  Mr.  Chairman,  let  me  now  address  several  features  of  the  bill  in 
more  detail,  and  make  some  recommendations  for  making  the  package  an  even  more 
effective  risk  management  program  for  our  nation's  agricultural  community. 

Repeal  Disaster  Authority 

1.         First  of  all,  the  authority  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  must  be  repealed. 
Without  this,  no  reform  package  will  work.   It's  that  simple. 

Contrary  to  popular  belief,  the  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1980  created  a 
reasonable  framework  for  a  nationwide  risk  management  program  that  would  provide 


274 


virtually  universal  protection  at  affordable  prices.   But  the  program  never  reached  its  full 
potential.    Participation  never  achieved  expected  penetration,  prices  never  came  down  to 
affordable  levels,  and  the  goal  of  actuarial  soundness  was  a  pipe  dream.   Why?  One 
fundamental  reason  called  ad  hoc  disaster  payments.    So  long  as  farmers  and  ranchers  knew 
that  if  a  natural  disaster  struck,  they  could  reasonably  count  on  the  Federal  Government  to 
bail  them  out,  there  was  no  reason  for  them  to  lay  out  their  hard  earned  cash  to  purchase 
crop  insurance.    And  to  be  very  honest,  who  could  blame  them. 

The  fact  of  the  matter  is  that  over  the  last  decade,  there  were  two  things  you  could 
count  on  every  year.    One,  there  would  be  a  natural  disaster  somewhere  in  the  country;  and 
two.  Congress  would  pass  an  ad  hoc  disaster  bill.   And  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  has  proven 
to  be  the  costliest  and  least  efficient  way  to  keep  farmers  in  business. 

Last  year  alone,  America's  farmers  and  ranchers  received  more  than  $2  billion  in 
emergency  disaster  assistance.    Now  you  might  say  that  with  the  Midwest  floods,  the 
Southeast  droughts,  the  California  fires,  etc.,  that  was  an  aberration.    And  you  would  be 
right.    But  over  the  last  ten  years,  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  have  averaged  something  like 
$1.6  billion  a  year.   That's  nearly  double  what  the  government  spent  on  crop  insurance. 
And  that's  not  an  aberration.    And  it  did  nothing  to  help  build  farmer  discipline  for  risk 
aversion  in  their  farm  plans. 

Mr.  Chairman,  if  Congress  passes  every  word  of  this  crop  insurance  reform  proposal, 
but  fails  to  terminate  the  authority  for  ad  hoc  disaster  programs,  the  reform  proposal  will  not 
work.  There  will  be  no  incentive  for  farmers  to  self-protect,  and  the  vicious  cycle  of  annual 
ad  hoc  relief  programs  will  continue. 

Cross  Compliance  Also  Key 

2.  Similarly,  we  strongly  support  the  cross-compliance  feature  of  the  proposal, 
and  feel  that  this,  too,  is  a  key  to  the  program's  success. 

You  cannot  go  out  and  buy  a  house  today  without  first  buying  fire  insurance.  You 
can't  drive  a  car  off  the  lot  until  you  have  auto  insurance.  And  the  reason  is  simple.  The 
mortgage  banker  and  the  auto  dealer  want  to  protect  their  investment. 

The  same  should  hold  true  for  the  Federal  Government.   If  the  Federal  Government 
invests  in  a  farmer  or  rancher  through  subsidized  loans,  deficiency  payments,  CRP,  or 
anything  else,  the  Government  has  a  right  to  protect  that  investment  by  requiring  the 
producer  to  carry  crop  insurance.    And  protecting  that  investment  is  not  only  good  public 
policy  from  a  taxpayer's  standpoint,  but  it  will  provide  program  beneficiaries  the  assurance 
that  should  they  be  victimized  by  a  natural  disaster,  they  will  not  have  to  spend  the  rest  of 
their  lives  paying  off  Uncle  Sam,  as  is  the  case  today  with  many  farmers  inundated  with 
defaulted  FmHA  Emergency  Disaster  Loans. 

Price  Competition  is  Good 


275 


3.  We  support  the  provision  that  allows  more  efficient  insurance  companies  to 
reduce  rates  charged  to  farmers  and  ranchers.    As  part  of  the  private  sector,  we  bankers  feel 
that  all  things  being  equal,  the  private  sector  can  do  things  more  efficiently  and  cost 
effectively  than  the  government.    And  we  feel  that  this  program,  too,  can  benefit  by 
abolishing  the  master  marketer  concept  and  relying  totally  on  the  private  sector. 

And  we  believe  that  producers  should  reap  some  of  the  benefits  of  more  efficient  and 
cost  effective  programs.    Price  competition  is  fundamental  to  the  free  market  system.    It  has 
worked  in  every  sector  of  our  economy,  and  has  assured  Americans  of  the  highest  quality 
products  and  services  at  the  lowest  possible  prices.   We  believe  price  competition  would 
have  the  same  effect  on  crop  insurance. 

Dual  Delivery  System  is  CoDcem 

4.  While  we  support  the  feature  of  the  bill  that  requires  farmers  to  purchase 
higher  coverage  policies  exclusively  from  private  agents,  we  have  some  concerns  about 
delivering  the  basic  catastrophic  coverage  programs  through  Federal  offices. 

Many  of  us  remember  when  crop  insurance  was  sold  in  county  ASCS  offices,  and 
many  of  us  also  remember  that  the  only  time  they  performed  that  function  with  any 
enthusiasm  was  when  their  normal  workload  requirements  were  completed.   The  fact  of  the 
matter  is  that  ASCS  employees  have  neither  the  expertise  nor  the  inclination  to  deliver  this 
product  in  an  effective,  conscientious  manner.    And  the  result  of  that  attitude  will  be,  in  my 
opinion,  that  many  producers  will  not  be  given  adequate  guidance  on  other  buy-up 
opportunities  that  might  better  suit  their  individual  requirements. 

The  apparent  solution  to  this  dilemma  would  be  to  deliver  the  catastrophic  coverage 
exclusively  through  trained  and  qualified  private  insurance  agents.   There  may  be  other  ways 
to  address  this  problem  as  well.   But  the  important  point  is  that  the  basic  package  may  not  be 
the  appropriate  package  for  most  fanners.   Indeed,  the  50/60  coverage  level  won't  keep 
many  farmers  in  business  unless  they  have  other  resources  they  can  fall  back  on.   So  it  is 
critically  important  to  assure  that  every  farmer  and  rancher  have  the  opportunity  to  consider 
buy-up  policies  in  an  informed  manner.   And  maintaining  a  dual  delivery  system  may  not 
achieve  that  objective. 

Make  Crop  Insurance  Funds  Mandatory 

5.  We  support  moving  crop  insurance  from  the  discretionary  to  the  mandatory 
account  to  make  it  less  vuberable  to  political  manipulation.    Under  current  law,  the  crop 
insurance  program  is  a  hostage  of  the  appropriations  process.    So  long  as  the  leadership  of 
the  appropriations  committees  in  Congress  supports  crop  insurance,  it  will  be  adequately 
funded.   However,  if  that  were  not  the  case,  the  program  could  be  terminally  crippled  by 
withholding  adequate  funding. 

If,  indeed,  crop  insurance  is  going  to  be  the  primary  risk  protection  program  available 
to  farmers  and  ranchers,  then  it  must  have  the  full  faith  and  backing  of  the  Federal 


276 


Government.    And  moving  crop  insurance  to  the  mandatory  side  of  the  ledger  will  achieve 
that  goal.   Some  have  objected  to  this  from  an  accountability  standpoint,  but  so  long  as 
private  companies  are  subject  to  the  terms  and  conditions  of  renewable  reinsurance 
agreements,  there  will  continue  to  be  full  accountability  to  the  Government  and  taxpayers. 

IBAA  Supports  Supplemental  Products 

6.         Finally,  Mr.  Chairman,  as  suggested  in  our  policy  resolution,  IBAA  believes 
expanded  authority  should  be  given  to  the  private  sector  to  develop  creative  programs  and 
policies  to  provide  higher  levels  of  protection  at  affordable  prices.   Companies  already  have 
authority  to  develop  supplemental  products.    But  these  products  are  subject  to  approval  by 
FCIC,  and  thus  far,  FCIC  has  been  either  slow  or  reluctant  in  approving  new  products. 

One  concept  IBAA  has  endorsed  is  the  concept  of  disappearing  deductibles,  under 
which  the  deductible  grows  smaller  as  losses  grow  larger,  so  that  if  a  farmer  had  a  100 
percent  loss,  he  or  she  would  receive  a  100  percent  indemnity.   This  would  address  an  often- 
heard  complaint  from  farmers  and  lenders  that  current  coverage  levels  are  not  high  enough  to 
justify  participation. 

Another  idea  we  would  like  to  see  explored  is  converting  the  program  from  a  yield 
base  to  an  income  or  cost-of-production  base.    Buying  dollar  per-acre  instead  of  bushel  per- 
acre  coverage  is  a  concept  easily  understood  by  both  producers  and  lenders,  and  it  would 
provide  an  assured  cash  stream  on  which  credit  could  easily  be  evaluated. 

Conclusion 

Mr.  Chairman,  on  Monday  of  this  week.  Secretary  Espy  addressed  about  250  IBAA 
bankers  who  had  gathered  here  in  Washington  for  our  annual  Spring  legislative  conference. 
Secretary  Espy  made  an  impassioned  plea  to  bankers  to  support  his  crop  insurance  reform 
proposal,  calling  it  a  unique  opportunity  to  enact  good  public  policy.   We  couldn't  agree 
more.   The  Administration's  crop  insurance  proposal  will  take  the  public-private  partnership 
that  already  exists,  and  strengthen  it  to  the  benefit  of  our  nation's  farmers  and  ranchers  and 
the  communities  they  serve.    In  the  process,  it  will  save  taxpayers  some  $750  million  over 
five  years. 

IBAA  hopes  that  the  Budget  Conferees  will  support  the  Administration's  request  and 
fully  fund  this  new  program,  and  we  have  told  them  so.   IBAA  also  hopes  that  the 
appropriations  committees  in  the  House  and  Senate  will  support  the  Administration's  package 
and  provide  the  necessary  funding,  and  we  will  tell  them  so.    But  regardless  of  the  outcomes 
in  those  bodies,  we  genuinely  hope  that  you  will  take  advantage  of  this  opportunity  to 
provide  for  the  long  term  protection  of  American  agriculture,  including  farmers,  ranchers, 
lenders,  agri-business,  and  Main  Street  shop  owners,  by  approving  the  Administration's  crop 
insurance  reform  proposal. 

Thank  you,  again,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  this  opportunity  to  testify  on  behalf  of  our 
nation's  community  bankers.   I  would  be  happy  to  respond  to  any  questions  you  may  have. 


277 


I^attpncd  Association  of  Wheat  Growers 

/  /\      415  Seco^l  Street.  N.E..  So.te  300,  Washir^ton.  DC  20002.  (202)  547-7800 

Chuck  Merja 

Secretary /Treasurer 

National  Association  of  Wheat  Growers 

Testimony 

before  the 

U.S.  House  of  Representatives       -      ^  .- 

Committee  on  Agricultural 

Subcommittee  on 

Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural  Development 

April  21,  1994 

Mr.  Chairman,  members  of  the  Committee,  my  name  is  Chuck  Merja,  of 
sun  River,  Montana.  We  have  utilized  crop  insurance  on  our  family  wheat 
and  barley  operation  for  many  years.  I  thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to 
present  my  views  on  crop  insurance  to  the  Committee.  I  am  serving  as 
secretary/Treasurer  for  the  National  Association  of  Wheat  Growers. 

A  revised  Federal  Crop  Insurance  program  has  been  a  long-term  goal 
of  our  organization,  and  we  urge  the  Committee  to  move  forward  with 
consideration  of  the  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  contained  in  the 
Administration's  FY'95  budget  request.  ^ 

Fifty-five  years  ago  wheat  was  the  first  commodity  to  be  covered  by 
Federal  Crop  Insurance,  and  the  industry's  need  for  effective  price  and 
yield  risk  protection  continues  to  be  a  major  goal  for  the  NAWG.  We  are 
familiar  with  the  Administration's  proposed  reform  of  crop  insurance  and 
disaster  aid,  and  we  believe  that  the  plan's  principal  features  provide 
a  strong  basis  for  development  of  a  viable  new  program. 


WHEAT  DOLLARS  ARE  IMPORTANT  TO  THE  NATCNAL  ECONOMY  AND  VOUR  BUSINESS' 


278 


In  standing  behind  the  fundamental  concept  of  providing  a  low  level 
of  catastrophic  coverage  to  all  farm  program  participants,  we  are  taking 
a  bold  step  which  many  of  us  have  previously  been  unwilling  to  take. 
However,  given  the  continued  budget  pressures  facing  all  government 
programs  and  the  solid  policy  reasons  favoring  an  insurance  approach  to 
disaster  relief,  we  believe  the  time  is  right  to  consider  change  to  a 
single  predictable  approach  to  disaster  relief.  The  Administration's 
approach  reflects  truthful  budgeting,  budget  discipline,  good  public 
policy,  improved  risk  management  options  for  farmers,  and  reduced  costs 
for  taxpayers. 

However,  NAWG  is  unwilling  to  step  completely  away  from  standard 
disaster  authority.  The  best  way  to  prevent  the  need  for  future 
disaster  legislation  is  to  establish  an  adequate,  workable,  affordable 
crop  insurance  program.  In  this  regard,  the  NAWG  supports  continued, 
standby  authority  for  disaster  relief  programs,  until  such  time  as  a  new 
regime  of  yield  and  price  risk  protection  is  proven  to  be  effective. 

Extensive  debate  has  already  occurred  over  who  delivers  the 
castastrophic  coverage  in  the  reform  package.  This  topic  was  also 
debated  as  part  of  NAWG's  resolution  process.  We  are  comfortable  with 
the  proposed  dual  delivery  system.  We  believe  the  existence  of  private 
and  public  delivery  will  guarantee  widespread,  well  serviced,  delivery 
of  catastrophic  coverage.  We  would  challenge  the  critics  of  public 
delivery  to  out-service  and  out-sell  public  delivery  systems  rather  than 
try  to  politicalize  the  issue. 


279 


3  - 


Another  topic  of  debate  has  been  the  linkage  of  program 
participation  and  the  catastrophic  coverage  plan.  The  NAWG  understands 
the  reasons  for  linkage;  however,  we  must  strongly  emphasize  that  costs 
are  to  remain  truly  a  nominal  processing  fee  and  are  not  to  be  connected 
to  risk,  acreage,  or  crops. 

NAWG  knows  of  the  interest  in  expanding  FCIC  coverage  to  new  crops. 
However,  we  don't  want  to  see  limited  resources  spread  too  thin  while 
the  program  is  still  inadeguate  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  seven 
commodities  (including  wheat)  that  comprise  75%  of  the  existing  crop 
insurance  business  and  most  of  the  potential  new  business.  One  of  the 
first  issues  FCIC  should  explore  would  be  to  develop  a  seed  wheat  policy 
for  producers  raising  high-value  seed  wheat.  These  producers  tend  to  be 
very  low  risk  with  adequate  production  records,  however,  they  may  not 
utilize  crop  insurance  due  to  inadequate  price  protection  compared  to 
the  higher  value  of  their  crop. 

NAWG  participated  in  a  FCIC  task  force  two  years  ago  thai 
recommended  the  new  four-year,  building  to  10-year,  actual  production 
history  (APH)  plan.  As  such,  we  are  supportive  of  how  the  plan  benefits 
producers  with  good  production  history,  who  have  been  blessed  with  good 
production  the  past  few  years.  However,  the  change  to  the  new,  more 
aggressive  APH  formula  has  not  been  without  pain.  Whether  a  reform 
package  moves  through  Congress  or  not,  the  highest  priority  for  FCIC 
should  be  to  develop  and  implement  an  affordable  catastrophic  yield 
clause  to  put  the  brakes  on  yield  declines  for  producers  with  multiple 
catastrophic  losses.  At  the  same  time,  the  Administration's  decision  to 


\ 


280 


base  catastrophic  yield  coverage  from  individual  APH  yields  as  opposed 
to  county  average  yields  is  a  vital  and  important  component  of  the   i 
current  reform  package.  jj 

Another  issue  which  must  be  addressed,  whether  or  not  there  is  a 
reform  package,  is  the  need  for  a  de  minimis  yield  clause.   The  lack  of   j 
a  de  minimis  yield  clause  for  small  grains  continually  makes  a  mockery   j 
of  MPCI  coverage  when  farmers  with  100%  losses  have  their  payments   1 
reduced  by  2  or  3  bushels  an  acre  because  an  adjuster  has  appraised  the 
yield  at  that  level.   This  inequity  is  further  exacerbated  by  ASCS 
having  a  de  minimis  policy  while  crop  insurance  continues  to  lack  such   | 
a  clause.  ! 


The  final  broad  area  which  NAWG  would  like  to  emphasize  has  to  do 
with  the  level  of  federal  crop  insurance  service  provided  to  the 
farmer/ consumer .  It  is  our  view  that  both  private  companies  and  FCIC 
must  become  more  customer  oriented.  We  applaud  FCIC's  recent  decision 
to  reinsure  a  new  supplemental  product.  However,  we  are  disappointed 
that  it  took  FCIC  this  long  to  utilize  the  new  authority  granted  by  this 
committee  in  1990.  We  would  encourage  FCIC  and  the  private  industry  to 
aggressively  develop,  approve  and  market  supplemental  policies.  Our 
stated  needs  for  a  seed  wheat  policy  and  a  de  minimis  yield  clause  may 
best  be  addressed  with  supplemental  policies.  Further,  the  on-going 
policy  debate  regarding  revenue  insurance  lends  itself  to  the  immediate 
creation  of  a  supplemental  policy  to  fit  that  market  niche. 


281 


The  second  areas  of  customer  service  is  the  market  price  election. 
In  the  final  days  of  1993,  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation 
relented  to  Grower  concerns  and  changed  the  1994  wheat  market  price 
elections  from  the  previously  announced  level  of  $2.80  per  bushel  to 
$3.25  per  bushel.  This  is  a  very  significant  and  responsive  improvement 
for  wheat  producers  and  reflects  well  upon  Mr.  Ackerman's  efforts  as 
FCIC  Manager.  However,  it  does  serve  to  illustrate  that  marketability 
of  the  product  must  come  into  consideration  when  establishing  the  market 
price  election.  This  final  area  of  customer  service  is  a  serious 
challenge  to  companies  and  FCIC  alike,  however,  it  is  key  to  the  success 
of  any  reform  package. 

Mr.  Chairman,  members  of  the  committee,  thank  you  for  the 
opportunity  to  testify  before  your  committee.  We  are  committed  towards 
reforming  crop  insurance  and  addressing  the  public  policy  concerns  of 
risk  management.  I  will  do  my  best  to  answer  any  questions  you  may 
have. 

Thank  you. 


282 


1521   New  Hampshire  Avenue,  NW  •  Washington,  DC  20036 
OF       AMERICA       (202)  745-7805  •  FAX  (202)  483-4040  •  TELEX  650-252-9879  MCI 

PRODUCERS    •    CINNERS    •    WAREHOUSEMEN    •    MERCHANTS    •    CRUSHERS    •    COOPERATIVES    •    MANUFACTURERS 

Testimony  by  Myrl  Mitchell 

of  Lenorah,  TX 

on  behalf  of 

The  National  Cotton  Council  of  America 

before 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural  Development 

The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson,  Chairman 

April  21,  1994 


Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman  for  the  opportunity  to  appear  on  behalf  of  the  National  Cotton 
Council  to  provide  testimony  on  the  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994.  My  name  is  Myrl 
Mitchell.  I  am  a  cotton  producer  and  ginner  from  Lenorah,  Texas  who  utilizes  the  multi-peril 
crop  insurance  program  as  a  necessary  risk  management  tool  for  my  operation.  I  serve  as  a 
member  of  the  Board  of  Directors  of  the  National  Cotton  Council  and  as  Chairman  of  its  Crop 
Insurance  Advisory  Task  Force.  We  commend  you  for  holding  this  hearing.  The  concept  of 
Crop  Insurance  reform  is  something  our  industry  has  wrestled  with  for  many  years.  Reform  is 
essential  if  this  program  is  to  effectively  replace  disaster  relief  and  entice  more  participation. 
We  believe  the  proposal  to  develop  a  new  program  is  moving  in  the  right  direction. 

The  National  Cotton  Council  supports  the  concepts  included  in  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture's 
Crop  Insurance  Reform  proposal.  Obviously,  the  devil  is  in  the  details.  I  must  caution, 
however,  that  cotton  producers  are  skeptical  that  a  workable  crop  insurance  program  can  be 
developed.  That  is  why  it  is  critical  that  FCIC's  staff  continue  to  listen  carefully  to  regional 
concerns  and  develop  provisions  that  truly  make  the  crop  insurance  program  useful.  We  cannot 
design  a  one  size  fits  all  policy. 

We  are  actively  working  with  other  commodity  groups  seeking  full  funding  for  the  plan.  With 
proper  funding,  reform  will  provide  improved  risk  management  for  producers.  Passage  of  the 
new  catastrophic  coverage  program  will  eliminate  the  uncertainty  of  ad  hoc  disaster  availability 
and  the  proposal  would  provide  producers  with  50%  yield  coverage  at  60%  of  the  average 
market  price.  USDA  and  0MB  assert,  and  we  agree,  that  producers  are  better  off  under  this 
proposal  than  under  a  disaster  bill  at  a  50%  prorate.  We  are  also  encouraged  by  the  reduced 
premiums  for  higher  coverage  levels. 

As  many  crop  lenders  require  crop  insurance  for  production  financing,  producers  need  the 
certainty  that  a  workable,  properly  funded  crop  insurance  program  provides.  While  still 
skeptical  of  the  precedent,  producers  have  generally  accepted  the  "voluntarily  mandatory"  aspect 
of  the  catastrophic  coverage  of  the  reform  plan  as  required  for  farm  program  and  FmHA 
participation  with  a  $50  per  crop  processing  fee.  We  acknowledge  the  plan  provides  for  an 
option  for  producer  to  buy  the  basic  level  of  coverage  at  his  local  Farm  Services  Agency  or 


283 


through  private  insurance  agents.  We  are  supportive  of  this  option  for  producers.  "Buyup" 
coverage  would  only  be  available  through  private  insurance  agents.  While  our  industry  supports 
the  Administration's  catastrophic  program  as  the  principal  mechanism  for  reform,  we  also 
maintain  that  flexibility  with  different  coverage  options  is  necessary  to  increase  participation  and 
meet  specific  regional  and  crop  needs.  Since  most  cotton  farmers  would  be  interested  in  the 
higher  levels  of  coverage,  we  would  urge  further  consideration  be  given  to  reducing  the  cost  of 
higher  levels  of  coverage. 

Mr.  Chairman,  in  anticipation  of  action  on  crop  insurance  reform  this  session,  the  cotton 
industry  has  hosted  or  participated  in  a  series  of  meetings  throughout  the  cottonbelt  to  hear 
comments  from  producers  on  the  Secretary's  reform  plan.  It  was  Mr.  Stenholm's  idea  to  host 
the  first  one  in  Abilene,  Texas,  and  it  went  so  well  that  we  tried  to  model  the  later  meetings 
after  it.  I  believe  there  is  one  going  on  right  now  in  Congresswoman  Lambert's  district  in 
Arkansas.  In  these  meetings  in  Abilene  and  Lubbock,  Texas,  Arizona,  Georgia,  Louisiana,  and 
Alabama,  we  have  heard  comments  that  can  be  condensed  into  five  areas  of  interest  or  concern 
with  the  current  program  and  the  reform  proposal.  FCIC  Manager  Ken  Ackerman  or  someone 
on  his  staff  was  at  each  meeting  and  listened  to  these  concerns.  In  each  area  of  interest  or 
concern,  Mr.  Ackerman  and  his  staff  have  agreed  that  there  is  a  need  to  address  these  concerns 
and  are  already  working  on  administrative  solutions  that,  once  perfected,  will  hopefully  be  added 
to  the  legislation.  The  remainder  of  my  testimony  will  focus  on  these  cotton  industry  concerns. 

The  cotton  industrv  believes  that  the  proposal  should  include  a  catastrophic  yield  adjustment 
when  calculating  actual  vields  during  disaster  years.  Administrative  efforts  to  comply  with 
Congressional  mandates  to  reduce  loss  ratios  have  relied  to  a  great  extent  on  the  use  of  actual 
production  history,  a  concept  our  industry  supports.  Unfortunately  this  concept  makes  no 
allowance  for  disasters  and,  in  fact,  severely  reduces  the  coverage  for  a  producer  through  no 
fault  of  his  own.  Under  the  current  program,  a  catastrophic  loss  year  or  "zero  year"  simply 
goes  into  a  producer's  yield  calculation  without  recognizing  that  he  might  not  have  another 
disaster  for  many  years  into  the  future. 

Thanks  to  encouragement  from  Mr.  Stenholm  and  other  members  of  this  Committee,  FCIC 
fortunately  has  recognized  this  problem  and  has  developed  an  actuarily  sound  proposal  that  is 
still  under  consideration.  This  proposal  would  allow  actual  yields  in  disaster  years  to  be 
compared  to  various  percentages  of  "T"  or  "D"  yields,  depending  upon  the  number  of  years 
records  are  available,  using  the  higher  of  the  two.  This  would  increase  the  level  of  coverage 
available  while  maintaining  the  concept  of  actual  production  history.  Premium  ratings  would 
continue  to  be  based  on  actual  production.  Upon  initial  review  by  our  industry,  this  approach 
has  merit. 

Another  suggestion  that  would  enhance  insurance  reform  would  he  the  addition  of  a  harvest 
incentive  when  determining  losses.  Currentiy  disaster  programs  contain  provisions  that  allow 
crop  production  to  be  zeroed  out  wiUiout  harvesting  if  production  estimates  are  less  than  harvest 
costs  A  similar  provision  is  needed  for  crop  insurance.  However,  to  prevent  inaccurate 
estimates  of  production,  the  application  of  harvest  yield  costs  need  modification 
One  method  would  be  to  allow  producers  to  harvest  a  crop  and  receive  credit  for  Uie  harvest 
cost    That  is  to  say,  a  producer  would  not  have  to  count  the  producUon  equated  to  the  cost  of 


81-128  0-94-10 


284 


harvest  against  any  loss.  This  would  provide  an  incentive  to  harvest.  FCIC  along  with 
universities  and  other  government  agencies  would  have  to  determine  appropriate  harvest  cost 
yields  for  each  region  as  harvest  methods  vary.  Consideration  could  also  be  given  for  third 
party  verification  on  zero  or  disaster  yields.  This  would  strengthen  the  credibility  of  the 
program  and  improve  loss  histories.  In  addition  to  improving  the  program,  harvest  incentives 
benefit  the  processing  and  marketing  industry  segments. 

FCIC  is  to  be  commended  for  their  continued  evaluation  of  optional  products  that  enhance  the 
value  of  crop  insurance  to  the  producer.  One  of  the  points  made  at  many  of  the  regional 
meetings  was  the  need  to  have  programs  that  entice  non-users  of  the  current  program.  We  are 
encouraged  with  programs  such  as  price  insurance  supplements  and  group  risk  programs.  One 
concept  that  is  particularly  interesting  to  our  industry  is  a  program  based  on  insuring  cost  of 
production.  Our  industry  is  in  the  very  early  stages  of  developing  this  concept,  but  believe  it 
is  viable.  An  individualized  approach  to  insuring  revenue  losses  relative  to  some  level  of  cost 
of  production  will  be  attractive  to  many  regions  of  the  cottonbelt  currently  not  utilizing  crop 
insurance  programs.  We  have  received  encouragement  from  FCIC  Manager  Ackerman  to 
continue  to  pursue  this  approach,  and  such  work  is  underway.  Other  points  brought  out  in  the 
meetings  were  the  need  to  provide  lower  premiums  for  producers  with  good  loss  histories  or 
with  lower  risk  operations.  FCIC  formerly  had  a  "good  experience"  discount  but  discontinued 
the  practice.  In  fact  some  producers  still  have  this  better  rate  because  of  grandfathered  clauses. 
We  recommend  that  this  practice  be  re-instituted.  Consideration  should  also  be  given  to 
premium  setting  flexibility  on  irrigated  operations.  For  instance,  in  Western  cotton  growing 
regions,  irrigation  is  the  norm  and,  therefore,  results  in  less  risk  firom  weather.  They  are  also 
highly  mobile  and  would  support  a  provision  allowing  individuals  to  transfer  actual  production 
histories  to  similarly  classed  farms  rather  than  being  treated  a  "new"  fanner  and  being  assigned 
an  insured  yield  of  65%  of  the  D  yield.  Participation  would  increase  if  these  matters  received 
attention. 

Often  losses  in  crop  quality  are  more  economically  devastating  than  production  losses- 
Improvements  in  the  quality  adjustment  provisions  for  cotton  are  needed  to  make  it  more 
effective.  USDA  has  developed  a  universally-accepted  cotton  classification  system  that  very 
accurately  describes  the  quality  of  our  product.  Upon  review  of  the  current  cotton  quality 
adjustment  procedure,  we  believe  a  better  utilization  of  this  classification  system  rather  than  spot 
price  differences  would  better  reflect  quality  losses.  We  are  in  the  process  of  analyzing  the  way 
the  current  program  is  being  administered  to  determine  how  it  can  be  refined.  We  hope  to  have 
this  analysis  completed  soon  with  recommendations  on  what  changes  are  needed.  We  think  this 
is  an  area  where  we  can  actually  save  the  program  money  by  better  insuring  quality  losses  due 
to  damaging  weather.  We  also  support  eliminating  the  current  25  %  deductible  for  quality  losses 
that  is  unique  only  to  cotton. 

The  current  Administration  proposal  only  applies  to  a  producer's  acreage  on  a  county  basis  and 
does  not  address  farm  units  (i.e.  fields  or  sections').  Effectively,  this  could  mean  that  an 
irrigated  farmer  could  pay  the  same  premium  as  a  non-irrigated  farmer  although  the  risk  is 
considerably  less.  While  we  realize  that  this  will  impact  how  the  subsidy  is  distributed,  we 
maintain  that  consideration  of  smaller  better  defined  units  will  improve  the  program  and  make 
it  more  effective. 


285 

For  crop  insurance  reform  to  be  successful,  credibility  must  be  restored  to  the  program.  Abuse 
of  the  program  must  be  minimized.  FCIC  recognizes  this  liability  and  is  seeking  ways  to 
strengthen  its  review.  We  support  effective  oversight  so  that  benefits  accrue  to  those  who 
deserve  it. 

Thank  you  again,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  allowing  me  to  present  testimony  here  today  on  behalf  of 
the  cotton  industry.  We  have  a  vested  interest  in  a  workable  program  both  as  farmers  and  as 
taxpayers.  We  have  received  good  cooperation  from  FCIC  on  cotton  industry  concerns  with  the 
administration  proposal  and  we  look  forward  to  working  with  this  Subcommittee  and  the  Full 
Committee  on  Crop  Insurance  Reform.  I  would  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions  that  you  or 
the  other  members  of  the  Subcommittee  might  have. 


286 


National  Family  Farm  Coalition 

no  Maryland  Avenue,  NE,  Suite  307   •   Washington,   DC  20002    •    (202)  543-5675    •    Fax:  (202)  543-0978 

Testimony  of  Katherine  Ozer 
on  behalf  of  the  National  Family  Farm  Coalition 

before  the 
Environment,  Credit,  and  Rural  Development  Subcommittee 
of  the  House  Agriculture  Committee  on 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 
April  21,  1994 

My  name  is  Kathy  Ozer.   I  am  the  Director  of  the  National 
Family  Farm  Coalition  (NFFC)  which  represents  39  family  farm  and 
rural  advocacy  organizations  in  30  states.   Our  organization  was 
formed  in  1986  to  provide  both  a  link  and  a  voice  for  family 
farmers  in  the  debate  over  federal  farm  and  food  policy. 

I  cun  testifying  here  today  to  strongly  support  a  change  in 
the  way  the  federal  government  prepares  for  and  responds  to 
disasters  which  strike  at  the  livelihood  of  family  farmers. 
Farmers  need  a  farm  policy  that  works  and  a  disaster  and/or 
insurance  program  that  is  accessible  and  affordable.   If  farmers 
received  a  fair  price  at  a  level  that  more  closely  meets  their 
cost  of  production,  it  would  be  more  plausible  that  a  "bad"  year 
is  not  as  economically  devastating. 

The  NFFC  supports  the  USDA  proposed  disaster  and  crop 
insurance  program  with  a  few  changes .   We  support  the  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  provision  that  would  require 
catastrophic  coverage  for  participants  in  any  farm  program.   The 
package  of  coverage  needs  to  provide  economic  security  for 
producers  of  all  crops  and  in  all  regions.   A  concern  is  what 
level  of  loss  does  this  catastrophic  level  translate  into?   Our 
understanding  is  that  it  would  trigger  in  once  a  farmer  has  lost 
50%  of  production  and  pay  at  60%  of  the  price.   This  price 
however  could  fluctuate  and  could  be  lower  than  the  target  price. 

Would  the  funds  needed  to  meet  these  losses  be  considered  an 
entitlement  in  the  budget  in  exchange  for  removing  the  emergency 
off-budget  nature  of  current  agriculture  disaster  proposals?   If 
not,  this  government  disaster  level  could  be  reduced  by  a  formula 
based  on  the  availability  of  limited  resources  which  would 
undermine  the  whole  system. 

The  other  major  question  that  has  been  raised  by  our 
Disaster  Task  Force  that  has  reviewed  the  proposal  is:  What 
happens  before  the  catastrophic  disaster  coverage  kicks  in?   Our 
understanding  is  that  private  crop  insurance  sold  through  crop 
insurance  agents  or  ASCS  would  be  available.   The  critical 


recycled  paper 


287 


question  is,  "at  what  price?"   Our  concern  is  on  the  price  to  the 
farmer  struggling  to  meet  cash-flow  and  budget  projections  and  to 
the  federal  government  in  the  form  of  subsidy  payments  to  provide 
the  insurance.   It  is  in  this  area  that  we  have  come  up  with  a 
proposal  to  help  farmers  "self-insure"  against  some  of  th\eir 
possible  losses.   It  would  be  through  an  expansion  of  the  current 
Farmer  Owned  Reserve  to  make  it  into  a  true  disaster  reserve. 
This  reserve  could  be  released  by  ASCS  when  and  only  when  a 
certain  loss  level  had  been  reached  on  the  individual  farm  or 
within  a  county.   We  would  propose  that  it  be  in  the  65-70%  production 
level.  In  these  cases,  a  farmer  could  still  purchase  crop 
insurance  to  protect  against  initial  losses  before  the  65%  level. 
The  grain  taken  out  of  reserve  would  then  be  available  for 
orderly  marketing. 

We  propose  to  establish  a  level  of  bushels  of  each  commodity 
that  the  government  wants  to  have  on  reserve  and  off  the  market. 
The  grain  in  the  disaster  reserve  would  not  be  eligible  for  a 
loan.  Farmers  could  be  eligible  for  a  cost-share  payment  to  build 
or  maintain  high  quality  grain  storage.   Farmers  would  continue 
to  receive  the  farmer  storage  rate  instead  of  the  higher 
commercial  rate.   We  know  that  our  proposal  is  more  easily 
applicable  to  wheat  and  feed-grains  and  some  other  storable 
commodities  but  feel  that  it  should  be  considered  as  part  of  the 
package  as  we  address  the  different  options  that  could  work 
together  to  cushion  the  weather  risk. 

We  would  ask  that  the  Subcommittee  look  at  the  costs  to  the 
federal  government  of  the  insurance  subsidy  for  wheat  and  feed- 
grains  for  this  range  of  protection  in  contrast  to  the  costs  of 
an  expanded  grain  reserve.   As  part  of  this  analysis,  we  would 
also  request  the  impact  on  net  farm  income  if  a  farmer  had  these 
two  types  of  coverage  and  the  same  level  of  loss. 

Who  needs  to  be  covered?   These  programs  need  to  respond  to 
the  family  farmer  who  has  made  the  transition  from  corn  and 
soybeans  to  growing  produce  for  a  local  farmers'  market  as  well 
as  the  diversified  farmer  who  milks  50  cows  and  raises  100  acres 
of  corn  but  still  buys  hay  for  feed.   Beginning  farmers  or 
farmers  making  the  transition  from  conventional  farming  practices 
to  low  or  no  chemical  use  must  not  be  penalized  by  a  long 
requirement  of  4-10  years  of  personal  crop  history  to  avoid  a  set 
reduction  of  35%.   Minority  farmers  who  have  historically  been 
under-represented  in  farm  credit  and  federal  farm  programs  should 
not  be  doubly  hit  by  loss  of  coverage  in  a  disaster.   These  are 
the  farming  businesses  and  operations  that  all  too  often  are 
already  the  most  vulnerable  due  to  other  situations.   These  new 
programs  need  to  minimize  the  risks  not  increase  them. 

Last  summer,  the  flood  in  the  Midwest  and  drought  in  the 
Southeast  became  the  priority  issue  for  our  organizations 
throughout  the  country.   It  has  been  as  crisis/credit 
intervention,  pushing  for  legislative  and  administrative  changes 


288 


in  the  disaster  program,  and  educating  farmers  and  others  in  the 
rural  community  about  what  is  and  should  be  available.    The 
impacts  of  last  years  weather  is  felt  far  beyond  the  flood 
waters.   Every  dairy  and  livestock  farmer  has  been  facing 
increasing  feed  costs.   For  those  who  produced  hay  crops  without 
value,  USDA  stated  that  they  couldn't  produce  a  formula  to 
calculate  loss  and  there  was  still  some  value  in  that  it  could  be 
used  as  "bedding". 

It  has  been  a  frustrating  process  to  say  the  least.   In 
Missouri,  where  yesterday's  Washington  Post  talks  of  33%  of  the 
nation's  $10  billion  of  flood  losses;  there  were  only  241 
applications  for  FmHA  emergency  loan.  Of  these,  67  have  been 
approved.   There  are  only  two  small  areas  in  Missouri  that  are 
still  accepting  applications.  2.1  million  crop  acres  were  lost 
last  year.   Is  this  low  application  rate  due  to  lack  of 
information  or  frustration?   I  certainly  doubt  it  is  due  to 
existing  disaster  coverage  and  crop  insurance  premiums  providing 
enough  to  keep  farm  businesses  going.   In  fact  most  of  these 
farmers  have  no  idea  whether  they  will  be  able  to  grow  a  crop 
this  summer  or  have  access  to  credit  to  purchase  inputs.   In  Iowa 
over  2,000  farmers  filed  FmHA  Emergency  Loan  applications  on  the 
deadline.   For  many  others  the  information  about  having  to  pledge 
150%  of  ones  assets  for  every  $1  of  the  loan  created  a  barrier. 
FmHA  sensibly  reduced  that  level  to  $1  of  security  for  every  $1 
of  loan  but  this  change  didn't  take  effect  until  after  the 
application  deadline  for  most  states. 

The  disasters  of  1993  put  the  capacity  of  USDA  and  other 
government  agency  disaster  response  systems  on  the  line.   In  many 
cases  they  failed  miserably.  What  is  the  responsibility  of  USDA 
to  publicize  and  inform  farmers  and  their  communities  about  these 
deadlines  and  changes?   Are  local  offices  even  aware  of  the 
changes?   Are  there  informative  and  accurate  materials 
distributed  by  USDA  to  help  farmers  understand  and  decipher  the 
maze  of  rules,  regulations,  and  deadlines  that  govern  these 
programs?  We  would  contend  that  USDA  needs  to  make  it  much 
easier  for  farmers  to  access  their  programs  and  become  much  more 
farmer- friendly.   Farmers  Legal  Action  Group  (FLAG)  produced  an 
excellent  Farmers  Guide  to  Disaster  Assistance.   These  types  of 
manuals  need  to  be  supported  by  USDA  and  to  ensure  its 
dissemination  to  farmers  and  agency  personnel. 

It  is  now  -  the  spring  of  1994  when  farmers  are  trying  to 
obtain  credit  and  assess  the  real  damage  of  the  past  year.   FmHA 
is  now  starting  to  foreclose  after  their  March  1994  lifting  of 
their  year-long  "suspension"  which  could  hit  many  of  the  same 
farmers  with  a  double  whammy.   In  addition,  there  is  legislation 
brewing  to  make  changes  in  FmHA  debt  restructuring  resulting  from 
their  credit  reviews  but  primarily  prompted  by  the  "wealthy  FmHA 
borrower"  press  from  late  January.   We  are  concerned  that  these 
changes  not  remove  existing  borrower  rights  from  farmer/borrowers 
in  the  rush  to  change  the  system. 


289 


NFFC  supports  a  comprehensive  approach  to  disaster  and  farm 
policy  that  helps  to  ensure  that  family  farmers  do  survive.  We 
urge  you  to  continue  asking  these  important  questions  and  find 
the  answers.   The  policy  put  in  place  now  must  work  to  make  sure 
that  natural  disasters  do  not  force  farmers  out  of  business,  just 
like  an  insurance  system  helps  to  ensure  that  fire,  loss,  or 
disaster  should  not  make  me  homeless.   We  are  talking  about 
homes,  jobs,  and  livelihoods  that  are  very  vulnerable  due  to 
current  inadequacies  in  the  crop  insurance  and  disaster 
provisions.   We  look  forward  to  working  with  this  Subcommittee  on 
this  important  issue  and  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  present 
this  testimony.   I  would  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions. 


290 


STATEMENT  OF  THE  AMERICAN  FARM  BUREAU  FEDERATION 

TO  THE  SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT  AND  RURAL 

DEVELOPMENT  OF  THE  HOUSE  COMMITTEE  ON 

AGRICULTURE 

REGARDING  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE 

Presented  by 

Doyle  Rallies,  President,  Kansas  Farm  Bureau, 
and  Member,  AFBF  Board  of  Directors 

Mr.  Chairman,  thank  you  for  this  opportimity  to  testify  on  crop  insurance 
legislation  on  behalf  of  the  American  Farm  Bureau  Federation  with  its  4.2  million 
family  members  from  across  the  nation. 

My  name  is  Doyle  Rahjes,  and  I  am  the  president  of  the  Kansas  Farm 
Bureau  and  a  member  of  the  Board  of  Directors  of  the  American  Farm  Bureau 
Federation. 

As  a  member  of  the  National  Commission  for  the  Improvement  of  the  Crop 
Insurance  Program,  which  completed  its  work  in  July,  1989,  I  hope  to  share  with 
you  both  my  experience  there  and  my  activities  on  crop  insurance  within  the 
Kansas  and  American  Farm  Bureaus. 

At  the  AFBF  1994  Annual  Meeting  held  in  Ft.  Lauderdale,  Florida,  the 
voting  delegates  reaffirmed  our  long-standing  policy  that  crop  disaster  programs 
and  crop  insurance  should  be  combined  into  a  single  program  designed  to  obtain 
the  greatest  amount  of  participation. 

That  is  why  we  feel  the  objectives  and  the  techniques  of  the 
administration's  crop  insurance  proposal  are  worthy  of  serious  consideration  by 
Congress. 

We  do,  however,  have  some  reservations  about  certain  provisions  in  the 
proposal  that  we  feel  are  contrary  to  achieving  full  participation  and  which  apply 
tinnecessary  eligibility  tests  that  would  further  discourage  fUl  participation  in 
both  the  crop  insurance  and  the  price  support  programs. 

Farm  Bureau  policy  is  very  clear  that  participation  in  a  crop  insurgmce 
program  should  remain  voluntary  and  that  there  should  be  no  mandatory  linkages 
between  farm  program  participation  and  Farmers  Home  Administration  loan 
eligibility  and  crop  insurance.  The  current  proposal  does  not  satisfy  that 
requirement.   Even  though  the  linkage  in  the  proposed  program  is  limited  to 
participation  in  the  catastrophic  coverage  portion  of  the  crop  insurance  program  at 
a  nominal  fee,  it  establishes  a  mechanism  that  coidd  become  very  burdensome  for 


291 


producers.   Moreover,  we  are  concerned  that  the  nominal  costs  of  the  mandatory 
portion  of  the  program  would  set  a  precedent  for  the  futvu-e.   A  cap  on 
participation  fees  for  catastrophic  coverage  which  is  set  at  $100  today  could 
escalate  rapidly  under  future  budget  pressures,  yet  producers  would  be  required  to 
participate  whether  or  not  they  get  any  real  individual  benefits  from  the  program. 
In  brief,  we  believe  that  a  well-designed  and  attractive  volimtary  program  will 
work  much  better.  Voluntary  access  and  freedom  to  participate  always  win  over 
government  coercion. 

Another  important  concern  is  the  linkage  between  crop  insurance  and  farm 
program  participation.  If  this  linkage  is  made,  then  Congress  would  face  a  very 
difficult  task  of  making  sure  that  appropriate  measures  are  taken  to  isolate  the 
catastrophic  portion  of  the  coverage  from  future  budget  reconciUation 
considerations.   About  $700  million  in  new  money  is  being  requested  by  the  House 
for  the  crop  insurance  reform  effort  based  on  previous  program  crop  expenditures 
resulting  from  ad  hoc  disaster  legislation.   There  is  concern  that  if  funding 
remains  at  the  $700  million  level,  non-program  crops  might  be  treated  inequitably. 
If  there  were  farm  program  crop  overruns  (particularly  if  parliamentary  changes 
make  it  increasingly  difficult  to  pass  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  for  non-insured 
crops),  then  non-covered  crops  would  likely  receive  reduced  or  pro  rated  benefits. 

We  have  a  number  of  specific  concerns  about  the  levels  of  coverage.  First, 
the  50  percent  yield  loss  provision  of  the  "basic  coverage"  provides  substantially 
less  coverage  for  moderate  losses  than  disaster  programs  that  have  been 
implemented  in  recent  years.  In  other  words,  disaster  fiinding  has  been  applied  to 
losses  below  65  percent  of  normal  production,  whereas  the  proposed  crop 
instirance  reform  "kicks  in"  only  for  yield  losses  greater  than  50  percent.  Another 
shortcoming  of  the  crop  insurance  reform  package  is  its  reUance  on  yield  as  a 
trigger  mechanism  for  insurance  payout. 

Farm  Bureau  strongly  favors  coverage  based  on  dollars  per  acre  rather  than 
yield.   Reliance  on  yield  as  a  trigger  mechanism  tends  to  skew  the  program  in 
favor  of  high-risk  production  acres  and  makes  it  much  more  likely  that  gaps  in 
coverage  will  exit. 

Second,  with  respect  to  the  "buy  up"  provisions,  it  is  unclear  as  to  where, 
and  from  whom,  producers  must  purchase  this  coverage.   Here  there  is  another 
potential  gap  in  coverage.     By  virtue  of  it  being  a  yield-triggered  pay  versus  a 
dollar  per  acreage  coverage,  even  if  narrowly  drawn,  there  is  an  invitation  for 
future  retrenchment  of  program  benefits,  and  as  such  make  the  overall  crop 
insurance  plan  less  effective  when  the  day  comes  that  a  future  Congress  will  be 
urged  to  provide  disaster  relief  beyond  that  provided  by  the  crop  insurance 
program. 


292 


Finally,  there  are  a  number  of  provisions  in  the  administration's  proposal  in 
Section  522,  the  "non-insured  assistance  program"  that  we  view  with  great 
concern.  They  include: 

" (8)  A  person  who  has  qualiiying  gross  revenues  in  excess 

of  $2  million  annually,  as  determined  by  the  Secretary,  shall  not  be 
eligible  to  receive  any  non-insured  payment." 

This  section  then  goes  on  to  define  "qualifying  gross  revenue". 

Granted,  the  scope  of  this  language  is  fairly  narrow,  and  the  $2  milUon 
threshold  might  appear  to  many  observers  as  high,  there  is  great  mischief  afoot  in 
establishing  a  "means  test"  in  tiiis  legislation. 

Veteran  members  of  this  committee  will  recall  the  1990  Farm  Bill  debate 
and  the  floor  struggle  necessary  to  avoid  a  much  lower  $100,000  means  test 
amendment  for  price  support  program  eUgibihty. 

It  seems  obvious  to  us  that  the  $2  million  level  or  any  stated  level  will 
become  an  early  and  easy  target  for  budget  cutters. 

Another  troublesome  provision  in  Section  522  also  states  as  follows: 

"(e) payment  limitations  -  (1)  The  total  amovmt  of  payments 

that  a  person  shall  be  entitled  to  receive  annually  under  this 
section  may  not  exceed  $100,000." 

The  section  goes  on  to  define  "person"  along  the  same  lines  as  now  apply  to 
price  support  programs. 

Finally,  the  language  regarding  the  estimation  of  yields  by  averaging 
observations  from  a  minimum  of  four  previous  crop  years  needs  to  be  clarified  for 
fruits  and  vegetables.   For  some  fruit  and  vegetable  operations  in  the  more 
temperate  climatic  zones,  there  may  be  several  crops  planted  sequentially  in  the 
same  calendar  year.   In  light  of  this,  is  the  intent  of  the  legislation  really  yields  of 
crops  planted  in  "four  continuous  crop  years,"  or  "four  consecutive  crop  plantings?" 

In  summary,  Mr.  Chairman,  we  feel  this  proposal  has  many  attractive 
features,  and  the  basic  idea  behind  it  is  sound. 

However,  we  hope  you  and  the  rest  of  Congress  will  amend  it  by  deleting  or 
changing  the  provisions  we  find  covinter  productive  and  unfair. 


293 


TESTIMONY  OF  LELAND  SWENSON,  PRESIDENT  OF  THE  NATIONAL 
FARMERS  UNION,  REGARDING  CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM,  PRESENTED 
TO  THE  HOUSE  AGRICULTURE  SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT, 
CONSERVATION,  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT. 

On  behalf  of  the  250,000  families  of  the  National  Farmers 
Union  I  wish  to  thank  you  for  holding  this  hearing  on  H.R. 
4217  and  the  reform  of  federal  crop  insurance.   Delegates 
to  our  92nd  annual  convention  held  this  spring  in  Fargo, 
North  Dakota,  expressed  strong  support  for  improving  crop 
insurance  with  the  addition  of  catastrophic  coverage. 
Attached  as  exhibit  A  is  a  copy  of  the  special  order  of 
business  from  the  delegates. 

My  testimony  today  will  address  the  following  items 
included  in  the  H.R.  4217: 

1.  Repeal  of  ad  hoc  disaster 

2.  Establishment  of  catastrophic  coverage 

3 .  Linkage  to  farm  programs 

4.  Delivery  system  of  crop  insurance 

5.  Industry  competition 

6.  Assistance  for  uninsurable  crops 

7.  Actuarial  soundness 

8.  Budget  authority 

9.  Adequacy  of  higher  levels  of  coverage 

10.   Federal  Crop  Insurance  Advisory  Committee 

Repeal  of  Ad  Hoc  Disaster  -  National  Farmers  Union 

supports  the  repeal  of  ad  hoc  disaster  authority  if 

catastrophic  insurance  is  made  available  to  producers  at 
an  affordable  price. 

The  Adequacy  of  Catastrophic  Coverage  -  H.R.  4  217  would 
provide  protection  against  losses  greater  than  50  percent, 
at  a  payment  rate  of  60  percent  of  the  expected  market 
price.   This  yields  coverage  of  about  $.30  per  dollar  of 
loss  in  a  complete  disaster  year. 

The  proposed  level  of  coverage  compares  to  the  1993 
disaster  program  which  paid  $.42  per  dollar  of  loss,  and 
the  1992  program  which  paid  $.19  -  $.21  per  dollar  of 
loss,  depending  on  whether  the  producer  had  purchased  crop 
insurance . 

The  adequacy  of  the  catastrophic  coverage  will  depend  on 
how  losses  are  calculated,  as  well  as  how  the  payment  rate 
is  determined.   We  support  the  provision  which  allows 
producers  to  choose  whether  to  use  actual  production 
history  (APH)  or  area  yield.   We  would  like  to  strengthen 
the  language  to  require  that  both  are  offered.   We  further 
recommend  that  APH  should  be  calculated  by  excluding 
production  from  disaster-declared  years. 


294 


We  also  recommend  that  the  payment  rate  is  increased  to 
100  percent  of  the  expected  market  price. 

Linkage  to  Farm  Programs  -  We  support  offering  crop 
insurance  as  a  benefit  of  farm  program  participation.   We 
further  support  requiring  participation  at  the 
catastrophic  level,  as  long  as  the  cost  of  participation 
is  limited  to  $50  per  crop,  per  county,  with  a  cap  of  $100 
per  producer  per  county. 

Delivery  System  -  Dual  delivery  offers  producers  the 
option  of  where  to  obtain  the  catastrophic  coverage.   It 
also  raises  some  questions.   Who  will  do  the  adjusting? 
Who  will  pay  the  administrative  cost  if  the  producer 
obtains  coverage  from  both  Farm  Service  Agency  and  the 
private  agent? 

We  support  providing  additional  coverage  through  a  private 
agent.   We  also  support  waiving  the  administrative  fee  for 
those  who  sign  up  for  coverage  greater  than  the 
catastrophic  level . 

Industry  Competition  -  We  support  allowing  private 
insurance  companies  to  compete  on  lower  rates  and  increase 
the  level  of  available  coverage. 

Assistance  for  Uninsurable  Crops  -  We  support  providing  a 
permanent  disaster  program  for  uninsurable  crops. 
However,  we  believe  a  producer  should  establish  a  crop 
production  history  before  becoming  eligible  for  disaster 
assistance.   This  will  prevent  producers  from  farming  the 
program. 

Actuarial  Soundness  -  We  support  the  goal  of  approaching 
actuarial  soundness.   We  believe  this  will  be  better 
accomplished  by  implementing  the  use  of  actual  production 
history. 

Budget  Authority  -  We  support  increasing  the  budget 
authority  to  accommodate  the  funding  request  of  the 
Administration.   We  would  point  out  the  additional 
spending  will  result  in  savings  of  $750  million  to  $1 
billion,  over  a  five  year  time  period. 

Adequacy  of  Higher  Levels  of  Coverage  -  We  believe  that 
crop  insurance  will  not  provide  adequate  loss  protection 
unless  producers  participate  in  levels  of  coverage  higher 
that  the  catastrophic  coverage.   We  believe  coverage 
should  be  available  to  allow  the  producer  to  cover  the 
cost  of  production,  including  yield  coverage  at  the  65, 
75,  and  85  percent  levels. 

We  further  recommend  that  a  premium  subsidy  is  offered  to 
encourage  producers  to  participate  at  these  higher  levels. 


295 


Producer  participation  in  the  catastrophic  level  alone 
will  provide  insufficient  loss  protection  and  will  create 
a  demand  for  disaster  assistance. 

We  support  provisions  in  the  bill  which  require  producers 
to  be  offered  coverage  for  loss  of  yield  and  prevented 
planting. 

We  support  the  provision  which  allows  the  producer  to 
choose  between  APH  or  area  yield  when  both  are  available. 
However,  we  would  like  to  go  an  additional  step  by 
requiring  that  both  be  made  available. 

Federal  Advisory  Committee  -  We  support  the  establishment 
of  the  Advisory  Committee  for  Federal  Crop  Insurance. 
However,  we  recommend  requiring  that  at  least  half  the 
board  be  comprised  of  family  farmers. 

Stimmarv 

We  offer  our  strong  support  for  the  reform  of  crop 
insurance  and  we  stand  ready  to  work  with  the 
Administration  and  Congress  to  ensure  that  the  final  bill 
will  address  the  needs  of  producers  as  well  as  minimize 
budget  exposure. 


(Attachnent  foll-ows:) 


-3- 


296 

Special  Order  of  Business 
Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform 


We  commend  the  Administration  for  supporting  the  reform  of 
the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  program. 

We  support  provisions  which  would  orovide  catastrophic 
coverage  as  a  requirement  of  participation  in  commodity 
programs  or  Farmers  Home  Administration  lending  programs. 

We  support  allowing  producers  to  base  yield  coverage  on 
actual  production  history  (APH). 

We  support  offering  producers  assistance  to  purchase 
coverage  above  the  catastrophic  level. 

We  support  offering  coverage  for  late  or  prevented 

planting. 

We  call  on  Congress  to  make  the  following  additions  to  the 
above-stated  provisions: 

1.  We  support  allowing  producers  to  exclude  disaster 
years  from  APH  calculation. 

2.  We  support  adding  an  additional  level  of  coverage 
higher  than  the  75  percent  level. 

3.  We  support  basing  expected  price  on  the  higher  of  the 
target  price  or  the  5  year  rolling  average  of  the  12  month 
market  price. 

4.  We  support  requiring  insurance  companies  to  offer  both 
APH  and  area  yield  options  to  producers. 

5.  We  support  maintaining  the  Secretary's  authority  to 
call  for  disaster  assistance  if  needed,  recognizing  that 
these  reform  provisions  will  significantly  reduce  the  need 
for  disaster  assistance. 


National  Farmers  Union  Convention 
Special  Order  of  Business 
Adopted  March  7,  1994 


Exhibit  A 


297 

STATEMENT  OF 

MICHAEL  CONNEALY 

RmAL  COMMUNITY  INSITIANCE  SERVICES,  INC. 

BEFORE  THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT,  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT. 
COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE,  US.  HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

APRIL  21.  1994   ^ 

Mr.  Chairman  and  Members  of  the  Subcommittee: 

On  behalf  of  Rural  Community  Insurance  Services,  Inc  ,  we  appreciate  the  oppom»ruT>-  to 
taetify  b«fora  this  Subcommittee  concerning  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of 
1994  Rural  Community  Insurance  Services  is  a  whoUy-owTicd  subsidiary  of  Norwest 
Corporation,  a  bank  holding  company  Norwesi,  as  a  principal  provider  of  farm  operaiing 
loans  to  those  in  rural  communities  and  businesses  that  support  rural  communities, 
considers  the  crop  insurance  program  to  be  an  eisential  part  of  the  fabric  of  those 
communities.  It  is  'out  hope  that  a  concrete  and  meaningful  crop  insurance  prograin  can 
be  continued  by  Congress  regardless  of 'reform"  This  proposal  addresses  many  of  our 
concerns,  and  thank  you  for  the  invitation  and  the  oppormnity  to  share  our  thoughts  with 
you  today. 

Mr.  Chaiinun,  we  would  like  to  begin  by  addressing  individually  t.Kt  twelve  issues  that 
you  posed  in  your  letter  of  April  8th. 

•  file  adequacy  of  prcmiam  nibiidiet  for  catastropliic  and  boy-op  cowrj**  for  injnrable  crops 

It  is  our  position  that  the  premium  subsidies  are  more  than  adequate  to  encourage 
participation  (jovemment,  in  this  case,  can  "lead  a  horse  to  water,"  and  ihc  subsidy 
can't  be  cjcpected  to  do  more  than  that.  The  current  converiuonal  program  is 
adequately  subsidized  in  our  opinion.  Ta.xpaycrs  should  not  be  expeaed  to  do  much 
more  for  this  "self  hdp"  program,  in  our  opinion. 

•  Tbe  praeeMiBf  fc*  «»$S0  per  producer  per  crop  per  countjr,  not  »  mtti\  SlOO  per  producer  per 
csoBt; 

We  feel  that  a  fee  is  appropriate  for  the  farmer  to  pay.  however.  urJes?  all  the 
expenses  can  be  reimbursed  to  agems  and  companies  for  administering  this  level  of 
coverage,  we  feel  private  sector  delivery  of  the  "caustrophic-  coverage  will  oe 
inhibited. 


298 


•  Tke  rMpiiremait  for  prodnoert  to  obtaia  cUMtrophic  emtntf  to  be  disibte  for  pries  support, 
prodacthM  tdiuitnieiit  tad  conienrttion  programi 

We  are  not  opposed  to  this  requirement;  however,  we  could  see  where  8  "vnuvcr '  of 
some  oature  could  be  considered  to  reduce  administraavc  costs  where  "low 
leveraged"  projducers  are  concerned.  A  "waiver"  would  forfeit  all  benefits  to  any  son 
of  disaster"  declaraticm. 

•  Th«  diul  dolivory  wyttmMt  CAtaotropbic  coverag*  miy  b«  porcbaacd  ciiber  at  USDA  tcrvicc 
caotart  or  tbroncji  piivata  ounrwica  agents;  additional  coverage  maj  be  porchased  oaly  f ron 
privata  agBBti 

The  expense  required  to  enable  the  ASCS  offices  to  "sell"  this  catastrophic  coxerage 
nrijitt  prove  to  be  a  concern;  however,  in  light  of  the  limited  expenses  allowed  the 
private  sector,  !the  dual  delivery  system  can't  be  arg;ued  against  It  is  our  position  that 
requiring  the  purdiase  of  additional  coverage  through  private  agents  will  work  well, 
as  the  dclivciy  system  already  exists.  This  is  essential  to  the  program,  making  sure 
that  decent  "buy  ups"  are  available  We  must  focus  our  efforts  on  those  producers 
that  need  "real"  coverage. 

•  Tbc  luc  of  actaal  production  bistory  (APff)  for  the  4  prcvioiu  crop  ya*rs,  baQding  up  to  10  yeant, 
and  tba  um  of  traa^iooal  yi«id«  fT-yUldi)  if  APH  ii  not  available 

This  idea  is  acceptable,  as  long  as  precautions  are  taken  in  design  to  avoid  skcwjig 
the  formulas  against  those  faimcrs  who  are  new  producers,  are  adding  new  land,  or 
have  suffered  catastrophic  loss  years.  This  is  true  for  ratLng  issues  as  well 

•  Tbc  prwisioDS  foritonittiurabk  crops 

Due  to  the  inherent  business  risk  that  is  part  of  the  nature  of  agriculture,  rt  would  be 
hard  to  axBue  fiar  goveniment  involvement  in  such  instances  Utere  there  ;s  no  aop 
insurance  proffram,  there  is  usually  a  good  reason.,  let's  look  at  the  economic  impact 
of ''with  or  without"  govemmeDt  involvement  We  could  do  well  not  to  "mess  up" 
p^iere  were  not  needed.... 

•  The  likelibood  that  ad  hoc  disaster  prosnuns  will  no  looser  be  available 

This  is  a  great  idea  that  we  hope  becomes  reality.  Ad  hoc  disaster  assisunce  should 
never  again  be  available  regardless  of  the  movement  on  the  crop  insurance  reform 
Self-help,  risk  retention,  and  discipline  should  provide  a  sufficient  backstop  for  those 
producers  who  now  enjoy  the  payments  provided  by  the  ad  hoc  disaster  programs 
These  payments  are  directed  to  many  who  have  a  'limited"  need  or  arc  doubled  vvith 
crop  insurance. 


299 


•  The  expaue  rdmbaneawBt  tarmuU  for  privMe  iniaraacs  conpuiw 

Our  studies  and  experience  have  shown  iJui  the  expense  reimburscinem  formula  is 
not  sufflciem  to  deliver  the  prograrc  with  the  degree  of  detail  and  integrit>  denur.dcd 
by  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  It  is  ou:  position  that  when  you  look 
carefully  at  all  of  the  costs  that  are  incurred,  the  govcmment  ii  getting  more  than  its 
moneys  worth.  The  operating  risks  are  so  great  that  50  pluj  prvat;  sector 
coatraaors  in  the  carij-  1980's  are  now  reduced  to  fewer  than  20  Our  (Rurai 
Conuaunity  Insurance  Services)  operating  losses  were  substantia]  in  1992  and  1993 
Loss  adjustment  e:q)enses  need  '"extra"  attention  for  integrity  purposes  F:nal!>,  it's 
time  to  STOP  taking  d»e  sales  and  procejsing  work  for  granted  —  curreniiy 
performed  by  our  local  tndep«Klent  agents.  These  laborers  arc  worth>  of  their  hire 
and  v.-e  need  to  keep  them  as  a  motivated  sales  force 

•  The  pnmsioa  to  allOM  prn-ate  insanace  coapmiet  to  lovrer  tbe  rates  cbarsed  lo  Droduccrs 

This  provision  is  not  in  anyone's  best  interests,  and  would  likely  encourage  rebates  by 
agents  as  well  as  other  avenues  of  unfair  discrimination.  Wc  can  thini;  of  no  reason  to 
pursue  this  issue. 

•  The  aon-sundard  dauiricatioa  lystcn 

It  is  our  position  that  the  rwrv-standard  classification  system  is  working  e.>.tmncl> 
wen.  As  long  as  the  system  is  "tested"  and  a  reasonable  appeal  process  is  in  place,  it 
protects  the  vast  majority  of  producers  from  the  bad  luck  or  the  "acts"  of  a  few 

•  Tbe  croup  riik  plaii 

The  program  works  adtnjuaidy  with  crop  programs  in  trouble,  such  as  Southeast 
soybeans  and  Midwest  fi>rage.  However,  for  most  of  the  crop  programs,  iht  group 
risk  plan  has  proven  to  be  a  questionable  use  of  moncj'.  resources,  and  time  m  cui 
opinion. 

•  The  market  value  protection  piaa 

We  agree  philosophically  that  the  govemmem  should  entenain  and  encourage  product 
development  in  the  private  seaor,  however,  attempts  should  also  be  made  to  enhance 
the  basic  crop  insurance  product  For  example,  with  an  enhanced  and  strengthened 
basic  product,  most  producers  who  buy  crop  insurance  would  need  fewer  products 
like  the  market  value  protection  plaa 


3      - 


300 


ADDITIONAL  COMMENTS. 


The  conventional  crop  insuranca  program  is  in  ecMntial  and  imponant  tool  to  Korwett  is 
a  lending  insdtutioii,  even  more  so  than  as  a  proccsjor  of  insurance  dccurimts  No^^^■cst 
is  conui^ed  to  rural  America;  we  are  said  to  be  the  second  largest  Ag  leader  in  rural 
communities  in  tlie  United  States  Whether  Norwest  lends  money  to  a  fiimily  farmer  or  to 
a  business  such  as  a  seed  or  fertilizer  dealer  that  sells  its  products  on  credit,  crop  insurance 
ultimately  provides  an  important  level  of  collateral,  especially  for  younger  farmers  v-hc  co 
•  not  yet  have  significant  equity  in  their  land  or  equipment 

The  crop  insurance  program  is  essential  to  the  creditworthmcss  of  these  Carmers  and. 
therefore,  to  the  viability'  of  our  rtiral  communities  and  towns  Those  conummiiies  and 
towns,  their  churches,  schools,  hospitals,  ar.d  businesses  ore  heavily  dependent  on  farm 
income,  and  therefore  arc  as  much  afiected  by  uninsured  natural  disasters  as  are  :bc 
fermers  whose  crops  have  been  destroyed.  The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  program  is  as 
much  their  risk  management  tool  as  it  is  for  the  farmers  who  purchase  the  policy 

If  conventional  crop  insurance  is  eliminated  or  signific&cdy  reduced  aj  s  source  o' 
collateral,  the  availability  of  credit  will  diminish  immediately  and  the  consequences  cf  each 
major  storm  or  drought  will  affect  not  onl>  unmsured  or  undcnnsured  £amner3  bu;  wdl 
resound  through  evety  rural  conununity.  This  is  "ESPECIALL"^"*  tnie  of  younger  fanners 
or  high  leverage  farmers  whom  we  should  try  to  help  Government  need  not  worry  abou: 
*Svealthy"  or  low  leverage  formers;  subaidv  dollars  arc  questionable  in  our  opinion,  when 

sent  to  [hose  who  don't  need  them. 

In  1992.  Norwest  had  a  national  loan  portfolio  of  about  $775,000,000  on  what  could  be 
described  as  land  or  operating  loans  including  FNIRA  guaranteed  loans  These  loans  were 
made  with  the  expectation  that  proceeds  from  the  sale  of  the  crops  were  going  to  repay 
the  loans  plus  ttic  interest.  "We  have  a  risk  rating  method  which  scores  the  loan  from  a 
high  of  "one"  to  a  low  of 'seven"  Those  operators  rated  as  "one,"  "two,"  or  "three" 
would  Ckely  not  be  adversely  aSeded  by  the  loss  of  a  meaningful  crop  insurance  program 
These  loans  amounted  to  $220,000,000  or  28  percent  of  the  toial  Those  rated  oj  "five.' 
"six,"  or  "seven"  would  most  likely  be  gone  from  the  portfolio  —  additionally,  we  would 
consider  reducing  or  dropping  Farmers  Home  Guarameed  Loans  These  amounted  to 
$157,000,000  or  20  percent  of  the  total.  Those  rated  as  a  "four,"  would  be  affected  by  a 
higher  rate,  reduced  operating  line,  or  no  loan  at  all  The  impact  of  this  52  percent  wou'd 
be  significant  and  costly  to  the  borrower,  and  uhimately  the  rural  community  in  which  they 
live. 

Norwest's  main  interest  in  the  crop  msurance  program  is  as  an  a£  lender,  and  our  main 
interest  in  the  re&mn  of  the  program  is  as  a  lender.  We  also  have  a  strong  interest  in 
genuine  refbnos  in  the  program  that  will  benefit  our  reinsurera,  our  fiimers,  and  our 
agents.  Each  pardcipant  of  this  program  needs  to  be  accountable  and  also  rewarded  for 
quality  pcrfonnance.  This  includes  &nners  with  low  levd  of  loss 


301 


Norwest  and  other  ag  lenders  (our  opinion)  already  require  crop  insurance  for  those  who 
are  in  financial  need;  and  if  there  were  a  choice  on  the  amount  of  reform,  our  preference 
would  be  to  keep  the  conventional  program  mtact  or  enhanced  (ejjk*  the  farmers  are 
already  comfortable  with  the  pro|xam,  see  the  benefits,  and  arc  partidpaiing)  before 
pushmg  ahead  with  a  great  deal  of  experimental  reform  Especially  refom  aur.cd  at  a 
"catastrophic  coverage"  that  amotmts  to  "0"  additional  ag  loans  emanating  from  the 
private  sector. 

Thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to  appear  before  the  Subcominittec,  and  I  would  be  happy 
to  answer  any  questions  that  you  may  have 


302 


Testimony  of 

John  H.  Joyce,  Chairman 

Robert  W.  Post,  Jr.,  Vice  Chairman 

on  behalf  of  the 

American  Association  of  Crop  Insurers 

Before  the  House  Agriculture  Subcommittee  on 
Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

Regarding  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994 

April  21,  1994 

Mr.  Chairman,  Mr.  Ranking  Member,  and  members  of  the  Subcommittee,  thank  you  for 
the  opportunity  to  present  our  views  on  H.R.  4217,  The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of 
1994.  These  views  are  expressed  on  behalf  of  the  American  Association  of  Crop  Insurers 
(AACI),  a  voluntary  membership  trade  association  of  the  private  crop  insurance  industry.  Our 
association  consists  of  insurance  companies,  private  reinsurers,  local  crop  insurance  agents  and 
adjusters. 

I  am  President  of  Rain  and  Hail  Insurance  Service,  Inc.  of  West  Des  Moines,  Iowa  which 
writes  federally  reinsured  multiple  peril  crop  insurance  (MPCI)  nationwide  as  well  as  private 
crop  hail,  and  fire  and  allied  lines  of  insurance  and  I  currently  serve  as  Chairman  of  AACI. 
Accompanying  me  is  Bob  Post,  who  is  President  of  Domberger/Berry  &  Co.  which  is  now  a 
wholly  owned  subsidiary  of  ITT/Hartford,  who  serves  as  a  Vice  Chairman  of  AACI.  AACI 
members  write  over  60  percent  of  the  U.S.  MPCI  policies  that  provide  peace  of  mind  for  over 
700,000  policyholders. 

THE  OPPORTUNITY 

We  find  ourselves  presented  with  perhaps  the  greatest  opportunity  of  all  time  to  improve 
the  crop  insurance  program.  Finally  crop  insurance  can  be  established  as  the  sole  means  of 
providing  producers  with  financial  protection  against  crop  disasters,  as  it  was  originally  intended 
to  be  following  the  1980  Act.  We've  seen  a  lot  of  reform  proposals  since  1980  as  well  as 
considerable  ad  hoc  disaster  funding  and  emergency  loans  handed  out.  However,  at  no  time  has 
there  been  such  a  consensus  for  reform  or  an  apparent  willingness  to  merge  the  ad  hoc  disaster 
payment  approach  into  an  improved  crop  insurance  program  as  was  the  original  intent. 

The  Administration's  plan  provides:  catastrophic  insurance  coverage  on  about  50  crops 
to  all  farm  program  and  lending  participants;  added  incentives  for  purchasing  additional 
coverage;  and  disaster  protection  for  all  other  crops.  We  commend  President  Clinton,  Secretary 
Espy,  0MB  Director  Panetta,  Under  Secretary  Moos,  and  FCIC  Manager  Ackerman  and  their 
staffs  for  putting  this  package  together  and  for  choosing  what  is  undoubtedly  the  best  policy 
approach  for  addressing  crop  losses  —  insurance.  Regardless  of  the  outcome  of  the  Budget 
Conference  activity,  we  need  to  thank  Representatives  Stenholm  and  Pomeroy  for  their 
tireless  efforts  on  getting  the  added  funding  for  the  reform  proposal. 

A  NEW  MINDSET  IS  ESSENTIAL 

No  matter  what  legislation  is  passed  by  Congress,  a  reformed  crop  insurance 
program  can  only  reach  its  objectives  IF  THERE  IS  A  COMPLETELY  NEW  MINDSET 
ON  ALL  FACETS  OF  THE  PROGRAM  ON  THE  PART  OF  USDA  (FCIC/FSA),  THE 


303 


COMPANIES,  FARMERS  A>fD  CONGRESS.  We  must  focus  on  a  greatly  simplified 
program  both  for  the  catastrophic  coverage  and  additional  coverages  that  will  be  available.  A 
new  program  in  the  old  package  will  not  work.  A  completely  restructured  program  in  both 
appearance  and  function  is  what  it  will  take  to  convince  farmers  that  real  reform  has  happened. 

Overall,  we  believe  that  there  could  be  at  least  a  one-third  reduction  in  the  administrative 
requirements  of  the  crop  insurance  program  without  adversely  affecting  program  performance. 
At  the  same  time  we  are  working  cooperatively  with  the  administration  in  support  of  this 
proposal,  we  have  been  presented  with  a  draft  reinsurance  agreement  that  adds  many  new  costly 
administrative  requirements  with  limited  program  benefit  to  an  already  needlessly  complex 
program.  Unless  USD  A  (FCIC/FSA)  is  willing  to  work  with  the  industry  on  completely 
evaluating  the  need  and  existence  of  all  current  administrative  burdens  neither  the  current 
program  nor  a  reformed  program  can  be  delivered  in  today's  restrictive  budget 
environment. 

OUR  OBJECTIVE 

We,  along  with  others  in  the  industry,  believe  that  the  objective  of  any  crop  insurance 
program  must  be  the  provision  of  incentives  and  opportunities  for  farmers  that  permit  them  to 
adequately  and  affordably  manage  their  production  risks.  The  risk  protection  provided  must 
meet  farmers'  most  basic  income  and  financial  needs  if  a  natural  disaster  strikes. 

In  achieving  that  chief  objective,  universal  availability  of  a  catastrophic  coverage  at  litde 
or  no  charge,  by  itself,  will  not  be  sufficient.  Significant  participation  at  greater  than 
catastrophic  levels  of  protection  is  necessary  to  adequately  protect  farmers.  ONLY  through  a 
continued  significant  involvement  of  the  private  sector  in  the  risk  bearing  and  delivery  of  crop 
insurance  can  Federal  dollars  be  fully  leveraged  to  meet  these  objectives. 

In  general,  the  Administration's  reform  proposal  deserves  positive  action  by  the  Budget, 
Appropriations,  and  Agriculture  Committees  of  Congress.  Furthermore,  for  farmers  to  be  able 
to  get  this  much  needed  protection  in  1995,  the  action  of  the  Congressional  committees  needs 
to  occur  very  swiftly.  However,  in  order  to  help  the  program  achieve  its  maximum  effective- 
ness, we  feel  that  a  number  of  refmements  need  to  be  made  in  the  proposal. 

These  refmements  can  be  categorized  in  three  general  areas: 

■  Program  Simplification 

■  Program  Delivery 

■  Reasonable  Remm  for  Private  Capital  Invested 

PROGRAM  SIMPLIFICATION 

Farmers  are  our  customers.  Therefore,  we  want  to  make  the  program  as  easy  to 
understand  and  as  simple  to  participate  in  as  possible  so  that  we  can  maximize  farmer 
participation.  At  the  same  time,  a  simplified  program  reduces  the  government's  expense  as  well 
as  that  of  the  companies  involved.  Industry  and  farmers  alike  are  very  familiar  with  simplified 
procedures  of  the  crop  hail  program  and  perhaps  several  aspects  of  that  program  may  serve  as 
a  model  for  simplifymg  the  MPCI  program. 


304 


The  principle  of  simplification  should  be  foremost  in  the  formulation  of  the  catastrophic 
level  of  coverage,  as  there  will  be  some  farmers  who  are  participating  against  their  will. 
However,  it  is  vitally  important  and  wholly  justified  that  whatever  simplification  measures  are 
adopted  for  the  catastrophic  level  should  also  flow  through  the  rest  of  the  program  as  well. 
Otherwise,  a  major  disincentive  for  participation  at  higher  levels  of  coverage  will  be  created  and 
the  opportunity  to  reduce  program  costs  will  be  foregone. 

ALTERATION  OF  COVERAGE  LEVELS  NEEDED.  There  is  some  complexity  in 
the  Administration's  proposal  as  it  relates  to  levels  of  protection  that  we  believe:  is  unnecessary; 
adds  confusion;  and  adds  administrative  costs  to  the  program.  The  proposal  contains  three 
classes  of  protection:  the  50/60  catastrophic  policy;  policies  between  50/60  and  65/100  or  its 
equivalent;  and  policies  equivalent  to  65/100  or  higher.  The  provisions  regarding  the  middle 
range  of  policies  need  improvement. 

For  simplification  purposes,  we  question  the  need  for  offering  a  range  of  50  percent  yield 
coverage/price  election  mixes  given  the  minimum  cost  of  such  policies  and  the  thrust  of  the 
proposal  which  is  to  have  as  many  farmers  adequately  protected  as  possible.  It  might  be 
advisable  to  only  provide  a  50  percent  yield,  100  percent  price  election  policy  as  the  next  step 
beyond  50/60.  This  is  a  significant  increase  in  liability  protection  for  the  farmer,  especially 
when  one  considers  that  optional  units  are  available  at  this  level,  while  only  costing  a  minimal 
amount. 

Providing  coverage  at  this  mid-range  level  is  also  worth  full  expense  reimbursement  and, 
given  the  reduced  premium  levels,  would  not  significantly  exceed,  if  at  all,  the  minimum  $50 
reimbursement  which  we  believe  the  Administration's  proposal  advocates  for  all  policies.  In 
fact,  the  application  fee  and  the  standard  expense  reimbursement  would  be  fully  justified  as  it 
not  clear  how  the  loss  adjustment  costs  would  be  covered  for  these  policies. 

Furthermore,  the  Subcommittee  may  wish  to  set  a  floor  under  protection  at  the  65  and 
75  percent  yield  levels  that  is  nearly  equivalent  with  the  50/60  catastrophic  policy  in  terms  of 
dollars  or  protection.  While  we  need  to  provide  farmers  with  a  variety  of  coverage  choices, 
there  is  no  need  to  offer  less  than  is  being  given  away  for  a  minimum  application  fee. 

NONSTANDARD  CLASSIFICATION  SYSTEM.  There  is  much  concern  in  many 
areas  of  the  country  over  the  administration  of  the  Nonstandard  Classification  System  (NCS)  and 
its  impact  on  farmers.  We  believe  that  the  catastrophic  level  of  protection  should  be  a  bottom- 
end  safety  net  for  all  farmers  below  which  they  should  be  forced  to  go  under  NCS  or  any  other 
program. 

PROGRAM  INNOVATION  MUST  BE  FOSTERED.  One  of  the  most  frequent 
comments  about  the  crop  insurance  program  is  that  it  doesn't  provide  enough  coverage.  We  also 
know  of  many  farmers  who  currently  buy  MPCI  whose  first  question  about  the  reform  proposal 
is  will  it  return  to  me  the  same  level  of  benefits  I  am  currently  getting  with  both  MPCI  and 
disaster  payments.    The  answer  to  that  question  is  no. 

We  understand  some  Members  have  expressed  a  desire  to  focus  more  of  the  buy-up 
subsidy  at  the  75  percent,  thereby  reducing  those  premiums  more.  We  would  have  no  problem 
with  trying  to  do  that  provided  the  underlying  risk  costs  are  statistically  derived.  The  Luveme, 
Minnesota  field  hearing  and  other  general  comments  from  farmers  and  farm  groups,  revealed 
that  many  people  want  subsidies  targeted  for  the  85  percent  level  of  coverage.    While  the 


3- 


\ 


305 


Administration's  bill  provides  that  such  levels  of  coverage  may  be  offered,  there  are  other  means 
for  making  the  program  more  attractive  that  the  Subcommittee  may  also  want  to  explore  that 
may  meet  the  same  need  expressed  by  farmers  in  a  more  economical  way  for  all  parties 
involved. 

One  such  alternative  would  be  a  type  of  supplemental  product  known  as  a  "disappearing 
deductible"  or  "accelerated  payout"  rider.  This  type  of  insurance  endorsement  would  pay 
farmers  an  increased  indemnity  amount  per  bushel  as  losses  increased  to  the  point  if  a  farmer 
had  a  total  loss,  they  would  receive  an  indemnity  reimbursing  them  for  100  percent  of  their 
APH.  At  what  level  of  loss  this  accelerated  payout  is  triggered  and  the  rate  at  which  it  is 
accelerated  affect  the  premium  for  such  policies.  This  type  of  benefit  could  provide  current 
MPCI  users  with  the  same  level  of  benefits  they  currently  get  through  crop  insurance  and 
disaster  payments  combined.  The  premiums  for  such  supplementals  are  significantly  more 
economical  than  the  premium  rates  for  85  percent  coverage. 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  gives  FCIC  the  authority  to  approve  supplemental  and 
alternative  products  for  reinsurance,  expense  reimbursement,  and  premium  subsidies.  Along 
with  the  announcement  of  the  Administration's  reform  proposal,  FCIC  announced  it  had  finally 
used  this  authority  to  approve  one  supplemental  product  on  a  pilot  basis  for  1994.  We  commend 
FCIC  for  doing  so  and  encourage  this  Subcommittee  to  encourage  FCIC  to  be  much  more 
proactive  in  this  arena.  Without  reinsurance  from  the  Federal  Government  on  supplemental 
products,  they  will  not  be  made  available  on  as  wide  a  scale  as  is  justified  or  needed.  In  its 
exercise  of  this  authority,  FCIC  also  needs  to  set  some  ground  rules  to  insure  the  timely 
consideration,  equitable  terms,  and  widespread  availability  of  alternative  products.  Also, 
government  reinsurance  or  other  support  of  these  products  should  be  made  available  through 
cooperative  financial  arrangements  with  a  minimum  of  red  tape  and  administrative  burdens. 
Given  the  proper  incentives,  reasonable  opportunities  for  return  on  capital  throughout  the 
program,  and  appropriate  government  backing,  USDA  and  fanners  would  be  amazed  at 
the  explosion  of  crop  insurance  products  that  could  be  developed  by  the  private  sector. 

REDUCTION  OF  THE  PROGRAM'S  ADMEVISTRATIVE  BURDEN.  Faced  with 
shrinking  reimbursements  to  cover  operating  and  administrative  costs,  most  reinsured  companies 
have  streamlined  operations  to  the  maximum  extent  possible.  However,  you  reach  a  point  where 
your  options  for  operational  changes  are  limited  by  the  program  you  are  administering.  That 
is  the  point  we  have  reached  in  this  program.  If  we  might  borrow  a  term  that  many 
Congressman  are  concerned  with  —  we  are  facing  a  form  of  unfunded  federal  mandate.  Like 
the  state  and  local  governments,  we  are  given  ever- increasing  mandates  by  FCIC  with  no  money 
to  comply  with  these  mandates.  Companies  end  up  being  forced  to  spend  limited  resources  on 
crossing  "i's"  and  dotting  "t's"  instead  of  on  innovative  new  crop  insurance  products,  improved 
fanner  services,  and  creative  marketing  to  increase  farmer  participation. 

There  are  a  number  of  existing  program  requirements  and  paperwork  burdens  that  will 
remain  in  the  reformed  program  that  could  be  altered  for  the  benefit  of  all  parties  involved  in 
the  program  without  adversely  affecting  program  integrity.  We  have  a  dual  regulatory  structure. 
As  you  know,  insurance  regulatory  matters  are  generally  governed  by  state  authorities  and  are 
usually  performance  measured.  While  that  system  is  not  perfect,  it  does  work  quite  effectively. 

What  we  have  been  experiencing  in  the  last  few  years  is  a  second  layer  of  federal 
regulation  of  insurance  functions  that  often  appear  more  as  regulation  for  regulation's  sake  and 


-4 


306 


are  not  performance  based.  We  are  in  favor  of  strong  oversight.  However,  that  oversight 
should  be:  timely;  cost  effective;  and  carefijlly  structured  to  achieve  measurable  performance 
objectives.  For  instance,  if  there  is  a  perceived  problem  with  agents  and  adjusters,  is  the  answer 
requiring  over  20,000  such  persons  to  spend  more  hours  in  classroom  training?  Or  is  everyone's 
time  and  money  better  spent  identifying  problem  individuals  and  having  a  system  to  identify  and 
correct  their  performance  or  to  disallow  their  participation  in  the  program? 

As  we  contemplate  adding  approximately  1.4  million  participants  to  the  program, 
the  streamlining  and  reduction  of  the  administrative  burden  for  FCIC,  the  companies,  the 
agents,  and  the  participants,  becomes  even  more  vital.  We  have  attached  a  list  of  suggestions 
for  the  reduction  of  administrative  costs  which  we  believe  warrant  consideration.  These 
suggestions  run  the  gamut  from  a  simple  requirement  to  require  more  timely  releases  of  program 
information  to  eliminating  separate  acreage  reports  to  more  refined  data  processing.  Overall, 
we  believe  that  there  could  be  a  one-third  reduction  in  the  administrative  requirements  of 
the  crop  insurance  program  without  adversely  affecting  program  performance.  We  hope 
that  the  Subcommittee  will  seriously  consider  such  a  reduction  as  part  of  the  reform 
package. 

APPLICATION  FEE.  While  there  is  much  debate  about  the  level  of  the  application  fee 
and  its  equity  with  respect  to  large  and  small  producers,  we  do  caution  the  Subcommittee  about 
locking  specific  rates  into  the  statute.  As  you  know,  this  approach  minimizes  the  flexibility  of 
the  Department  to  respond  to  changing  conditions  without  having  to  ask  Congress  to  amend  the 
statute.  Perhaps  the  Subcommittee  could  strongly  express  its  expectations  with  respect  to  these 
fees  in  report  language. 

PROGRAM  DELIVERY 

We  are  in  strong  support  of  the  Administration's  proposed  reliance  on  the  private  sector 
for  delivering  all  higher  level  coverage  crop  insurance  policies.  This  maximizes  the  impact  of 
limited  Federal  dollars  and  recognizes  the  preference  and  convenience  of  farmers  in  obtaining 
insurance  coverage.  The  reestablishment  of  a  goverrmient  delivery  system,  however,  causes 
some  problems  that  we  believe  need  to  be  addressed  to  make  the  reform  proposal  work.  We 
believe  the  provision  for  dual  delivery; 

1.  Could  threaten  the  success  of  the  reformed  program; 

2.  Is  unjustifiable  in  terms  of  cost  and  performance;  and 

3.  Is  inconsistent  with  both  the  current  crop  insurance  statute  and  the  reinventing 
government  initiative  of  the  Clinton  Administration. 

We  question  the  need  for,  cost  effectiveness  of,  and  farmer  satisfaction  with  any  govenmient 
delivery. 

NEED  FOR  COUNSELING.  The  catastrophic  protection  alone,  which  approximates 
the  benefits  of  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  of  the  past  is  good,  but  not  sufficient  to  save  the  farm 
for  most  growers  when  disasters  occur.  Therefore,  the  core  issue  that  will  determine  whether 
farmers  are  adequately  protected  is  whether  they  do.  in  fact,  purchase  additional  coverage  to 
meet  their  risk  management  needs.  We  strongly  believe  that  professional  counseling  to 
quantify  risks  and  match  them  with  the  right  insurance  coverage  is  indispensable  for  this 


5- 


307 


program  to  succeed.    Private  sector,  professional  insurance  agents  are  trained,  licensed,  and 
in  place  to  perform  that  task  as  they  do  with  all  other  consumer  risk  management  needs. 

For  most  growers,  they  will  entrust  the  same  professional  insurance  agent  for  their  crop 
insurance  that  they  trust  to  help  with  their  other  farm  insurance  plans.  These  insurance 
professionals  often  meet  customers  at  their  kitchen  table  and  are  able  to  develop  a  comprehensive 
package  of  farm  and  crop  protection.  Government  employees  are  simply  not  trained,  nor  should 
they  be,  nor  do  they  have  the  time  to  attempt  to  perform  this  essential  duty. 

Meeting  the  Counseling  Needs  of  Farmers.  At  a  minimum,  we  strongly  suggest  that 
fanners'  risk  management  needs  could  best  be  met  if  farmers  are  required  to  visit  a  private 
insurance  agent  prior  to  their  being  able  to  obtain  the  catastrophic  risk  policy  at  an  USDA 
office.  Being  adequately  covered  is  much  more  than  filling  out  a  form  after  standing  in  line  at 
the  FSA  office.  It  is  a  complex  decision  for  which  professional  counseling  should  be  provided 
and  which  private  agents  are  best  positioned  to  provide. 

UNJUSTIFIABLE  COSTS.  Budget  constraints  argue  against  the  creation  of  a 
duplicative  infrastructure  for  the  delivery  of  crop  insurance.  FCIC  has  already  made  the  sound 
decision  to  discontinue  the  writing  of  federal  paper  because  over  93  percent  of  farmers  who 
choose  to  purchase  crop  insurance  do  so  from  private  agents  on  private  company  policies.  FCIC 
realized  it  could  no  longer  afford  to  have  24  percent  of  its  resources  and  personnel  devoted  to 
servicing  only  seven  to  eight  percent  of  MPCI  policies. 

Government  Involvement  on  Only  an  "As  Needed"  Basis.  Due  to  the  fixed  costs  of 
a  government  infrastructure,  serious  consideration  should  be  given  to  identifying  areas  of  the 
country  in  which  there  would  be  no  backstop  USDA  delivery  due  to  the  presence  and 
commitment  of  sufficient  private  sector  insurance  forces  that  will  see  that  every  single  farmer's 
needs  are  met.  Government  availability  of  catastrophic  coverage  would  only  be  needed  to 
address  instances  (if  any)  where  private  insurance  agents  are  not  available.  This  could  save 
hundreds  of  millions  of  dollars  in  government  administrative  overhead. 

Delivery  "Point"  Versus  Delivery  "System".  Another  option  to  consider  is  that  while 
the  USDA  office  may  be  a  delivery  point,  the  government  need  not  develop  a  costly  and 
inefficient  delivery  system  infrastructure  to  back  that  delivery  point  up.  Rather,  the  policy 
obtained  at  the  USDA  office  could  be  serviced  by  the  private  sector  infrastructure  already  in 
place.  We  continue  to  believe  that  there  are  many  administrative  functions  that  FCIC  is 
mandated  to  not  duplicate  should  such  services  be  available  in  the  private  sector.  Yet,  such 
duplication  continues  to  occur. 

REINVENTING  GOVERNMENT.  Finally,  if  we  are  serious  about  Reinventing 
Government,  then  there  is  no  better  place  to  begin  than  the  crop  insurance  program.  First  of 
all,  we  are  hitting  the  ground  running  because  we  already  have  a  public/private  partnership  in 
place.  Secondly,  we  have  an  existing  statutory  mandate  to  utilize  the  private  sector  to  the 
maximum  extent  possible.  7  U.S.C.  1507(c).  Thirdly,  as  USDA  is  reorganized  and  field 
offices  are  consolidated  and  collocated,  there  is  an  existing  private  sector  network  that  can 
deliver  crop  insurance  -  and  even  the  noninsured  standby  disaster  assistance  --  to  farmers 
more  conveniently,  more  efficiently,  and  more  cost  effectively  than  government.  We  need  to 
capitalize  on  that  opportunity. 


308 


The  capability  of  the  private  sector  is  illustrated  by  the  fact  that  should  Congress  adopt 
a  reform  proposal  this  year,  the  private  sector  can  have  it  in  place  for  the  1995  crop  season  — 
meaning  this  fall  --  while  the  government  is  still  trying  to  determine  who  is  in  charge  of  what 
as  it  deals  with  its  reorganization  and  what  types  of  computers  to  buy  for  FSA  offices.  Such 
rapid  implementation  of  a  completely  redesigned  program  can  be  accomplished,  but  it  requires 
major  retooling  costs  that  must  be  accommodated. 


ADEQUATE  DELIVERY  EXPENSE  REIMBURSEMENT.  As  you  know.  Congress 
has  made  the  determination  that  farmers  will  not  pay  any  premium  that  is  related  to  the  costs 
of  delivering,  servicing,  or  adjusting  federally  reinsured  crop  insurance  protection.  Therefore, 
an  integral  part  of  the  crop  insurance  equation  is  providing  the  means  for  covering  these  costs. 

The  administrative  expense  loaded  into  the  premiums  of  most  property  and  casualty 
policies  can  run  as  higher  than  40  percent  of  premium.  While  the  expense  reimbursement  for 
crop  insurance  used  to  be  around  34  percent,  it  has  dropped  year  after  year  as  the  operating 
expenses  and  administrative  requirements  of  the  program  have  increased.  The  slashing  of 
expense  reimbursement  took  on  a  new  dimension  last  year  as  the  Appropriations  Committee 
capped  the  rate  at  31  percent  in  its  annual  funding  measure  --  a  $10  million  reduction  in 
reimbursements  to  the  industry. 

1993  proved  that  not  only  can  the  reinsured  companies  involved  in  the  program  lose 
money  on  the  risk  sharing  side  of  the  private/public  partnership  relationship,  but  we  also  stand 
exposed  on  the  expense  side  as  well.  The  expense  reimbursement  equation  assumes  that  there 
will  be  loss  claims  on  approximately  35  to  40  percent  of  all  policies.  Most  companies  received 
claims  on  as  many  as  90  percent  of  their  policies  in  several  Midwestern  states  last  year. 

Each  year  we  find  ourselves  at  the  mercy  of  FCIC  as  they  draft  a  Standard  Reinsurance 
Agreement  (SRA)  outlining  the  administrative  and  risk  sharing  requirements  of  the  private/public 
partnership  that  also  sets  the  reimbursement  rate.  Despite  ever  increasing  administrative 
requirements  and  increased  costs  of  doing  business  like  anyone  else,  the  reimbursement  rate 
declines  (or  stays  at  the  capped  rate  of  31  percent  for  this  year).  This  pattern  is  contrary  to  that 
of  the  flood  insurance  program  where  private  companies,  who  bear  no  risk  in  the  program,  have 
received  increasing  expense  payments. 

There  is  language  in  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  (hereinafter  "FCIA")  mandating  that 
private  companies  be  reimbursed  at  "rates  of  compensation  consistent  with  those  generally 
prevailing  in  the  insurance  industry"  for  functions  performed.  7  U.S.C.  1507(c).  However, 
FCIC  has  always  maintained  that  this  language  does  not  apply  to  standard  delivery,  servicing, 
and  loss  adjustment  functions.  We  believe  the  FCIA  should  be  amended  to  make  the  prevailing 
compensation  rates  applicable  to  all  of  the  functions  performed  by  the  reinsured  companies.  We 
are  not  asking  for  anything  special,  just  something  that  reflects  reality  and  brings  this  insurance 
program  in  line  with  insurance  practice. 

There  is  also  strong  justification  for  some  type  of  expense  reimbursement  supplement  in 
years  like  1995  when  the  industry  will  have  to  undertake  a  significant  retooling  of  all  their 
operations  to  accommodate  a  reformed  program.  Even  in  1994,  as  this  Summary  of  Changes 
for  Spring  1994  Crops,  reveals,  we  were  required  to  implement  a  number  of  significant  changes 
--  especially  the  new  Acnial  Production  History  (APH)  requirements  -  that  involved  major 
retooling  while  facing  a  five  percent  cut  in  our  reimbursement  rate.    Finally,  if  FCIC  makes 


309 


changes  midstream  within  a  crop  year,  they  should  be  encouraged,  perhaps  through  statutory 
language,  to  provide  added  compensation  for  these  expenses  which  were  not  contemplated  by 
either  party  when  entering  the  SRA. 

A  REASONABLE  RETURN  ON  PRIVATE  CAPITAL  INVESTED.  An  integral  part 
of  program  delivery  is  having  a  healthy  private  sector  available  to  provide  the  level  of  service 
and  competition  that  farmers  want  and  deserve.  The  health  of  the  private  sector  is  greatly 
affected  in  the  crop  insurance  program  by  the  risk  sharing  relationship  it  has  with  the 
government. 

As  this  Subcommittee  heard  from  FCIC  Manager  Ken  Ackerman  at  its  earlier  Washington 
hearing,  not  only  did  farmers  lose  big  in  1993,  but  the  private  reinsured  companies  did  as  well. 
As  alluded  to  earlier,  we  can  assure  you  that  not  only  did  we  lose  on  the  underwriting  side  of 
the  program,  we  also  lost  on  the  administrative  expense  side  due  to  the  significant  costs  of 
adjusting  the  record  number  of  claims. 

FCIC  Manager  Ackerman  indicated  company  losses  would  be  approximately  $83  million 
in  1993.  To  put  that  in  perspective,  some  companies'  losses  in  1993  exceeded  their 
cumulative  profits  over  the  10  to  13  years  they  have  been  involved  in  the  program.  The 
industry  as  a  whole  lost  in  one  year  most  of  the  9-years  worth  of  gains  that  GAO  reported 
in  its  January  1992  risk  sharing  report.  Furthermore,  given  the  very  limited  gain 
oppormnities  in  the  current  SRA,  it  would  take  companies  many  years  to  earn  back  what  they 
have  lost  in  one  if  they  are  given  that  opportunity  by  corporate  executives  and  shareholders  who 
have  other  uses  for  their  capital. 

Current  language  in  the  FCIA  states  that: 

"beginning  with  the  1992  reinsurance  year  ...  the  Corporation  [FCIC]  shall 
revise  its  reinsurance  agreements  ...  so  as  to  require  the  reinsured  companies 
to  bear  an  increased  share  of  any  potential  loss  under  such  agreement  taking  into 
consideration  the  financial  condition  of  the  companies  and  the  availability  of 
private  reinsurance."    7  U.S.C.  1508(h). 

FCIC  has  used  this  language  with  a  vengeance  and,  despite  the  devastating  financial  impact  of 
1993  and  the  short  supply  of  private  reinsurance,  is  continuing  to  apply  it  so  with  the  1995 
proposed  agreement.  An  attached  exhibit  shows  how  the  risk  has  increased  over  the  last  few 
years  and  far  outpaced  the  gain  opportunity. 

The  Administration  proposal  includes  some  improvement  in  the  above  language,  but  we 
believe  it  needs  further  refinement.  The  bottom  line  is  that  the  opportunity  for  gain  must  be 
commensurate  with  the  opportunity  for  loss.  As  that  same  exhibit  shows,  that  balanced 
relationship  does  not  exist  in  the  current  reinsurance  agreements  FCIC  is  offering.  In  fact,  some 
recent  industry  analyses  have  revealed  that  if  a  company  placed  all  of  its  policies  in  the  fund 
where  it  can  achieve  the  most  gain  and  it  bears  100  percent  of  the  risk  thereby  having  a  right 
to  maximum  gain,  it  would  come  out  losing  nearly  seven  percent  over  time. 

One  has  to  understand  that  in  a  program  with  a  historical  loss  ratio  of  1 .47,  and  one  now 
with  a  long  range  goal  of  an  estimated  1 . 1  loss  ratio,  the  rates  and  programs  are  such  that  they 
build  in  a  loss  for  companies.  Therefore,  the  reinsurance  relationship  must  be  improved  and  the 
FCIA  should  require  a  reasonable  oppormnity  for  gain  and  should  continue  to  take  into  account 
the  financial  condition  of  the  companies. 


8- 


310 


PARAMETERS  FOR  COMPETITION  PROVISION.  A  new  element  of  the 
Administration's  proposal  is  one  that  would  allow  companies  to  reduce  premium  rates  to  farmers 
based  upon  savings  in  administrative  expense.  While  all  such  reductions  must  be  approved  by 
FCIC,  we  believe  some  well-defined  parameters  need  to  be  established  to  ensure  that  the  farmer 
benefits  from  this  provision  and  is  not  penalized.  As  we  have  noted,  the  administrative  burden 
of  this  program  is  great,  and  while  there  are  some  requirements  that  we  feel  are  unnecessary  and 
should  be  eliminated  or  streamlined,  there  are  others  that  are  central  to  providing  farmers  with 
adequate  servicing  of  their  policies. 

Therefore,  strict  controls  are  needed  to  ensure  that  any  premium  rebates  are  the  result 
of  true  efficiencies  that  do  not  adversely  affect  service  to  the  farmer  or  program  integrity. 
Otherwise,  the  fanner  will  be  on  the  losing  side  with  fewer  choices  for  insurance  and  less 
service  by  those  remaining  providers. 

ESSENTIAL  QUESTIONS.  Our  judgment  is  that  if  all  costs  are  capmred,  the  private 
sector  can  deliver  and  service  crop  insurance  policies  more  cost  effectively  and  efficiently  than 
the  government  with  both  parties  playing  according  to  ffie^same  rules.  Therefore,  we  believe 
the  Members  of  this  Subcommittee  should  demand  to  know  the  facts  about  the  cost  of  delivering 
this  program  through  the  government.  There  are  a  number  of  questions  which  if  we  were  sitting 
in  your  place,  believe  need  to  be  answered: 

1 .  What  are  the  costs  of  this  government  dual  delivery  system? 

2.  How  much  will  it  cost  to  train  and  license  FSA  employees  across  the  country  to 
perform  the  tasks  required  of  them  under  this? 

3.  If  no  additional  funds  are  provided  to  ASCS  or  FSA  to  undertake  this  new 
proposal  then  how  much  of  existing  resources  are  going  to  be  diverted  to 
accommodate  this?  This  would  have  to  occur  unless  there  is  a  significant  amount 
of  over  staffing  or  over  fijnding  currently  in  existence  in  the  FSA  system. 

4.  What  will  be  the  impact  of  this  dislocation  of  resources  on  the  current  services 
and  responsibilities  of  ASCS  and  FSA  to  farmers  across  the  country? 

We  believe  these  types  of  questions  need  to  be  fully  evaluated. 

OTHER  ISSUES 

There  are  a  number  of  other  issues  regarding  the  reform  proposal  and  overriding 
administrative  issues  which  impact  the  current  and  any  reformed  program  which  we  also  believe 
are  very  important.  To  that  end,  we  have  included  several  attachments  we  feel  the  Subcommit- 
tee should  be  aware  of  and  which  may  assist  you  in  making  the  decisions  you  will  have  to  make 
while  formulating  the  crop  insurance  reform  legislation.  We  look  forward  to  providing  the 
Subcommittee  with  additional  input  as  needed  and  requested. 

CONCLUSION 

We  have  a  unique  opportunity  this  year  to  drive  the  crop  insurance  stake  deep  into  the 
soil  to  ensure  that  the  tent  of  protection  for  farmers  will  be  able  to  weather  the  significant  winds 
of  change  facing  agriculture  in  the  years  to  come.   The  time  for  leadership  is  now.  We  believe 


311 


the  Administration  has  set  before  Congress  a  framework  for  reform  that  will  work  if  refined  and 
implemented  in  a  manner  which  capitalizes  on  the  existing  public/private  partnership  of  the  crop 
insurance  program.  We  cannot  emphasize  enough  that  this  reformed  program  will  only 
achieve  its  objectives  if  everyone  involved  approaches  it  with  a  new  mindset. 

We  firmly  believe  that  the  private  sector  can  deliver,  day  after  day,  more  bang  for  the 
scarce  federal  dollar  available,  thereby  permitting  the  intended  beneficiaries  -  farmers  ~  to 
receive  the  bulk  of  those  scarce  dollars.  We  thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to  appear  before  you 
today  and  look  forward  to  working  with  you  to  insure  the  development  and  implementation  of 
an  improved  crop  insurance  program. 

List  of  attachments: 

Master  List  of  Concerns  With  the  Legislative  Language 

Cost  of  Government  Programs  for  Disasters 

Talking  Points  on  Administration  Proposal 

Advantages  of  Private  Sector  Delivery 

Agent  Count  by  State 

Comparison  of  Reinsurance  Treaties 

Increased  Risk  Requirements  Under  Reinsurance  Agreements 

List  of  Paperwork  Reduction  Ideas 

Industry  Joint  Position  Statement 

Flow  Chart  on  Administrative  Expense  Reimbursement  Flow 

List  of  Functions  Performed  by  Reinsured  Companies 


-  10 


312 


LIST  OF  POINTS/CONCERNS  THAT  NEED  TO  BE  EXPLORED 

1 .  Program  simplification/paperwork  reduction  language. 

2.  Rewrite  levels  of  coverage: 

a.  50/60  to  50/100  as  first  step; 

b.  cup  on  65%; 

c.  full  expense  reimbursement  on  all  buy-ups. 

3.  Clarify  that  catastrophic  policies  are  written  on  a  one  unit  per  crop  per  county  basis  only. 

4.  Application  fee  options: 

a.  Take  out  specific  amounts; 

b.  Per  acre  basis  or  some  sliding  scale; 

c.  Spread  across  all  participants; 

d.  Fees  for  limited  resource  farmers  ~  private  reimbursed  by  govt.? 

5.  Delivery  options: 

a.  Agent  first; 

b.  Government  only  on  an  "as  needed"  basis; 

c.  Delivery  point  v.  entire  duplicative  system. 

6.  Reasonable  rate  of  return  on  private  capital  invested. 

7.  Reasonable  expense  reimbursement  for  adminsitrative  and  operating  functions. 

8.  Establish  some  strict  parameters  for  competition  provision. 

9.  Establish  reasonable  and  timely  parameters  for  oversight. 

10.  Provide  litigation  support  for  protecting  program  integrity. 

11.  Alternative,  supplemental,  and  optional  insurance  products: 

a.  Regulations/guidelines  needed; 

b.  Test  of  private  sector  availability; 

c.  Must  be  a  cooperative  fmancial  arrangement. 

12.  Encourage  the  increased  use  of  private  sector  in  program  reviews,  administration,  and 
development  to  avoid  costly  duplication. 

13.  Change  substantial  interest  from  5%  to  the  same  definition  in  ASCS  programs. 

14.  Reinstate  cap  on  FCIC  employment. 

15.  Insure  that  GRP  can  be  offered  only  as  an  option  to  regular  MPCI? 

16.  Require  a  thorough  evaluation  of  the  cost  effectiveness  and  farmer  utilization  of  GRP  and 
other  pilot  programs  to  determine  whether  they  should  be  continued. 


313 


Government  Cost  For  Current  Disaster  Programs 


(1981  -  1993  Estimates) 


Dollars  In  Billions 


CROP  INSURANCE*  DISASTER  PAYMENTS 


(1981  -  1992  Only) 


Govt.  Cost 


Farmer  Benefits 


*  Losses  In  Excess  of  Total  Premium 

These  figures  do  not  Include  administrative  expenses  of  any  of  the  programs. 


Premiums  &  Loss  Payments 

Multiple  Peril  Crop  Insurance 


Dollars  in  Billions 


$1,800 
1,600 


1,400 


I  Total  Premium        I      I  Loss  Payments 


314 


TALKING  POINTS  ON  THE  CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  PROPOSAL 
WHY  NOW? 


It  is  time  for  the  dual  and  competing  systems  of  crop  insurance  and  ad  hoc  disaster 
payments  to  come  to  an  end  both  due  to  their  budgetary  costs  and  to  the  "disaster"  (too 
little  too  late)  which  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  are  to  farmers. 

We  have  seen  in  recent  months  the  difficulty  of  "finding"  disaster  funds  and  the 
increasing  movement  to  subject  them  to  PAYGO.  This  proposal  reigns  disaster  funding 
in  and  eliminates  the  authority  for  future  non-PAYGO  ad  hoc  payments,  while  at  the 
same  time  providing  farmers  with  the  certamty  of  having  some  type  of  base  level 
assistance  in  the  event  of  a  disaster. 

It  is  in  the  long-term  best  interest  of  our  agricultural  sector  to  undergird  it  with  a  stable, 
fully  funded,  safety  net  for  risk  management  to  handle  the  unpredictable  risks  which  that 
sector,  and  no  other,  is  susceptible  to  year  in  and  year  out. 

WHY  A  CROP  INSURANCE  APPROACH? 

President  Clinton  and  Agriculture  Secretary  Espy  have  recognized  the  superior  attributes 
of  an  insurance  solution  to  disaster  situations  over  an  ad  hoc  "throw  money  at  the 
problem  after  the  fact"  solution  by  adopting  a  crop  insurance  solution  as  the  primary 
means  of  disaster  assistance  for  the  future. 


Crop  Insurance: 

Is  a  plan  that  facilitates 
business  planning. 

Represents  true  risk  management. 

Can  be  used  as  collateral  for 
increasingly  important  ag 
financing. 

Encourages  self-reliance  and 
responsibility.  Farmers  help 
themselves. 

Allocates  loss  costs  to  those 
who  properly  should  bear  them. 

Encourages  people  to  reduce 
premiums  through  loss  prevention 
and  risk  avoidance,  thus  lowering 
overall  costs  to  society. 

Exposure  is  measurable  and  can 
accounted  for  in  underwriting 
adjustments. 


Ad  Hoc  Disaster  Assistance: 

Is  unpredictable,  ad  hoc,  inconsistent 
with  planning. 

Represents  no  management  whatsoever. 

Cannot  be  used  to  backstop  financing. 


Encourages  dependence. 


Flies  in  the  face  of  equity. 


Discourages  risk  management. 


Exposure  is  unknown  and  cannot  be 
accounted  for  or  regained. 


315 


THE  ADMINISTRATION'S  PROPOSAL  REFLECTS: 

Truth  in  budgeting  --  Over  the  past  six  years  the  Federal  Government  has  expended 
$1,575  billion  annually  on  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  in  addition  to  approximately  $900 
million  on  crop  insurance,  a  portion  of  which  is  paid  by  farmers.  The  Administration's 
proposal  recognizes  this  budget  reality,  it  puts  an  end  to  the  authority  to  handout  such 
funds  in  the  fumre  widiout  paying  for  them,  and  it  conservatively  shifts  $1  billion 
annually  to  the  crop  insurance  program. 

Savings  to  taxpayers  ~  The  dual  system  of  ad  hoc  disaster  plus  crop  insurance  over  the 
past  six  years  has  cost  American  taxpayers  approximately  $2.4  billion  a  year.  The 
Administration's  proposal  according  to  0MB  would  cost  $8.1  billion  over  five  years  or 
approximately  $1.62  billion/year.  This  is  a  savings  of  $780  million/year  or  $3.9  billion 
over  five  years  using  actual  disaster  expenditure  figures  for  the  past  six  years! 

Even  using  the  conservative  $1  billion  in  disaster  expendimres  from  the  10-year  average, 
0MB 's  estimates  show  a  five-year  savings  of  $750  million.  If  CBO's  scoring  of  the  cost 
of  the  reform  proposal  is  used  with  OMB's  $1  billion  added  in  the  baseline,  taxpayers 
would  still  show  a  savings  of  $350  million  over  five  years! 

Improved  risk  management  options  to  farmers  -  For  the  many  reasons  outlined  above, 
crop  insurance  is  a  far  superior  means  for  addressing  disasters  than  ad  hoc  payments. 
Insurance  improves  farmers'  ability  to  obtain  financing  and  manage  weather  as  well  as 
market  risks.  The  increased  incentives  in  the  package  for  additional  levels  of  coverage 
will  help  insure  a  wider  number  of  farmers  are  adequately  protected. 

Utilization  of  the  private  sector  in  partnership  with  government  -  The  private  sector  now 
delivers  and  services  over  93%  of  all  federal  crop  insurance  in  the  U.S.  Farmers  prefer 
dealing  with  private  agents  and  companies  and  FCIC  has  already  decided  to  phase  out 
federal  paper  for  1995.  The  private  sector  provides  a  number  of  advantages  that  reduce 
government  costs,  improve  farmer  service,  and  avoid  duplicative  delivery  infrastructures. 
The  reform  proposal  builds  on  these  concepts.  However,  it  may  need  to  go  further  and 
utilize  the  private  sector  to  the  maximum  in  concert  with  the  Reinventing  Government 
initiative. 

Good  public  policy  -  Providing  for  the  risk  management  protection  of  America's  food 
and  fiber  production  system  is  vital  to  the  survival  of  that  sector  of  our  economy  and  to 
the  continued  availability  of  the  world's  safest  and  cheapest  food  suppy.  Risk  protection 
becomes  increasingly  important  due  to  the  fact  that  risks  increase  as  farm  program 
supports  decrease,  and  that  decreasing  trend  is  virtually  unstoppable.  It  is  in  the  public's 
interest  to  maintain  this  system  in  a  planned,  budget  accountable  manner.  The 
Administration's  proposal  does  this.  In  addition,  the  choice  of  a  insurance  solution  is  also 
the  best  policy  choice. 

Without  the  Ml  funding,  the  Administration's  reform  proposal  will  not  be  able  to  accomplish 
the  goals  necessary  to  provide  American  producers  of  food  and  fiber  with  the  risk  management 
protection  they  need  and  deserve  at  a  cost  that  American  taxpayers  can  afford  to  bear. 


81-128  0-94-11 


316 


ADVANTAGES  OF  PRIVATE  SECTOR  MPCI  DELIVERY 

*  Local  agents  are  in  position  in  the  local  communities  where  the  farmers  are,  they  are 
known,  they  are  trusted,  they  are  experienced,  they  are  licensed. 

*  Farmers  have  had  a  choice  between  direct  government  policies  and  reinsured  private 
policies,  they  have  chosen  private  policies  —  92%  private;  8%  government. 

*  Rural  communities  are  dependent  on  the  jobs  and  associated  economic  activity  created 
by  a  privately  delivered  crop  insurance  program  —  some  68,000  private  sector 
individuals  receive  all  or  a  part  of  their  income  from  the  sales,  service,  and  adjustment 
of  Federally  reinsured,  privately  delivered,  crop  insurance.  Many  of  these  people  are 
farmers  themselves. 

*  Farmers  don't  have  to  wait  in  line  to  get  their  crop  insurance.  The  agent  often  comes 
to  them,  agents  have  evening  and  weekend  hours. 

*  Agents  and  companies  already  have  established  relationships  with  over  700,000 
policyholders. 

^  Reinsured  companies  have  increasingly  put  their  own  money  at  risk  in  the  program  and 

compete  against  one  another.    This  creates  the  incentive  to  do  the  job  right  from  sales 
through  adjustment.  It  has  improved  program  loss  ratios  and  cut  down  on  claims  errors. 

*  Reinsured  companies  invest  added  money  in  the  program  through  the  development  of 
alternative  and  supplemental  products  which  provide  farmers  additional  means  to 
sufficiently  manage  their  risks. 

*  The  creation  of  a  government  infrastructure  sufficient  to  make  the  sales  and  perform  the 
service  necessary  to  achieve  the  levels  of  participation  being  called  for  would  be 
enormously  expensive  and  would  have  to  be  paid  whether  the  objective  was  achieved  or 
not. 

*  Reinsured  companies  and  local  insurance  agents  only  get  paid  if  they  deliver.  No  sales, 
no  cost.   This  provides  the  incentive  to  them  and  saves  the  government  money. 

*  Not  all  farmers  participate  in  government  programs,  while  they  may  purchase  and  need 
crop  insurance. 

*  Even  free  coverage  should  be  delivered  by  the  private  sector  in  order  to  seize  the 
marketing  opportunity  to  sell  fanners  the  higher  levels  of  coverage  necessary  to 
adequately  manage  their  risks  and  avoid  requests  for  disaster  assistance. 

*  With  a  more  stable  program,  private  companies  could  do  even  a  better  job  in  efficiently 
delivering  crop  insurance.  Annual  instability  affects  hiring,  strategic  planning,  long-term 
planning.    Mid-year  changes  significantly  affect  operational  efficiency. 

NOTE:   These  advantages  have  proved  themselves  through  the  tripling  of  farmer  participation 
in  the  program  since  delivery  was  largely  turned  over  to  the  private  sector. 


317 


318 


CO 

LU 

H 

< 

LU 

1- 

0) 

LU 

> 

O 

O 
(0 

z 

2 

^ 

3 

•o 

0) 

(0 

"Ql 

z 

Q. 

< 

LU 

CO 

a: 

05 

LL 

•^ 

O 

oa 

(0 

z 

o 

O 

CO 

i 

Q^ 

X 

< 

Q. 

^ 

o 

o 

>N 

(D 

>% 

(D 

(0 

2> 

H 

03 

3 

CO 

O) 

O 

a> 

< 

V 

■  J 

c 
o 


319 


</) 


(0 

c 


C 

.S 
1 


2 

C 


c 

CD 

0 

1 

5 

5 

1) 

5i 

u 

<n 

s 

3 

;c 

<y 

u. 

Q) 

I? 

GC 

u. 

V) 

«w 

.^^ 

c 

(/> 

s 

■^ 

S> 

GC 

0) 

(/) 

en 

(Q 

^ 

0 

«> 

s. 

5 

0 

£ 

c 

"53 

C 

o 


o 

CO 


o     o 

CM        •<— 


o     o 

▼-       CM 


o 

CO 


o 


o 


o 


o 


o 

QO 


o 
at 


^      3 


< 

(0 

I 
1 


320 


SUMMARY  OF  PAPERWORK  REDUCTION  mEAS 

1.  Timely  and  Predictable  Release  of  Program  Information 

Crop  program  information  and  the  corresponding  actuarial  materials  are  often  not 
released  in  time  for  companies  to  perform  strategic  planning  for  such  items  as  internal  training, 
agency  training,  and  proper  marketing  of  the  crop  insurance  program.  The  program  information 
and  actuarial  materials  need  to  be  in  the  hands  of  the  companies  six  months  in  advance  of  the 
sales  closing  date  for  the  crops  affected. 

2.  Tolerances  for  Acreage  Modifications 

After  the  acreage  reporting  date,  any  change  in  acreage,  regardless  of  size,  results  in 
modification  to  the  policy  and  reissuance  of  some  policy  paperwork  like  the  declaration  page. 
If  the  revision  is  upwards,  an  inspection  will  also  have  to  occur.  Tolerances  should  be 
established  such  that  acreage  can  change  within  tolerance,  without  requiring  inspections  and 
reissuance  of  policy  paperwork. 

3.  FCI-5  Agreement 

Eliminate  the  insured  signamre  portion  for  the  application  for  coverage  (FCI-5)  so  the 
company  or  the  agency  is  authorized  to  make  the  request.  The  insured  must  sign  the  resulting 
offer  of  insurance  (FCI-2)  anyway,  making  the  signatures  on  both  forms  duplicative  and 
requiring  an  extra  trip  for  the  insured  or  the  agent. 

4^        Wetlands  ACT 

Different  approaches  are  used  by  different  county  ASCS  offices  in  verifying  compliance 
with  Sodbuster/Swampbuster.  All  ASCS  offices  should  have  the  capability  to  print,  based  upon 
written  request,  copies  of  a  producer's  ASCS  Form  424  and  all  offices  should  use  the  same 
system  of  verification.  In  addition,  the  insured  must  also  sign  a  disclaimer  at  the  time  of 
processing  a  claim  that  they  remain  in  compliance  with  Sodbuster/Swampbuster.  ASCS  and 
FCIC  should  develop  an  interactive  database  to  streamline  this  whole  process. 

5.  Minimum  Premium 

Institute  a  minimum  premium  as  is  done  for  Crop  Hail  policies.  Companies  must  process 
policies  with  premiums  as  low  as  $1.00.  It  takes  virtually  the  same  time  and  effort  (hence  costs) 
to  process  small  premium  policies  as  it  does  large  ones. 

6.  Data  Reporting  Requirements 

We  must  electronically  transmit  12  different  records  types,  250  bytes  each,  with  a  total 
of  485  data  fields.  Duplicate  information  is  being  processed  by  the  FCIC  and  the  insurance 
companies.  We  need  to  eliminate  insignificant  data,  consolidate  multiple  records  into  one  record 
group  and/or  group  redundant  data  and  send  only  once. 

7.  Educational  Requirements 

We  must  furnish  agendas,  copies  of  tests,  handouts  and  various  other  materials  to 
compliance  auditors  aimually  to  support  our  training  programs.     In  addition,  we  also  must 


321 


provide  at  least  24  hours  of  classroom  training  to  each  adjuster.  Each  company  should  be  able 
to  provide  compliance  auditors  with  the  above  data  for  approval  of  our  training  programs  one 
time  and  not  on  an  annual  basis  unless  they  have  changed.  Also,  the  company  should  be  able 
to  determine  the  number  of  hours  of  training  each  individual  needs,  based  upon  observation  and 
not  some  arbitrary  requirement. 

8.  High  Risk  Land  Rating  Procedures 

This  is  currently  a  manual  rating  procedure  as  the  FCIC  does  not  have  an  automated  edit 
in  place.  In  its  present  state,  someone  must  physically  review  a  map  to  determine  if  a 
policyholder  is  insuring  high  risk  land.  This  is  very  time  consuming  and  inefficient,  as  the  maps 
are  not  easy  to  read,  which  can  result  in  improper  classification.  The  FCIC  itself  does  not 
currently  have  an  automated  edit  in  place  for  high  risk  land.  This  means  the  only  time  potential 
high  risk  land  locations  are  reviewed  is  in  the  event  of  a  compliance  audit.  Obviously,  the 
opportunity  for  high  risk  land  to  be  improperly  rated  and  never  corrected  is  great. 

FCIC  should  develop  a  database  of  high  risk  land  locations  that  the  insurance  companies 
can  load  into  their  systems.  This  would  provide  an  efficient  automated  method  in  which  to 
identify  high  risk  land  locations  and  then  rate  accordingly. 

9.  APH  &  Acreage  Reports 

Both  APH  and  Acreage  reports  are  required  separately  and  at  different  due  dates  thereby 
resulting  in  the  file  having  to  be  handled  twice  for  information  that  could  easily  be  provided  all 
at  one  time.  The  due  dates  for  both  of  these  pieces  of  data  should  be  the  same,  and  the  data 
should  be  reported  on  the  same  form. 

10.  Missing  Acreage  Reports 

Insureds  may  choose  to  not  file  an  acreage  report  and  try  to  get  out  of  a  policy  if  they 
perceive  conditions  to  be  good  at  that  point  in  time.  If  the  company  wishes  to  determine 
whether  in  fact  a  crop  was  planted  and  the  acreage,  they  must  absorb  the  costs  of  having  an 
adjuster  visit  the  farm.  The  company  should  have  die  latitude  to  cancel  the  policy  for  non- 
performance or  contract  with  an  adjuster  to  have  an  inspection  done  at  the  expense  of  the 
insured. 

11.  Obtaining  ASCS  Established  Yields 

On  many  units,  ASCS  program  yields  are  required  to  either  establish  or  complete  the 
APH  database  It  is  the  insured's  responsibility  to  provide  this  information  by  the  production 
reporting  date.  There  should  be  a  minimum  county  established  yield  that  could  be  used  when 
the  insured  does  not  provide  one.  This  yield  would  need  to  be  low  enough  in  order  to  provide 
an  incentive  for  the  insured  to  obtain  the  ASCS  established  yield.  Another  option  to  facilitate 
this  process  would  be  to  allow  the  companies  to  obtain  the  ASCS  established  yield  via  a 
documented  phone  call  to  the  ASCS  office  without  hardcopy  documentation. 

12.  Handling  Requests  to  the  Regional  Service  Office 

In  several  situations,  the  company  is  required  to  obtain  information  from  the  Regional 
Service  Office,  called  written  agreements,  in  order  to  write  and  service  a  policy.  A  tew 
examples  of  this  would  be  crops  that  do  not  have  a  rate  esublished  m  the  county,  for  obtaimng 


322 


the  determined  yields  on  category  C  crops  and  for  determining  a  classification  if  one  is  not 
published  on  peanuts  and  tobacco.  The  companies  should  be  given  the  necessary  authority  and 
training,  under  established  guidelines,  to  administer  the  situations  that  require  written 
agreements. 

13.  Consolidated  loss  adjustment  forms/process. 

We  would  request  that  ASCS  and  insurance  companies  develop  one  complete  source 
document  that  would  be  used  for  loss  adjustment  purposes.  The  form  would  include  line  item 
legal  descriptions,  acreage,  share,  practice,  intended  use,  compliance  with 
sodbuster/swampbuster,  established  yield  and  any  other  pertinent  data.  The  next  step  in  the 
process  would  be  automation  that  would  allow  companies  by  computer  modems  to  access  this 
information.  Companies  could  then  dial  up  and  request  this  for  insureds  with  losses  and  print 
the  data  in  their  own  offices. 

14.  ASCS  Paperwork  re  losses 

The  current  forms,  systems,  and  practice  between  crop  insurance  and  ASCS  as  it  relates 
to  losses  and  several  program  items  are  totally  inefficient  and  wasteful.  Greater  coordination 
and  discipline  needs  to  occur.   There  needs  to  be  one  set  of  rules  that  everyone  must  follow. 


323 


AACI      CIRB     NCIS 

PIA     IIAA 

I  BAA 


JOINT  POSITION  STATEMENT  ON  CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM* 

The  Objective  of  Crop  Insurance: 

The  crop  insurance  program  and,  therefore,  any  reform  of  it,  must  provide  farmers  with 
incentives  and  oppormnities  to  adequately  and  affordably  manage  their  production  risks.  This  risk 
protection  should  meet  farmers'  most  basic  income  and  fmancial  needs  if  a  natural  disaster  strikes. 

Measurement  of  That  Objective: 

The  success  of  a  government-assisted  crop  insurance  program  should  be  measured  by  the  extent 
to  which  it:  (1)  encourages  farmers  to  get  the  most  risk  protection  per  dollar  of  government  and  private 
money  expended;  and  (2)  eliminates  the  need  for  ad  hoc  disaster  assisunce. 

Achievement  of  That  Objective: 

Reform  of  the  crop  insurance  program  must  build  upon  the  underlying  framework  of  the  much 
improved  existing  program.  That  framework  includes  individualized  protection  based  on  actual 
production  history  delivered  by  the  private  sector.  A  reformed  program  should  treat  those  farmers  who 
currently  take  the  initiative  to  manage  their  own  risks  through  crop  insurance  fairly,  and  it  certainly 
should  not  penalize  them.  The  crop  insurance  product  itself  must  provide  adequate  protection  at  an 
affordable  price.  '  •  -" 

By  itself  universal  availability  of  a  catastrophic  level  of  coverage  at  little  or  no  charge  will  not 
be  sufficient.  Significant  participation  at  greater  than  catastrophic  levels  of  protection  is  necessary  to 
adequately  protect  farmers  and  replace  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance.  Only  through  a  continued  significant 
involvement  of  the  private  sector  in  the  risk  bearing  and  delivery  of  crop  insurance  can  Federal  dollars 
be  leveraged  to  meet  these  objectives  in  today's  budget  environment, 

ELEMENTS  OF  A  REFORMED  CROP  INSURANCE  PROGRAM: 

(1)  Fliminate  Ad  ¥nr  Disaster  Payments.  Multiple  peril  crop  insurance  (MPCI)  must  be 
established  as  it  was  intended  to  be  in  1980,  as  the  sole  mechanism  for  delivering  disaster 
assistance  to  farmers.  This  cannot  be  achieved  without  removing  the  authonty  for  ad  hoc 
disaster  assistance.  As  long  as  the  possibility  of  such  ad  hoc  assistance  exists,  many  agricultural 
producers  will  not  take  the  steps  necessary  to  manage  their  risk  through  crop  insurance.  The 
Federal  Govemmem's  liberal  provision  of  ad  hoc  assistance  in  the  past  decade  has  hindered  the 
success  of  the  crop  insurance  program  and  greatly  increased  the  taxpayer  costs  of  assistmg 
farmers  in  times  of  disaster.  The  monies  that  have  historically  been  expended  on  ad  hoc 
assistance  should  be  transferred  to  the  crop  insurance  baseUne  to  fund  improvements  in  and 
increased  availability  of  that  program.  Any  type  of  permanent  disaster  program  established 
for  crops  not  currently  covered  by  MPCI  should  include  a  private  sector  delivery  element. 


*    Developed  prior  to  the  release  of  the  legislative  language. 


324 


Joint  Position  Statement 


(2)  Universally  Available  Catastrophic  Coverage.  We  support  the  provision  of  some  catastrophic 
level  of  crop  insurance  at  little  or  no  charge  if  that  coverage  is  structured  and  delivered  in  a  way 
that  will  enhance  the  incentive  for  farmers  to  acquire  increased  protection  which  is  adequate  to 
meet  their  true  risk  management  needs.  This  coverage  should  be  delivered  exclusively  by  the 
private  sector.  The  catastrophic  coverage  should  be  a  standard  MPCI  policy  that  is  otherwise 
the  same  as  a  higher  coverage  level  policy  so  that  it  may  be  incorporated  easily  into  a  single 
policy  providing  higher  coverage.  I.e.,  coverage  should  be  on  an  individualized  farm  basis 
using  actual  proven  yields,  whenever  yield  records  exist.  This  would  reduce  farmer  confusion 
and  facilitate  the  purchase  of  additional  protection. 

(3)  Exclusive  Private  Sector  Delivery.  Maximum  participation  of  farmers  at  optimum  levels  of 
insurance  protection  can  best  be  achieved  through  the  use  of  reinsured  MPCI  products  and  one 
marketing  and  service  system  —  the  private  sector.  There  should  be  no  government  delivery 
nor  any  Sales  and  Service  Contractors  (Master  Marketers).  This  extends  to  the  catastrophic  level 
of  coverage  as  well.  The  local  agent  will  be  the  one-stop  shop  for  crop  insurance,  or  in  many 
cases  will  go  to  the  farmer  to  make  the  farmer's  home  the  point  of  sale.  The  government  can 
not  afford  nor  should  try  to  duplicate  the  tens  of  thousands  of  people  comprising  the  current 
private  sector  crop  insurance  sales  and  service  force.  Exclusive  private  delivery  would  also 
capitalize  on  the  existing  relationships  with  nearly  700,0CX)  policyholders.  Direct  FCIC  policies 
and  the  infi^stiucture  accompanying  them  should  be  eliminated. 

(4)  Each  Farmer  On  Record  As  Insured  Or  Waivine  Coverage.  The  FSA  Office  should  distribute 
a  certificate  to  each  participant  of  record  several  months  before  the  crop  insurance  sales  closing 
date  entitling  them  to  a  certain  level  of  insurance  coverage  and  verifying  their  eligibility  for 
insurance.  The  certificate  would  double  as  a  statement  which  the  farmer  would  sign  and  return 
to  the  FSA  Office  if  they  chose  not  to  insure  themselves  with  any  catastrophic  or  other  level  of 
coverage.  That  statement  would  indicate  the  recipient  had:  1)  been  offered  the  catastrophic  and 
any  other  coverage;  2)  understood  that  this  was  the  limit  of  what  he  or  she  could  expect  from 
the  government  in  the  event  of  a  crop  disaster,  and  3)  declined  to  participate.  Each  farm 
program  participant  should  either  be  insured  or  have  a  signed  statement  on  record.  Farmers  who 
do  not  participate  in  any  farm  programs  involving  the  FSA  office  could  receive  the  same  level 
of  insurance  coverage  by  contacting  an  insurance  agent  without  the  need  for  a  certificate. 

(5)  Separate  USDA  Risk  Management  Unit.  A  reorganized  Department  of  Agriculture  should 
contain  a  unit  with  adequate  and  experienced  staff  fiiUv  devoted  to  the  management  of  the  crop 
insurance  program  and  standby  disaster  program  for  uninsured  crops.  FCIC  should  create  a 
reinsurance  division  staffed  with  personnel  with  experience  in  the  insurance  or  reinsurance 
industry.  As  a  laboratory  for  reinventing  government.  FCIC  should  explore  turning  over  a 
number  of  program  functions  to  the  private  sector  in  accordance  with  guidelines  established  by 
FCIC. 

(6)  Government  Must  Continue  as  a  Reinsurer.  The  government  must  continue  to  provide 
catastrophic  reinsurance  to  the  private  sector  on  all  approved  policies.  An  appropriate  and 
equitable  blend  of  risk  sharing  between  private  insurance  companies  and  the  government  should 
be  considered  for  all  levels  of  coverage. 


325 


Joint  Position  Statement  3 

(7)  Permanent  Joint  Task  Force.  A  pennanent  FCIC/Industry  Task  Force  should  be  established  for 
the  purpose  of  providing  a  mechanism  for  a  continuing  working  dialogue  on  program  issues  be 
they  one-time  or  ongoing  (i.e.,  high  moisture  com,  quality  adjustment  in  general,  APH,  expense 
reimbursement,  risk  sharing,  new  products,  etc.).  The  Task  Force  would  include  reinsured 
company  representatives,  agents,  adjusters,  and  government  agency  representatives  and  would 
operate  on  a  roll-up-the-sleeves  cooperative  philosophy.  Such  a  group  could  help  reduce 
administrative  costs  substantially  by  heading  off  practical  difficulties  of  various  proposals  early 
in  the  process  and  certainly  prior  to  implementation. 

(8)  Approve  Alternative  and  Supplemental  Policies.  The  existing  authorities  for  FCIC  to  approve 
alternative  and  supplemental  policies  and  to  undertake  pilot  programs  with  different  types  of 
insurance  coverage  should  be  retained  and  fully  utilized. 

(9)  Provide  Fair  and  Adequate  Expense  Reimbursement.  Congress  has  made  the  commitment  to  the 
private  sector  delivery  of  crop  insurance  as  the  most  cost  efficient  method  of  increasing 
participation  and  thereby  spreading  the  risk.  If  the  government  continues  to  pay  the 
administrative  and  operating  costs  associated  with  the  sale  of  crop  insurance,  whether  loaded  mto 
the  premium  or  paid  separately  as  it  is  now,  then  this  reimbursement  should  be  based  on  the 
reasonable  costs  of  delivering  the  program.  It  must  be  recognized  that  those  costs  increase  as 
the  administrative  requirements  imposed  under  the  program  and  ordinary  costs  of  domg  business 
increase  If  the  government  decides  not  to  pay  these  costs,  then  the  prohibition  on  loading  these 
costs  into  the  premium  must  be  removed  and  very  strict  guidelines  established  to  insure  umform 
and  high-level  standards  of  service  to  policyholders. 

(10)  Reduce  Administr..ivp  Costs  of  Program.  FCIC  should  conduct  a  thorough  review,  in 
cooperation  with  the  private  sector  and  farm  groups,  of  the  paperwork  burdens  of  both  the 
current  and  any  reformed  program.  Steps  should  be  taken  to  reduce  those  burdens  and 
streamline,  simplify,  and  computerize  the  administration  of  the  program. 

(11)  F^tahlish  a  Catastrophic  Ia)ss  Fund.  A  catastrophic  loss  fund,  perhaps  by  state,  by  crop,  should 
be  established  to  fund  widespread  disasters  to  avoid  the  need  for  large  premium  rate  increases 
following  widespread  disasters. 

(12)  A  Competitive  Private  Sector.  In  the  interest  of  competition,  the  program  should  be  crafted  to 
encourage  participation  of  both  small  and  large  companies  as  risk  bearer 

(13)  ron.innPd  Propram  Reform.  FCIC  should  not  let  reform  happen  without  continuing  to  address 
various  aspects  of  the  current  and  reformed  program  that  remain  areas  of  recumng  problems. 
FCIC  should  thoroughly  review  premium  rates  on  a  county  by  county  basis  to  remove  existing 
anomalies.  The  rates  of  a  reformed  program  should  reflect  the  nsk  exposure  of  the  new 
program  rather  than  the  past  program. 

American  Association  of  Crop  Insurers  (AACI) 

Crop  Insurance  Research  Bureau,  Inc.  (CIRB) 

National  Crop  Insurance  Services  (NCIS) 

Professional  Insurance  Agents  (PLA) 

Independent  Insurance  Agents  of  America  (IIAA) 

Independent  Bankers  Association  of  America  (IBAA) 


326 


.a 


I 


I 

8 

i 

(A 

GC 
O 

I 


3     C 

<J    Si 

-a  0  i^ 

ll-l 

S^l 

lU  ^   t 

ol 

1 

13 


^15 
Sill 


I 


o   O) 

S  —  ^    ™ 
iS    C    3   CL 

S,  $2  u  m 

q:  £  o  R) 


xi 

3 

o  E    •  ■" 
in       E 


M    <9 


i 

f 


^^^ 

(A 

s 

S 

o 

tt) 

(0 

C 

a: 

<0 

o 

C) 

_l 

g 

o 

s 

u. 

t 

a 

8 

z 


327 


ui 

z 

I 

i 

i 

UI 
GC 

CO 

1 

i 

i 


! 

u 

•i 


8  S  0  > 

bO  60  t>0T3 

<   <   <  < 


328 


NATIONAL  CROP  INSURANCE  SERVICES 

7301  CXXIEGE  BOULEVARD.  SUITE  170 
OVERLAND  PARK.  KANSAS  66210 


Testimony  given  to 

U.S.  House  of  Representatives  Committee  on  Agriculture 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

by  Robert  Parkerson,  President, 

National  Crop  Insurance  Services. 


April  21,  1994 


National  Crop  Insurance  Services  (NCiS)  has  been  serving  the  crop  insurance  industry, 
in  one  form  or  another,  since  1915.  Our  organization  has  continuously  evolved  over  the 
years  to  meet  the  changing  needs  of  crop  insurers. 

We  were  organized  for  three  primary  purposes:  1)  to  gather  and  analyze  crop  statistics 
so  that  appropriate  premium  rates  can  be  developed;  2)  to  develop  standard  policy  terms 
and  conditions  so  that  agents  and  consumers  need  to  understand  only  a  few  basic 
program  options;  and,  3)  to  develop  loss  adjustment  methods  and  adjuster  training  to 
support  the  appraisal  of  crop  damage  so  that  losses  can  be  settled  fairiy. 

NCIS  has  the  professional  staff,  experience  and  organization  to  support  the  increasingly 
sophisticated  risk  management  needs  of  farmers.  The  services  of  NCiS  help  insurance 
companies  position  themselves  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  farm  community. 

Industry  applauds  the  Refomn  effort  to  explicitly  recognize  past  off-budget  expenditures 
on  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  and  incorporate  those  expenditures  into  the  budget  for  crop 
insurance.  The  following  is  our  written  testimony  addressing  the  twelve  items  mentioned 
in  Chairman  Johnson's  letter  of  April  8,  1994. 


329 


Adequacy  of  Premium  Subsidies:  This  is  a  complex  issue.  The  Refomi  Act 
requires  actuarially  sound  premium  rates  and  sufficient  premium  subsidy  to  attract 
farmers  to  purchase  buy-up  coverages.  If  the  underlying  rate  structure  is 
inadequate,  then  premium  subsidies  which  are  uniformly  applied  across  the 
country  will  result  in  adverse  selection  in  improperly  rated  areas.  Catastrophic 
premium  subsidy  is  most  likely  adequate  since  loss  ratio  experience  at  50%  level 
coverage  is  acceptable.  However,  the  subsidies  at  higher  coverage  levels  must 
take  into  account  the  actuarial  history  of  state/crop  combinations  with  unfavorable 
experience.  At  current  MPCI  rates,  several  state/crop  combinations,  such  as 
Midwest  com  and  soybeans,  appear  actuarially  sound.  Wheat  and  cotton 
experience  in  various  states  is  not  satisfactory.  Several  minor  crops  also  have 
unfavorable  loss  ratio  experience.  The  private  industry,  with  our  historical 
experience  and  knowledge  of  crop  insurance  rating,  would  be  willing  to  participate 
more  actively  with  the  FCIC  in  resolving  this  complex  issue. 

Processing  Fee:  The  processing  fee  of  $50  per  crop  per  county  (maximum  of 
$100  per  producer)  would  probably  cover  minimum  enrollment  requirements. 
However,  establishing  an  individual  APH  database,  processing  acreage  reports, 
perfonning  mandatory  inspections  and  ensuring  other  USDA  program  compliance 
would  cost  more  than  the  suggested  $50  processing  fee.  For  example,  in  1 992 
there  was  approximately  $760  million  of  gross  premium.  At  an  administrative 
expense  reimbursement  of  26%  (31%  less  loss  adjustment  expense  of  5%)  and 
approximately  689,000  policies  with  premium,  the  average  enrollment  and 
processing  cost  per  policy  is  estimated  at  approximately  $280.  ASCS/FSA  will 
also  incur  the  same  basic  costs  as  industry. 

Mandatory  Linkage:  Mandatory  linkage,  although  not  desirable  in  an  insurance 
program,  would  provide  the  necessary  program  participation  in  order  to  make  crop 
insurance  a  more  workable  system.  The  habitual  practice  of  ad  hoc  disaster 
payments  provides  a  tremendous  disincentive  for  farmers  to  seriously  consider 
crop  insurance  enrollment  as  a  much  needed  risk  management  tool  (see 
GAO/RECD-92-25  Crop  Insurance). 

Dual  Delivery:  Industry  has  indicated  a  willingness  to  wori<  with  USDA  for  dual 
delivery  but  additional  government  costs  will  be  incurred.  Initially,  the  private 
sector's  delivery  systems  (computer  systems,  manuals,  training,  and  staff)  will 
have  to  be  duplicated  for  ASCS/FSA  delivery.  This  will  be  a  tremendous  start-up 
cost  to  the  government.  In  the  long  run,  it  may  cost  the  same  or  more  to  deliver 
MPCI  through  ASCS/FSA  as  through  the  current  delivery  system.  Currently, 
private  sector  delivery  is  a  variable  cost  to  the  govemment.  Under  dual  delivery, 
certain  crop  insurance  program  costs  would  become  a  higher  fixed  govemment 
expense. 

Actual  Production  History:  Industry  and  FCIC  have  jointly  wori<ed  on  the 
improvement  of  the  APH  process.  Four-year  modified  APH  is  the  most  recent 
attempt  to  meet  the  risk  management  needs  of  the  American  farmer  and 
simultaneously  achieve  actuarial  soundness.  Modified  APH  encourages  farmers 


330 


>v 


to  provide  their  own  records  which  should  result  in  better  individualized  coverage. 
Several  years  of  experience  are  needed  before  this  system  can  be  property 
evaluated.  Thus,  only  minimal  changes  should  be  considered  until  sufficient  data 
has  been  obtained. 

6.  Noninsurable  Crops:  Enrollment  and  processing  will  be  a  major  hurdle  at  first. 
In  the  long  run,  government  will  be  in  a  better  position  to  determine  the  risk 
exposure  of  the  agricultural  production  sector  and  provide  the  necessary  resources 
required  to  manage  the  system.  As  experience  data  and  information  become 
available,  noninsurable  crops  can  be  incorporated  into  the  existing  MPCI  program. 
However,  careful  screening  criteria  should  be  in  place  before  transferring 
noninsurable  crops  to  the  insurance  program. 

7.  Likelihood  of  Ad  Hoc  Disaster  Assistance:  Present  budget  pressure  and  the 
language  contained  in  the  Refomn  Act  would  suggest  the  likelihood  of  future 
disaster  assistance  is  small.  Historically,  assistance  has  been  routinely  provided 
and  the  credibility  of  the  crop  insurance  program  has  been  seriously  damaged. 
Industry  stands  opposed  to  the  provision  of  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  if  crop 
insurance  is  to  be  a  viable  risk  management  tool  for  the  American  fanner. 

8.  Expense  Reimbursement  Formula:  When  establishing  rates  for  other  lines  of 
insurance,  state  regulators  typically  allow  an  allocation  for  expense  of  doing 
business,  provision  for  underwriting  gain,  and  the  loss  component  of  the  rate. 
Currently,  FCIC  provides  an  administrative  expense  reimbursement  to  the 
company  and  a  subsidized  loss  component  of  the  rate  to  the  farnier.  There  is  no 
formal  provision  for  an  undenwriting  gain  in  the  current  program  other  than  the 
portfolio  management  of  the  Standard  Reinsurance  Agreement  (SRA).  In  the  past 
several  years,  the  administrative  requirements  of  the  program  have  increased 
substantially  without  any  consideration  of  the  additional  costs  imposed  on 
companies. 

9.  Competitive  Rating:  The  social  dimension  of  the  program  coupled  with  FCIC's 
control  over  the  actuarial  and  underwriting  functions  do  not  make  competitive  rating 
a  prudent  practice  for  the  industry  at  this  time.  At  an  historical  loss  ratio  of  1 .47 
(not  including  1993  experience  which  is  presently  at  2.18),  it  is  unclear  at  this  time 
how  the  competitive  rating  provision  to  lower  the  rates  charged  to  farmers  would 
be  consistent  with  the  targeted  loss  ratio  of  1.10.  Suggesting  that  companies 
lower  the  rates  charged  to  farmers  would  also  be  inconsistent  with  concerns  over 
solvency  in  our  industry  as  well  as  other  lines  of  private  insurance.  Competitive 
rating  could  jeopardize  companies'  fiduciary  responsibility  with  the  private 
reinsurance  community.  The  existence  of  private  reinsurance  is  a  critical 
component  of  the  private  delivery  system.  Private  reinsurance  represents  a 
sizeable  cost  savings  and  transfers  substantial  risk  from  the  government  to  private 
industry.  Private  companies  must  have  a  reasonable  opportunity  for  gain  to  attract 
the  necessary  capital  to  support  the  program. 


331 


10.  Non-Standard  Classification  System  (NCS):  NCS  is  an  important  first  step  in 
corectly  underwriting  individual  insureds  who  are  potentially  abusing  the  program. 
The  system  has  been  modified  to  correct  for  area  wide  disasters  but  further 
improvements  are  still  required.  Only  3.6%  of  insureds  are  cun-ently  impacted  by 
this  program. 


1 1 .  Group  Risl<  Plan:  Although  the  GRP  may  achieve  certain  public  policy  goals  and 
may  have  a  place  in  covering  certain  noninsurable  crops,  it  is  not  based  on 
standard  insurance  principles  and  practices.  GRP  has  met  some  resistance  from 
state  regulators  and  consumers.  Industry  has  expressed  concems  to  FCIC  over 
the  rating  and  implementation  of  this  progreun. 


12.  Marl<et  Value  Protection  Plan:  The  MVP  program  represents  a  breakthrough  in 
allowing  private  industry  to  introduce  creative  solutions  to  meet  the  risk 
management  needs  of  producers.  The  MVP  product  combines  both  yield  and  price 
risk.  MVP  better  enables  the  fanner  to  manage  his  risk  by  using  the  martlet  to 
provide  a  price  for  his  crop  that  may  not  be  possible  at  harvest-time.  The 
combination  of  MPCI/MVP  allows  the  farmer  to  fully  fonward  price  his  production 
with  insurance  protection.  We  encourage  FCIC  to  continue  to  wori<  with  private 
industry  to  find  other  ways  and  solutions  to  meet  the  changing  risk  management 
needs  of  America's  farmers. 


332 


Crop  Insurance  Research  Bureau  Inc. 

9200  Indian  Creek  Parkway,  Suite  220  •  Overland  Park,  Kansas  66210-2008 
Tel  (913)  338-0470  •  Fax  (913)  661-1640 


Testimony  of 

Thomas  A.  Rudisill,  CPCU,  Chairman 

Crop  Insurance  Research  Bureau,  Inc. 
Overland  Park,  Kansas 

Before  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

Committee  on  Agriculture 
U.S.  House  of  Representatives 

Regarding  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Program 

April  21,  1994 


Mr.  Chairman,  the  Crop  Insurance  Research  Bureau,  Inc.,  ("CIRB")  is  a  national 
trade  association  representing  34  companies  that  provide  multiple  peril  and  crop  hail 
insurance  to  the  nation's  farmers.  I  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  share  with  the  committee 
our  views  on  the  future  direction  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Program,  and  particularly, 
our  thoughts  on  H.R.  4217,  the  Administration's  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  put  forward 
by  Secretary  Espy  last  month. 

Coupled  with  the  positive  changes  put  into  the  program  last  year  through  the  budget 
reconciliation  legislation.  Secretary  Espy's  proposal  gives  us  a  measure  of  hope  that  for  the 
first  time  in  recent  years,  we  as  private  insurers  can  get  on  with  what  we  do  best  -  providing 
a  comprehensive  risk  management  tool  to  the  agricultural  producers  of  this  country  -- 
without  continually  looking  over  our  shoulders  for  the  specter  of  federal  ad  hoc  disaster 
payments.  Conceptually,  the  Administration's  reform  proposal  is  acceptable  to  us,  but  there 
are  a  number  of  bothersome  aspects  that  must  be  addressed  before  it  can  be  successful. 


333 


For  many  years,  CIRB  has  actively  supponed  an  actuarially  sound  federal  crop 
insurance  program,  delivered  by  the  private  sector  and  backed  with  federal  catastrophic 
reinsurance.  We  believe  that  the  involvement  of  both  small  and  large  risk-bearing  entities 
is  critical  to  its  success.  In  addition,  CIRB  strongly  supports  private  crop-hail  insurance  and 
opposes  any  legislation  that  might  negatively  impact  this  successful  insurance  product. 
Finally,  CIRB  has  long  supported  the  elimination  of  Congressionally-authorized  ad  hoc 
disaster  payments  because  as  has  been  painfully  demonstrated  over  the  past  six  years,  from 
both  a  policy  perspective  as  well  as  a  fiscal  standpoint,  crop  insurance  cannot  co-exist  with 
ad  hoc  disaster  payments. 

While  we  clearly  have  concerns  with  some  portions  of  the  Secretary's  proposal  ~  such 
as  the  continuation  of  the  dual  delivery  system,  the  appUcation  of  individual  yields  and 
actual  production  history  on  the  low-level  catastrophic  coverage  and  the  ability  of  our 
companies  to  adequately  service  producers  who  choose  only  the  low-level  coverage  option  - 
-  we  are  cautiously  optimistic  that  CIRB  companies  could  operate  under  this  new  system. 
We  pledge  to  work  with  you  and  your  subcommittee  to  insure  that  the  final  legislation  both 
provides  producers  with  the  risk  management  options  they  need  and  allows  our  companies 
to  provide  the  tools  to  achieve  that  goal  -  at  an  affordable  cost  to  the  American  taxpayer. 

Two  components  critical  to  the  success  of  this  proposal  are  the  willingness  of 
Congress  to  forgo  future  ad  hoc  disaster  payments  and  full  funding  of  the  federal  crop 
insurance  program  through  the  shifting  of  $1  billion  annually  from  off-budget  disaster 
spending  to  the  crop  insurance  program.  In  the  face  of  a  continuing  real  decline  in  federal 
farm  program  expenditures,  providing  risk  protection  through  crop  insurance  is  the  most 
responsible  public  policy  option.  Given  the  many  problems  associated  with  applying  the 
"Pay-As-You-Go"  requirements  of  the  Budget  Act  to  disaster  funding,  moving  a  portion  of 


334 


the  money  on-budget  to  fully  fund  the  crop  insurance  program  makes  good  sense.  However, 
without  full  funding  of  this  program,  it  will  have  little  chance  of  success.  The  funding  issue 
is  the  key  element  of  this  proposal.  If  this  legislation  were  to  become  law  without  sufficient 
funding,  it  would  place  the  crop  insurance  program  in  imminent  danger. 

Mr.  Chairman,  you  and  the  members  of  your  subcommittee  have  voiced  strong 
support  for  an  end  to  the  current  schizophrenic  two-track  insurance  versus  disaster  system 
and  we  urge  you  to  continue  your  support. 

I  would  now  like  to  highlight  a  few  of  CIRB's  specific  concerns  with  the  Secretary's 
crop  insurance  reform  proposal: 

•  Dual  Delivery  System  -  While  the  goal  of  the  proposed 
legislation  is  to  eliminate  ad  hoc  federal  disaster  payments  and 
to  encourage  producers  to  actively  manage  their  risks,  the  Farm 
Service  Agency  may  not  be  the  best  source  of  information  to 
allow  producers  to  best  assess  their  true  risk  management 
needs.  Should  a  dual  delivery  system  be  created.  Congress  must 
insure  that  FSA  employees  are  adequately  trained.  Without  a 
clear  understanding  of  the  various  insurance  options  available, 
serious  problems  could  arise  if  a  disaster  strikes  and  only  a 
minority  of  producers  "buy  up"  to  the  65%  or  75%  level  of 
coverage.  We  prefer  to  see  producers  come  to  professional 
insurance  agents,  who  are  well  prepared  to  explain  these 
various  insurance  options  and  provide  quality  service  after  the 
sale. 

•  Actual  Production  History  -  As  we  understand  the  Secretary's 
proposal,  actual  production  history  ("APH")  would  be  required 
both  for  the  catastrophic  level  as  well  as  for  higher  coverage 
levels.  Given  the  time  and  paperwork  required  to  provide  and 
report  that  information,  for  the  sake  of  reducing  cost  and 
complexity,  catastrophic  coverage  should  be  based  on  the  ASCS 
yield  as  adjusted  by  FCIC  (T-yield). 

•  Effective  Date  -  The  Secretary's  proposal  calls  for  an  effective 
date  of  the  crop  year  immediately  following  approval  of  the 
Act.  Should  this  proposal  become  law  in  the  next  few  months, 
both  private  companies  and  FCIC  would  be  under  tremendous 
pressure  to  make  the  new  product  available  for  this  fall's  crops. 
Given  the  importance  of  this  initiative  and  the  amount  of  time 


335 


and  effort  spent  to  develop  this  proposal,  the  effective  date 
should  be  postponed  to  insure  that  federal  employees  are  well 
trained  and  that  companies  and  agents  have  the  materials 
necessarj'  to  make  this  program  succeed.  An  artincially 
expedited  start-up  date  could  become  a  disaster  in  itself. 

•  Flexibility  in  Required  Risk  Retentions  -  The  Secretary's 
proposal  requires  reinsured  companies  to  bear  a  sufficient  share 
of  any  potential  loss  ...  so  as  to  insure  that  the  reinsured 
company  will  sell  and  service  policies  of  insurance  in  a  sound 
and  prudent  manner.  However,  the  proposed  1995  SRA  will 
make  it  extremely  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  for  a  number  of 
private  providers  to  continue  their  participation  in  the  program. 
This  in  turn,  will  take  away  an  imponant  element  of  choice  for 
producers.  As  companies  agree  to  assume  increased  risk  of 
loss,  there  must  be  a  commensurate  potential  for  profit  in  a 
program  actuarially  based  on  a  loss. 

•  Catastrophic  Expense  Reimbursement  -  For  the  catastrophic 
level  coverage,  the  Secretary's  proposal  provides  for  a  $50  - 
$100  processing  fee,  and  in  the  event  of  a  loss,  $150  to  adjust 
the  loss.  The  required  effort  on  the  part  of  the  agent  coupled 
with  the  true  cost  of  adjusting  the  loss  will  likely  relegate 
virtually  all  of  these  "catastrophic  -  only"  contracts  to  the 
federal  government. 

In  summary,  Mr.  Chairman,  CIRB  supports  the  efforts  of  this  subcommittee  and 
those  of  Secretary  Espy  to  rationalize  the  risk  protection  functions  of  the  federal  crop 
insurance  program.  We  believe  that  the  Congress  has  a  golden  opportunity  this  year  to 
make  this  program  work  for  both  producers  and  taxpayers.  The  participation  of  national, 
regional  and  single-state  operations  is  essential  for  the  crop  insurance  program  to  grow  and 
improve.  The  private  sector  simply  must  have  the  opportunity  for  a  fair  return.  A  fair  1995 
SRA  coupled  with  the  best  aspects  of  crop  insurance  reform  will  assure  continued  private 
sector  involvement. 

As  you  and  your  staff  work  through  the  complexities  of  this  proposal,  I  would  like  to 
offer  you  the  expertise  of  the  many  experienced  crop  insurance  specialists  from  our  member 
companies  as  we  work  toward  our  common  goal.  Thank  you. 


336 

April  19,  1994 


The  Honorable  Jim  Sasser 
Chairman,  Senate  Budget  Committee 
United  States  Senate 
Washington,  DC   20510^ 

Dear  Chairman  Sasser: 

f 

In  your  role  as  Chairman  of  the  Senate  Budget  Committee,  the  undersigned  organizations  and 
the  thousands  of  farmers  and  ranchers  we  represent  urge  you  to  fully  fund  the 
Administration's  budget  request  for  its  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  during  your 
conference  on  the  Fiscal  Year  1995  Budget  Resolution.   While  we  may  not  all  agree  on 
every  detail  of  the  proposal  and  will  be  working  to  improve  the  package,  we  stand 
unanimously  behind  the  provision  of  funding  for  the  package  and  believe  that  it  warrants 
your  support. 

In  standing  behind  the  fundamental  concept  of  providing  a  low  level  of  catastrophic  coverage 
to  all  farm  program  participants,  we  are  taking  a  bold  step  which  many  of  us  have  previously 
been  unwilling  to  take.   However,  given  the  continued  budget  pressures  facing  all 
government  programs  and  the  policy  reasons  favoring  an  insurance  approach  to  disaster 
relief,  we  believe  the  time  is  right  for  change  and  for  committing  to  a  single  predictable 
approach  to  disaster  relief. 

The  Administration's  approach  reflects  truthful  budgeting,  budget  discipline,  good  public 
policy,  improved  risk  management  options  for  farmers,  and  reduced  costs  for  taxpayers.    The 
$1  billion  being  requested  is  actually  conservative  due  to  the  fact  that  over  the  last  six  years, 
ad  hoc  disaster  bills  have  cost  the  American  taxpayer  $1.^75  billion  annually.   We  believe 
the  House  Budget  Committee  took  a  historic  step  by  providing  approximately  $3  billion  in 
additional  funds  for  the  crop  insurance  baseline.   We  hope  that  the  conference  committee  will 
lend  its  leadership  to  this  effort  by  providing  the  full  Administration  request  of  $4.5  billion 
over  five  years. 

Thank  you  for  your  consideration  of  this  issue.   We  look  forward  to  the  Conference 
Committee's  positive  action  on  this  proposal. 

Sincerely, 

American  Agriculture  Movement 
American  Soybean  Association 
National  Association  of  Wheat  Growers 
National  Com  Growers  Association 
National  Cotton  Council  of  America 
National  Farmers  Organization 
National  Farmers  Union 
U.S.  Rice  Producers  Group 

cc:    House  and  Senate  Budget  Conferees 


337 


? 


AMER^Q^  /laBCJOATION  OF  NURSERYMB^ 

1250  I  STREET.  N.W.  /  SUITE  500  /  WASHZNGTON,  D.C.  aOOOS  /  208/788-2800 


TESTIMOKY 

Before  the 

UNITED  STATES  HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT,  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

April  21,  1994 

Mr.  Chairman,  and  Members  of  the  Subcommittee,  the  American 
Association  of  Nurserymen  (AAN)  welcomes  this  opportunity  to 
present  the  nursery  industry's  views  regarding  legislation  to 
reform  the  federal  crop  insurance  system. 

BACKGROUND 

Founded  in  1875,  AAN  is  the  national  trade  organization  of  the 
nursery  industry.   We  directly  represent  approximately  2,300 
growers,  landscape  professionals,  garden  center  retailers  and 
horticultural  distributors.   Through  the  membership  of  our  state 
and  regional  nursery  and  landscape  associations,  AAN  represents 
an  additional  16,000  family  farms  and  small  businesses  in  the 
nursery  industry. 

ECONOMIC  STATURE  OF  NURSERY  INDUSTRY 

According  to  USDA's  Economic  Research  Service  (USDA-ERS) ,  the 
nursery  and  greenhouse  industry  continues  to  outpace  other 
agricultural  sectors  in  cash  receipts.   Nursery  and  greenhouse 
crops  totaled  an  estimated  $9.0  billion  in  1993  —  representing 
nearly  11  percent  of  the  total  cash  receipts  for  all  U.S.  farm 
crops . 

Nursery  and  greenhouse  crops  in  1992  ranked  6th  in  total  grower 
cash  receipts  among  all  farm  commodities  —  ahead  of  such  major 
crops  as  wheat,  cotton  and  tobacco.   Nursery  and  greenhouse  crop 
production  now  ranks  in  the  top  five  agricultural  commodities  in 
23  states,  and  in  the  top  10  in  42  states,  including  13  of  the 
states  represented  by  Members  of  this  Subcommittee. 

This  impressive  industry  record  of  growth  becomes  even  more  so 
when  one  considers  that  unlike  other  segments  of  agriculture,  the 
nursery  industry  does  not  receive  —  nor  does  it  desire  —  any 
federal  subsidies  or  price  supports.   What  we  do  want  is  for  the 
unique  nature  of  nursery  crop  production  to  be  fully  recognized 
as  part  of  agriculture  and  for  this  recognition  to  be  reflected 
appropriately  in  any  reform  of  the  federal  crop  insurance 
program. 


Garden  Centers  o(  America /Horlicumjral  Resocfch  msfthjle  /NotkXKil  Association  of  Plant  Patent  Owners/ 
IMational  Landscape  Associalion/Wtxjiesale  Nursery  Growers  of  America 


338 


NURSERY  CROP  PRODUCTION 

Nursery  crop  production  is  a  unique  segment  of  agriculture,  but 
it  is  agriculture  nonetheless.   Unlike  fanning  operations  of  many 
of  the  "major"  commodities,  most  nursery  crops  are  not  harvested 
in  the  same  year  in  which  they  are  planted.   Moreover,  although 
they  may  be  planted  at  the  same  time,  not  all  such  nursery  crops 
are  then  harvested  at  the  same  time. 

As  with  other  agricultural  crops,  nursery  stock  is  generally 
planted  in  rows  —  either  in  the  ground  or  in  containers  —  and 
is  cultivated  by  farm  equipment  similarly  used  by  other  farmers. 
Most  nursery  farms  grow  hundreds  of  different  varieties  of  plant 
species  which  often  require  individual  attention,  so  the  labor 
activity  can  be  more  intensive  than  other  agricultural  crops. 

As  an  example  of  the  unique  nature  of  growing  nursery  plants, 
let's  examine  the  production  of  ornamental  evergreen  trees.   Some 
types  of  evergreens  are  first  propagated  from  cuttings  in  a 
greenhouse.   Others  are  propagated  from  seed.   After  several 
months  in  the  greenhouse,  the  rooted  cuttings  (some  of  which  may 
be  sold  to  other  nursery  farms)  are  planted  in  beds,  usually  for 
two  more  years.   These  three-year  old  cuttings  (some  of  which 
again  may  be  sold  to  other  nursery  farms)  are  then  transplanted 
in  fields  or  in  other  containers  and  cultivated  for  as  many  as 
four  or  five  additional  years  until  the  trees  begin  reaching 
various  marketable  sizes.   As  other  examples,  rhododendrens  may 
be  grown  for  four  to  six  years  or  more  before  they  reach 
marketable  sizes,  and  landscape  specimen  shade  trees  may  be  grown 
for  ten  years  or  more. 

Seldom  does  a  nursery  farmer  sell  an  entire  "crop"  in  any  given 
year.   For  example,  evergreens  planted  in  the  field  at  the  saYne 
time  will  not  contain  trees  of  uniform  size.   This  is  due,  in 
part,  to  each  plant's  individual  rate  of  growth,  or  perhaps  to 
variations  in  soil  quality  in  different  parts  of  the  field.   As  a 
result,  when  a  nursery  grower  receives  an  order  from  a  retail 
garden  center  or  a  landscape  firm  for  ornamental  evergreens  of  a 
given  size,  the  order  may  be  filled  out  of  several  fields  of 
trees  of  varying  ages. 

As  with  other  agricultural  commodities,  nursery  crops  are  subject 
to  insects,  pests,  and  diseases.   Unlike  most  other  agricultural 
crops,  nursery  plants  are  often  shipped  with  soil  attached. 
Since  soil  increases  the  likelihood  of  harboring  pests,  a  variety 
of  federal  and  state  certification  and  quarantine  shipping 
requirements  are  imposed  on  nursery  growers  to  prevent  the  spread 
of  such  pests  to  other  agricultural  crops  even  when  such  pests 
are  not  directly  injurious  to  nursery  plants. 


339 


THE  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  SYSTEM  NEEDS  TO  BE  OVERHAULED 

Since  many  nursery  crops  often  take  several  years  in  the  field 
before  they  are  ready  for  harvest,  nursery  farmers  endure  wide 
weather  swings  and  patterns  over  a  multi-year  period.   In  any 
given  year,  nurserymen  may  lose  farmgate  sales  of  tens  of 
millions  of  dollars  in  plant  material  destroyed  by  the  vagaries 
of  nature. 

Nursery  farmers  traditionally  absorb  these  losses  and  treat  them 
as  costs  of  conducting  business.   The  weather  patterns  of  freezes 
and  droughts  are  often  unpredictable.   The  toll  is  obviously 
heavier  and  more  costly  in  some  years  than  in  others.   As  noted 
earlier,  the  nursery  industry  does  not  receive  any  federal 
production  subsidies  or  price  supports,  and  we  desire  as  little 
government  interference  as  possible.   In  turn,  nursery  farmers 
have  historically  not  looked  to  the  federal  government  for  direct 
federal  assistance. 

Given  the  nursery  industry's  strong  and  continuing  aversion  to 
turning  to  the  federal  government  for  direct  financial 
assistance,  there  is,  nonetheless,  an  important  mechanism  by 
which  the  federal  government  can  partner  with  the  nursery 
industry.   It  is  one  in  which  the  nursery  industry,  and  the  rest 
of  agriculture,  could  pay  its  fair  share.   AAN  recommends  that 
the  availability  of  federal  crop  insurance  be  broadened  to  all 
agricultural  crops,  and  that  its  purchase  by  farmers  be  made  more 
economical.   We  are  pleased  that  H.R.4217,  the  "Federal  Crop 
Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994,"  introduced  on  April  14,  1994  by 
House  Agriculture  Committee  Chairman  Kika  de  la  Garza  and  the 
Chairman  of  this  Subcommittee,  Rep.  Tim  Johnson  (D-SD) ,  largely 
embraces  AAN's  position.  ^ 

The  availability  of  federal  crop  insurance  to  the  nursery 
industry  is  severely  limited.   In  part,  this  is  due  to  the  often 
multi-year  production  periods  for  most  nursery  crops,  as  well  as 
the  tremendous  diversity  of  nursery  crops.   Even  in  those  limited 
instances  where  crop  insurance  is  availaUale  to  nursery  farmers, 
the  premiums  are  excessive  and  unaffordetble.   By  iiniversally 
broadening  federal  crop  insurance  to  all  agricultural  crops, 
costs  can  be  pooled  and  risks  can  be  spread  more  effectively. 
Only  when  federal  crop  insurance  is  availeU3le  to  nonprogram 
crops,  such  as  container  and  field-grown  nursery  crops,  will  the 
insurance  system  succeed  in  attracting  a  sufficient  pool  of 
farmers  and  growers  so  that  costs  can  be  spread  more  widely  and 
the  premiums  can  be  more  economical. 

Current  USDA  disaster  assistance  prograuns  can  unintentionally 


340 


reward  marginal  farmers  who,  if  only  they  were  to  change  some  of 
their  management  practices,  could  mitigate  or  even  avert  some  of 
their  crop  losses.   By  the  same  token,  current  USDA  disaster 
prograuns  are  often  off-limits  to  strong  and  innovative  farmers 
who  make  investments  in  their  operations  (such  as  implementing 
irrigation  systems  to  combat  droughts)  in  often  successful 
efforts  to  minimize  crop  losses.   Federal  crop  insurance  premiums 
could  reflect  such  investments  and  management  practices. 

Crop  insurance  for  nonprogram  crops  would  strengthen  the 
financial  position  of  the  insured  in  dealing  with  freezes, 
droughts,  and  other  reasonably  anticipated  and  periodic  weather 
swings  and  patterns.   Crop  insurance  can  act  as  collateral  on 
loans,  and  lowers  the  risk  factor  enabling  lenders  to  offer 
better  terms  or  larger  loans. 

Universally  broadening  the  federal  crop  insurance  system  to  all 
agricultural  crops,  and  making  such  more  economical,  would 
present  potential  budgetary  savings.   It  would  mitigate  the  need 
for  Congress  to  continuously  find  itself  year-in  and  year-out 
having  to  appropriate  huge  sums  of  federal  dollars  to  USDA 
disaster  assistance  progreuns,  which,  unfortunately,  have  often 
been  outright  grants  to  marginal  agricultural  producers. 

AAN  strongly  urges  Congress  to  puruse  the  goal  of  universally 
broadening  the  availability  of  federal  crop  insurance  to  all 
agricultural  producers  for  all  crops,  and  making  the  premiums 
more  economical.   H.R.4217  is  a  positive  first  step  in  this 
direction.   AAN  recommends  that  an  overhauled  federal  crop 
insurance  system  should  cover  reasonably  anticipated  weather 
swings  and  patterns  (such  as  freezes  and  droughts)  which  damage 
or  destroy  agricultural  crops.   In  so  doing,  USDA  disaster 
assistance  programs  could  then  be  revamped  to  help  restore   n 
farmers'  lost  income  due  to  catastrophic  disasters,  such  as 
1992 's  Hurricane  Andrew  or  last  summer's  severe  Midwest  floods, 
for  which  crop  losses  could  not  be  averted  no  matter  what 
precautions  are  implemented  by  farmers. 

H.R.4  217  MUST  BE  AMENDED  TO  EXPLICITLY  COVER  NURSERY  CROPS 

AAN  understands  that  nursery  crops  —  both  container  and 
field-grown  —  are  included  on  the  official  crop  expansion 
feasibility  study  list  for  the  development  of  new  crop  insurance 
programs,   AAN  applauds  this  review  of  container  and  field-grown 
nursery  crops  for  inclusion  as  "eligible  crops."  At  the  same 
time,  though,  we  are  deeply  disturbed  that  section  4  of  H.R.4217 
(which  proposes  a  noninsured  assistance  program  for  crops  for 
which  catastrophic  risk  insurance  is  not  available)  is  limited  to 


341 


food  and  fiber  crop  production.   We  are  concerned  that  if  such 
limiting  language  is  included  in  any  final  legislation,  it  will 
work  against  the  insurance  eligibility  of  nursery  crops. 

Since  nursery  crops  are  neither  food  nor  fiber,  the  proposed 
eligibility  coverage  in  section  4  of  H.R.4217  effectively 
excludes  nursery  farms  or  production  nurseries  —  creating  a 
wholly  inappropriate  and  artificial  wedge  between  the  nursery 
industry  and  the  rest  of  American  agriculture.   H.R.4217  must  be 
amended  to  explicitly  cover  nursery  crops  (and  other  non-food 
or  fiber  crops,  such  as  sod)  as  eligible  for  insurance. 

CONCLUSION 

Mr.  Chairman,  AAN  deeply  appreciates  this  opportunity  to  share 
our  thoughts  about  reforming  the  federal  crop  insurance  program 
in  general,  and  H.R.4217  in  particular.   We  hope  Congress  will 
work  to  overhaul  the  federal  crop  insurance  system  by  universally 
broadening  its  availability  to  all  agricultural  crops,  including 
nursery  plants  and  trees,  and  by  making  the  purchase  of  crop 
insurance  by  farmers  more  economical. 

AAN  also  urges  that  crop  insurance  premiums  reflect  the 
investments  and  management  practices  made  by  strong  and 
innovative  farmers  to  mitigate  their  crop  losses.   By  overhauling 
the  federal  crop  insurance  system,  USDA  disaster  assistance 
programs  could  be  revamped  to  help  restore  farmers'  lost  income 
due  to  truly  catastrophic  disasters,  for  which  crop  losses  could 
not  be  averted  no  matter  what  precautions  are  implemented  by 
farmers. 

As  always,  Mr.  Chairman,  AAN  is  willing  and  ready  to  work  with 
you,  the  Members  of  this  Subcommittee,  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Corporation,  and  USDA  to  make  the  federal  crop  insurance  system 
more  equitable  and  available  to  nursery  farmers.   Thank  you. 


342 


Testimony  of  Teny  N.  Barr 

Chief  Economist 

National  Council  of  Farmer  Cooperatives 

Before  the 

Committee  on  Agriculture 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

Thursday,  April  21,  1994 

Mr.  Chairman,  my  name  is  Wayne  Boutwell.  I  am  testifying  today  on  behalf  of 
the  National  Council  of  Farmer  Cooperatives  (National  Council).  The  National 
Council  is  a  nationwide  association  of  cooperative  businesses  which  are  owned  and 
controlled  by  farmers.  Its  membership  includes  over  100  agricultural  marketing, 
supply  and  credit  cooperatives,  plus  32  state  councils.  National  Council  members 
handle  practically  every  type  of  agricultural  commodity  produced  in  the  U.S., 
market  these  commodities  domestically  and  around  the  world,  and  furnish 
production  supplies  and  credit  to  their  farmer  members  and  patrons.  The  National 
Council  represents  about  90  percent  of  the  nearly  4,500  local  farmer  cooperatives 
in  the  nation,  with  a  combined  membership  of  nearly  2  million  fanners. 

Mr.  Chairman  I  would  like  to  begin  my  testimony  by  commending  you  and  the 
members  of  the  committee  for  holding  these  hearings.  It  seems  that  every  day  the 
farmers  of  this  country  are  being  advised  to  prepare  for  change  from  another 
source.  New  sources  of  change  include  global  competition,  envirorunental  and 
conservation  regulations,  food  safety  regulations,  new  biotechnologies,  and  a 
rapidly  changing  information  technology.  All  of  these  changes  bring  new  risks  in 
addition  to  the  already  present  price  and  production  risk. 

For  decades  farmers  focused  on  enhancing  their  production  skills.  In  the  1970's 
and  1980's  farmers  were  told  to  also  enhance  their  marketing  skills.  The  focus  into 
the  next  century  will  be  managing  risk  from  a  growing  array  of  sources.  The 
subject  of  this  hearing  is  one  of  the  steps  toward  assisting  farmers  to  manage  their 
risk. 

I  am  not  sure  there  is  much  that  can  be  said  about  Federal  Crop  Insurance  that  has 
not  been  said  since  the  Federal  Crop  Insiu-ance  Act  of  1980  was  signed  into  law. 
The  goal  at  that  time  was  to  replace  disaster  assistance  programs  with  an  expanded 
and  improved  crop  insurance  program.  The  program  was  to  run  on  an  actuarially 
sound  basis  and  to  rely,  to  the  maximum  extent  possible,  on  the  private  sector  for 
delivery,  service,  and  claims  adjustment. 


343 


Since  that  time  we  have  had  a  steady  stream  of  studies,  reports.  Commissions  and 
hearings.  The  objective  remains  the  same  and  we  have  14  years  experience  with 
what  will  not  work. 

The  members  of  the  National  Coimcil  of  Farmer  Cooperatives  support  the  repeal 
of  ad  hoc  disaster  assistance  authority  and  the  implementation  of  a  catastrophic 
crop  insurance  coverage  as  a  supplement  to  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  program. 
To  ensure  wider  participation,  crop  insurance  at  the  catastrophic  level  should  be 
linked  to  participation  in  Federal  commodity  support  programs  and  Farmers  Home 
Administration  loans. 

To  be  successful  this  merger  of  disaster  assistance  and  Federal  Crop  Insurance  must 
be  adequately  funded.  Unless  the  funding  issue  is  resolved  it  is  unlikely  that  the 
necessary  merger  could  be  carried  out.  Most  importantly,  do  not  permit  this 
merger  to  proceed  without  an  adequate  level  of  funding.  This  program  evolution 
has  been  underway  for  14  years  and  it  is  important  that  we  not  have  another  failed 
experiment. 

With  respect  to  specific  issues,  I  would  like  to  make  a  few  observations.  First,  it 
is  clear  to  our  membership  that  the  "devil  is  in  the  detail".  The  translation  of  all 
of  the  issues  under  discussion  into  premiimis,  coverage  and  delivery  will  ultimately 
determine  the  success  of  the  program.  I  have  seen  extensive  discussion  on 
modifications  to  the  existing  programs,  but  no  one  has  translated  those 
modifications  into  premiums  across  the  various  commodities  and  regions.  It  would 
be  useful  if  premium  assessments  could  be  prepared  on  alternative  choices. 
Ultimately  the  farmer  will  decide  whether  the  premium  reflects  the  value  of  the 
coverage. 

Secondly,  please  remember  that  the  farmer  is  the  customer  and  if  you  want  a  viable 
program  it  must  serve  the  needs  of  the  farmer.  The  administrators  and  agents  may 
design  a  successful  program  from  their  viewpoint  but  it  is  the  farmer  and  his  risk 
management  needs  that  must  be  served. 

Let  me  make  a  few  closing  comments  on  several  issues: 

a)  Dual  Deliveiy  System  -  The  objective  of  moving  die  program  into  the  private 

sector  at  some  time  in  the  future  must  be  maintained.    From  the  producers 

standpoint  the  more  quality  sources  a  farmer  can  utilize  to  obtain  risk 

management  alternatives  the  better  he  will  be  served.     While  the  Farm 


344 


Services  Agency  may  be  a  source  for  catastrophic  coverage  it  cannot  offer  risk 
management  planning  in  addition  to  all  of  its  other  duties.  Producers  should 
be  encouraged  to  seek  professional  risk  management  advice  when  they  are 
enrolled  in  the  catastrophic  coverage.  However,  no  matter  what  the  source, 
the  minimum  coverage  should  be  available  for  an  affordable  fee  established 
by  the  proposed  reforms.  We  should  be  seeking  to  broaden  the  delivery 
system  not  to  narrow  its  focus  to  existing  distribution  networks. 

With  respect  to  coverage  levels,  FCIC  should  evaluate  providing  additional 
levels  of  coverage  higher  than  the  75  percent  level. 

b)  Provisions  for  Non-insurable  Crops  -  With  the  elimination  of  disaster 
assistance  programs,  a  large  number  of  currently  non-insurable  crops  now 
come  under  Federal  Crop  Insurance  in  the  event  of  a  disaster.  Additionally, 
many  covered  commodities  have  not  been  active  participants  in  the  crop 
insurance  program  in  all  areas  of  the  country.  The  National  Council  would 
encourage  FCIC  to  work  closely  with  those  industries  in  establishing  an 
information  system  upon  which  to  base  any  disaster  assistance. 

c)  Industiy  Competition  -  The  effectiveness  of  crop  insurance  reform  will  be 
greatly  enhanced  by  encouraging  greater  competition  in  rates  and  services  in 
the  private  sector.  The  market  for  risk  management  alternatives  is  expanding 
rapidly  with  greater  use  of  futures,  options  etc.  The  integration  of  crop 
insurance  into  the  array  of  services  will  facilitate  its  emergence  as  a  risk 
management  tool. 

The  members  of  the  National  Council  strongly  support  efforts  to  develop  an 
effective  and  efficient  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Program.  We  look  forward  to 
working  with  the  members  of  the  committee  on  this  important  issue.  Thank  you, 
Mr.  Chairman. 


345 

Dakota  Rural  Action 


Box  S49     •     Brookingj,  South  Dakota  57006     •     603-697-5204 

Testimony,  Dakota  Rural  Action 

Before  tlie  U.S.  House  of  ^Representatives 

Committee  on  Agriculture  Subcommittee  on 

Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 

April  21, 1994 

Dakota  Rural  Action  (DRA)  is  a  grassroots,  membership  based  organization  located  in  South 
Dakota.  We  have  over  500  members  who  have  organized  tpgether  to  achieve  and  create  a 
sustainable  society  which  will  guarantee  freedom  and  justice  for  future  generations.  One  of  our 
long  term  goals  is  to  address  the  man-made  disaster  of  fam^  policy  in  part  by  reforming  federal 
crop  insurance  and  changing  the  federal  disaster  program.  We  would  like  to  make  some 
suggestions  on  the  proposal  to  reform  federal  crop  insurance  which  is  before  this  subcommittee. 

In  the  simplest  terms,  famiJy  farmers  want  a  federal  crop  insurance  program  which  is  simple, 
offers  real  protection  against  disaster  and  is  affordable.  Too  often  the  current  system  offers  little 
of  no  protection  at  a  price  which  makes  it  a  foolish  choice  for  farmers  to  purchase. 

We  understand  that  one  of  the  first  purposes  of  this  pro{)osal  before  you  is  to  reduce  the 
roiC'  s  loss  ratio  from  where  it  is  now  to  1 . 1 .  We  as  tax  payers  would  also  1  ike  to  sec  the  cost  of 
the  program  reduced  but  we  warn  you  that  it  is  necessary  tobuild  a  program  which  offers  a  good 
product  to  the  customers,  the  farmers. 

1.  We  support  the  proposal  plans  to  use  actual  production  history  (APH).  This  will  allow 
producers  to  base  their  coverage  on  the  history  of  their  farm|  and  their  farming  techniques. 
Instead  of  using  yields  which  have  been  locked  in  for  years,  the  yields  will  roll  with  cnanges  in 
farming  techniques  and  with  changes  in  land  ownership. 

However,  we  believe  recording  a  disaster  yield  for  faraners  who  have  experienced  a  natural 
disaster  is  unfair.  We  support  a  system  in  which  a  farmer  irjay  substitute  the  county  average  or  a 
previous  year's  APH  yield  in  place  of  the  disaster  for  a  year, during  which  they  experienced  a 
natural  disaster.  This  will  help  keep  farmers  from  being  peilalized  for  occurrences  which  were 
beyond  their  control.  As  fanners  we  would  love  to  stop  these  acts  of  nature  when  they  occur  and 
never  collect  crop  insurance,  but  we  can't  and  we  shouldn't  be  penalized  by  having  to  include 
disaster  years  in  our  production  history. 

This  change  will  also  help  insure  that  people  participate  p  the  new  federal  crop  insurance 
program.  The  plan  to  increase  farmer  participation  by  linking  federal  crop  insurance  to  the  farm 
program  participation  may  fall  short  of  expectations  because  many  farmers  are  talking  about 
dropping  out  of  the  farm  program  due  to  new  restrictions  on'program  paiticipants  and  reductions 
in  benefits  from  the  farm  program.  The  new  federal  crop  insurance  has  to  be  a  quality  product 
which  will  sell  on  its  own  merits. 

2.  iMore  than  four  levels  of  crop  insurance  should  be  offered  to  insure  that  producers  have  the 
maximum  amount  of  flexibility.  Some  farmers  will  be  willing  to  pay  more  for  a  higher  level  of 
coverage.  A  100  percent  coverage  level  should  be  offered  for  those  farmers  who  would  like  this 
kind  of  protection.    This  could  be,  an  option  for  farmers  having  trouble  finding  financing  for 
spring  planting.  With  100  percent  insurance,  a  farmer  could  walJc  into  the  bank  with  his  policy 
aad  use  it  as  collateral  for  an  operating  loan.  At  100  percent  coverage,  federal  crop  insurance 
would  work  like  hail  insurance.  Hail  insurance  allows  a  farmer  to  buy  a  dollar  amount  of 


346 


coverage  paying  for  it  ac  a  set  premium  level.  For  example  a  faimcr  may  buy  $100  an  acre         ' 
coverage  for  $8  an  acre  or  $150  an  acre  coverage  for  $12  an  acre.  The  benefits  and  costs  are 
clear,  easily  understood  and  dependable.  Payments  aie  bas<:d  on  percentage  of  loss.  If  a  farmer 
covered  for  $100  an  acre  receive  a  50  percent  loss,  the  insurance  will  pay  $50. 

3.  Another  benefit  of  hail  insurance  is  its  simplicity.  Federal  crop  insurance  should  be  simple  so 
the  customers  know  what  they  are  buying.  We  need  to  get  rid  of  confusing  percentages  ancf 
useless  quirks  in  the  program.  For  example,  the  "T  yield"  is  a  term  with  only  one  pui^posc,  to 
make  the  program  confusing.  Instead  of  taking  percentages  of  yields  and  giving  it  a  new  name. 
Find  one  of  the  many  yields  already  being  figured  by  fanners  and  government  agencies  and  use 
it.  Farmers  have  a  lot  of  work  to  do  and  the  time  spent  trying  to  figure  out  how  much  they  are 
covered  and  when  they  are  covered,  could  be  used  more  productively.  In  fact  many  famiers 
don't  have  an  exact  ideaiabout  vvliat  their  crop  insurance  coverage  is  until  they  have  a  loss. 

4.  The  $50  per  crop  processing  fee  for  the  catastrophic  level  of  crop  insurance  is  simply  a 
subsidy  for  large  farmers.- A  farmer  with  1,000  acres  of  wheat  would  pay  5  cents  an  acre  while  a 
faimer  with  100  acres  of  wheat  would  be  paying  50  cents  ah  acre  for  the  same  coverage.  This 
should  be  changed  so  everyone  pays  a  per  acre  fee  for  the  coverage.  Even  though  this  fee  is 
proposed  to  be  something  other  than  a  premium  it  still  acts  like  an  insurance  premium  and  tlic 
small  producer  ends  up  on  the  short  side. 

5.  Tile  payment  level  for  prevented  planting  should  be  raised  to  65  percent  instead  of  50  percent. 
Last  year,  a  lot  of  faiiners  got  everything  into  the  ground  accept  the  seed.  This  includes 
expensive  items  like  fertilizer,  herbicide  and  in  some  cases  insecticide.  Under  the  proposed  plan 
all  these  farmers  would  have  qualified  for  is  the  low  coverage  level  of  prevented  planting.  This 
low  coverage  will  not  prevent  farmers  from  going  to  great  Extremes  like  flying  on  their  seed  to 
qualify  for  their  higher  level  of  insurance  and  recapture  the'costs  of  the  inputs. 

Disaster  Reserve  Proposal 

DRA  and  the  National  Family  Farm  Coalition  (NFFC)  !would  like  to  propose  an  expansion 
of  the  Farmer  Owned  Reserve  and  make  it  a  true  disaster  reserve  program  where  farmers  raise 
grain  on  land  tliat  would  have  been  set-a-side  or  take  a  percentage  of  their  production  for  storage 
until  a  disaster  year.  We  would  like  the  program  to  include  a  storage  payment  at  the  cunent 
fanner  storage  rate  which  will  help  farmers  put  up  the  additional  storage  they  need  for  the 
reserve.    The  farmer  would  have  to  document  the  loss  and  fiave  it  verified  by  ASCS.  The  grain 
would  only  be  released  from  storage  on  a  documented  loss  by  a  single  producer  or  in  the  case  of 
a  county-wide  disaster.  They  then  would  be  able  to  substitute  this  grain  for  lost  crops. 

ii   ! 

We  propose  that  this  "self-insurance"  program  be  offered  in  place  of  part  of  the 
administi'ation's  crop  insurance  reform  program.  We  would  propose  that  the  disaster  reserve  be 
put  in  place  at  the  65-70  percent  production  level.  Tlie  farmer  could  still  purchase  insurance  to  cover 
their  initial  losses  before  the  65  percent  levei. 

The  disaster  resei^fe  could  help  both  diversified  farmers  with  livestock  as  well  as  those 
witliout.    Livestock  fanners  would  have  enough  grain  in  their  bins  to  feed  their  livestock  and 
wouldn't  need  a  disaster  payment.  They  could  have  fed  their  animals  with  high  quality  grains, 
keeping  the  rate  of  gain  high  and  marketing  them  on  time.  (Quality  feed  in  a  disaster  year  is 
worth  more  than  a  disaster  payment  which  can  only  buy  popr  feed. 

Grain  fanners  will  receive  the  benefit  of  having  quality  grain  to  market  in  a  disaster  year. 
The  local  economy  would  also  benefit  because  this  grain  wpuld  be  sold  locally  the  same  as  it 
would  in  a  good  year.  Elevators  and  main  street  businesses  will  all  benefit.  With  today's 
programs,  fanners  get  a  check  from  one  government  agency  and  sign  it  over  to  pay  debts  held  by 
another  government  agency. 

We  appreciate  this  opportunity  to  present  written  testimony  on  these  issues. 


347 


fl6Pfl 


AMERICAN  SOD  PRODUCERS  ASSOCIATION 

An  International  Organization  Deaicatea  to  Advancement  of  tne  Turfgrass  Sod  industry 


«^p»» 


OFFICERS  1993-M 

POESiOENT  ftcrwdScNMM 
Gieannofiion  Group  inc 
'400  hUuieOiloo  Road 
CimOfiOQe  Omano  hOH  4H6 
P»»one,5'9j6S3  749* 

w   PRESIDENT  I.Ou>»L   BnxJking  J' 

B'oohmeaoe  Sod  Farm  Ire 

RR  t   8c>  S47 

Do5»eil  Vfginia  23047  97Sl 

psorw   eW,  883  6338 

FAX  ,804.  883-6377 

SEC  Y  TREAS  J  Dougus  Baitwrrv 
^A-r^  SoO  Fjm«  irtc 
PO  Bo>2i8 

Crturcnviae  Maryland  21028 
Phooe  ,4101 879^*277 
FAX   410(836  2932 

PASTPRES  M.i<eMoin%« 
Waffen  s  Turt  Nurses  i«C- 
'502  S  Ma.n  Si'eei 
CfysiaiU»ie  lUmo^  6001*8045 
PrxJoeiS'Sl  455  5100 
FAX   8!6,  455  7894 

80AH0  OF  TPUSnES 

3e"  I  Coceia-ia 

Pir.en  Seeo  Co  Soper  Sod 

PO  3o. :■- 

La«e--ary)  3eor9ia  3^635 

P-oofl  ,512   482  3'3' 

"av<]  Ooccet 

Cfensnaw  4  OoQuei  Turtgtass   i 

6C9  C.»&"f  Roge 

Aushn    7^.35  78746 

P'xsne  Si:i  328  0884 

'.vay'*  "'■cso« 
'ceo  Vaie*  Famis  "x 
=   M^f-i»ay52 
V«3a  N«O'asM6S04i 
="one  ,4C2 1  624-6385 


Lrca  ■ 


cuet 


Scoco  i-y; 

t"©  So>2 

Stocum  s^ooe  island  02877 

^-^neJCi    294-31C0 

Frank  H    iV-.mot 
SurvTOl  H3'l  Tufi  Far^ 
C:3C<JR-/e'Rdad 
Pk!*swj*  ^.^aryta-'w  20837 
P^crs,3C-i548  29C0 

Srya^  Wood 

T  0  'CO  7^f  L"0 

Co"f  P«ti,-'e  Farm 

Mu'or   i<i?<'-es  England 

•.1K1-C8U 

^•■S'^  ,09C8l  270701 

Cena  B:ueq>ass  Co 

PC  9ox307 

5roc«Ton  Ci-iom»a  9520 '0307 

P-C-e  2C9  464  8355 

EXECUTIVE  DIRECTOR 

C'CjQfJS  M   ^^nOef  CAE 

•  ^55  Amos  Road 

Cc^iirq  iA>accws   '.i.no>s  60008 

e-one."''9>  "C5  9698 

LEGAL  COUNSEL 

'.<cGi>-neis  i  WUiams 

•^^5  ■5*?' SvMi   NW    Sua*  1200 

iVay^g-o-  D  C  200C5 

P-^-«.2;2    799-8600 


STATEMENT  OF  AMERICAN  SOD  PRODUCERS  ASSOCUTION 

TO  THE  HOUSE  SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT, 

CREDIT  AND  RURAL  DEVELOPMENT 

Regarding  H.R.  4217  -  Proposal  to  Reform  Crop  Insurance 

Presented  by  Douglas  H.  Fender 

Ejtecutive  Director 

American  Sod  Producers  Association 


April  21,  1994 


Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  the  Subcommittee,  my  name  is 
Douglas  H.  Fender  and  I  am  the  Executive  Director  of  the  American  Sod 
Producers  Association.    We  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  submit  a  statement 
regarding  the  availability  of  crop  insurance  for  specialty  crops  like  turfgrass 
sod. 

The  American  Sod  Producers  Association  (ASPA)  is  a  26-year  old,  not- 
for-profit  association  with  members  in  49  states  in  the  United  States,  Canada 
and  25  other  countries.    ASPA  consists  of  over  600  turfgrass  sod  farm 
operations  that  produce  approximately  80  percent  of  the  acreage  sold  each  year 
in  the  U.S.    ASPA  represents  its  members  on  federal  issues  of  importance. 
Crop  insurance  and  disaster  relief  assistance  are  significant  concerns  to 
ASPA's  membership. 

We  want  to  preface  our  statement  by  commending  the  Administration 
and  the  Subcommittee  for  their  efforts  to  provide  fanners  with  a  rational 
policy  on  the  availability  of  federal  crop  insurance.    Moving  away  from 
reliance  on  federal  disaster  relief  measures  and  toward  crop  insurance  makes 
fiscal  as  well  as  practical  sense.    However,  Congress  should  recognize  that  an 
effective  and  equitable  crop  insurance  program  must,  at  a  minimum,  provide 
protection  for  the  same  agricultural  commodities  as  presently  are  entided  to 
disaster  relief  assistance.    Turfgrass  sod  is  currently  entitled  to  disaster  relief 
assistance  under  the  terms  of  the  1990  Farm  Bill.    Prior  to  the  Farm  Bill, 
however,  turfgrass  sod  was  excluded  because  of  definitional  ambiguities  in 
USDA  assistance  programs. 


1855-A  Hicks  Road 


Rolling  Meadows,  IL  60008 


708/705-9898     (Fax  708/705-8347) 


81-128  0-94-12 


348 


Legislation  to  expand  crop  insurance  as  an  alternative  to  ad  hoc  disaster  relief 
legislation  should  ensure  that  turfgrass  sod  is  included  as  an  eligible  crop.    We  are  concerned 
that  the  language  of  H.R.  4217  creates  some  doubt  regarding  the  eligibility  of  turfgrass  sod 
and  other  specialty  crops.    As  discussed  below,  definitional  ambiguity  in  other  USDA 
programs  has  resulted  in  confusion  and,   in  some  cas^  the  exclusion  of  producers  of 
turfgrass  sod  from  benefits  to  which  they  should  be  enntled  as  an  agricultural  commodity. 

Turfgrass  sod  farmers,  like  those  producing  nursery  and  other  specialty  crops,  often 
face  challenges  that  other  more  traditional  types  of  agricultural  commodities  do  not. 
Although  turfgrass  sod  is  considered  an  agricultural  commodity  under  many  federal  and  state 
laws,'  it  is  sometimes  inappropriately  excluded  from  federal  benefits  afforded  other 
agricultural  commodities.   This  is  often  a  result  of  oversight  or  lack  of  knowledge  about  its 
production  and  harvest  characteristics.^ 

Several  statutes  define  the  term  agriculture  to  be  "food  or  fiber.'   Because  turfgrass 
sod  typically  is  not  considered  a  traditional  "food  or  fiber"  agricultural  commodity,  it  is 
important  for  the  Subcommittee  to  understand  that  turfgrass  production  is  nevertheless  a 
traditional  agricultural  activity.    It  is  produced,  cultivated  and  harvested  in  much  the  same 
manner  as  other  more  familiar  agricultural  commodities.    As  a  consequence,  ASPA  believes 
that  turfgrass  sod  farmers  should  have  the  same  degree  of  access  to  crop  insurance  that  other 
agricultural  producers  are  entitied  to  obtain. 

ASPA's  members'  experience  with  disaster  assistance  in  the  past  illustrates  the 
problems  encountered  in  our  industry  and  which  will  continue  unless  the  proposed  federal 
crop  insurance  program  includes  within  the  definition  of  eligible  crops  specialty  crops  like 
turfgrass  sod. 

For  example,  prior  to  the  1990  Farm  Bill,  turfgrass  sod's  exclusion  from  disaster 
assistance  resulted  in  part  because  it  was  not  considered  "food  or  fiber."    USDA  officials  in 
charge  of  administering  disaster  relief  assistance  felt  constrained  to  limit  relief  to  crops 
falling  within  that  narrow  definition. 


'   The  Departments  of  Agriculture,  Labor,  Treasury,  and  Commerce,  as  well  as  the 
Environmental  Protection  Agency,  all  have  laws  and  regulations  that  define  and  treat 
turfgrass  sod  as  an  agricultural  commodity. 

'  For  example,  under  the  Swampbuster  program,  producers  of  annual  program  crops 
lose  payments  from  USDA  for  wetlands  converted  into  cropland  after  1985.    In  defining 
what  is  prior  converted  cropland  for  the  broader  purposes  of  the  Clean  Water  Act,  the  Army 
Corps  of  Engineers  borrowed  the  Swampbuster  definition  of  "agriculture"  which  is  limited  to 
annual  crops  governed  by  the  Swampbuster  program.    As  a  perennial  crop,  turfgrass  sod, 
along  with  all  other  perennials,  was  arbitrarily  denied  prior  converted  cropland  status  under 
the  Corps  of  Engineers  definition. 


349 


Section  2244  of  P.L.  101-624  (1990  Farm  Bill)  resolved  the  definitional  problem  in 
the  context  of  disaster  relief.    It  included  turfgrass  sod  among  the  "non-food  or  fiber"  crops 
determined  to  be  eligible  for  disaster  assistance.    The  1993  disaster  relief  provisions 
necessitated  by  the  floods  in  the  midwest  last  year  also  adopted  this  definition. 

As  the  subcommittee  moves  forward  with  legislation  to  reform  disaster  assistance  and 
require  the  purchase  of  crop  insurance,  we  request  that  it  include  turfgrass  sod,  nurseries  and 
other  specialty  crops  within  the  provisions  defining  eligible  agricultural  crops.    We  ask  that 
turfgrass  sod  farms  be  allowed  to  participate  in  crop  insurance  in  the  same  fashion  as  other 
agricultural  crops  and  that  USDA  be  given  the  necessary  guidance  to  achieve  that  end. 

We  are  somewhat  concerned,  however,  by  the  crop  eligibility  provisions  of  H.R. 
4217.    Section  520  of  the  bill  would  condition  eligibility  for  catastrophic  risk  protection 
coverage  on  the  definition  of  a  "person"  as  determined  by  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture. 
Since  eligibility  will  be  determined  by  regulations  issued  by  USDA,  it  is  critical  the 
legislation  clarify,  like  the  1990  farm,  bill  that  "non-food  and  fiber"  crops  are  "persons"  for 
purposes  of  program  eligibility. 

In  addition.  Section  522(a)(1)  of  H.R.  4217  authorizes  the  establishment  of  a  non- 
insured  assistance  program.    Coverage  would  be  extended  to  all  "commercial  crops  and 
commodities  for  which  catastrophic  risk  protection  coverage  is  not  available  and  that  are 
produced  for  food  and  fiber."   Use  of  the  term  "food  and  fiber"  poses  a  problem.    As 
previously  discussed,  turfgrass  sod  does  not  meet  the  traditional  definition  of  "food  or  fiber." 
To  avoid  the  problems  caused  in  crop  disaster  programs  preceding  the  1990  Farm  Bill,  we 
strongly  suggest  that  the  definitional  section  of  H.R.  4217  be  amended  to  include  turfgrass 
sod  and  other  specialty  crops  within  the  category  of  eligible  crops. 

Notwithstanding  the  fact  that  the  1990  farm  bill  includes  "non-food  or  fiber"  crops 
within  the  definition  of  eligible  crops,  we  raised  these  concerns  with  officials  of  FCIC.    We 
have  been  assured  by  officials  of  FCIC  that  turfgrass  sod  will  be  considered  eligible  for  crop 
insurance.    While  ASPA  receives  some  comfort  from  such  representations,  it  is  preferable 
that  the  legislation  clearly  evidence  such  an  intent.   We  respectfully  request  the 
Subcommittee's  assistance  to  clarify  the  definition  of  eligible  "persons"  and  the  term  "food 
and  fiber."   Even  though  FCIC  presently  considers  turfgrass  sod  to  be  eligible  for  crop 
insurance,  we  believe  more  explicit  definitions  would  reduce  eligibility  problems  in 
application  of  the  program. 

We  look  forward  to  working  with  the  Subcommittee  as  it  develops  legislation  to 
reform  federal  crop  insurance.    We  respectfully  request  the  Subcommittee's  help  to  eliminate 
any  definitional  ambiguity  in  the  proposed  legislation  that  might  exclude  turfgrass  sod 
farmers  from  access  to  crop  insurance.    We  will  be  glad  to  provide  any  additional 
information  regarding  this  issue.    Thank  you  for  the  opportunity  to  present  our  views. 


350 


/-^  National  >*i 

Sunflower 


I  National^*!  4023  sutc  street 

Bismarck.  ND  58501  (KiWI  USA 

Phone  7ai-221-S10l 

ASSOCIATION  FAX.  701  221-3101 


The  Nationai  Sunflower  Association  (NSA)  appreciates  the 
opportunity  to  express  its  views  regarding  the  current  Federal  crop 
insurance  program  and  the  Administration's  reform  proposal. 

Traditionally,  Bunf lower  growers  have  par-ticipated  in  the  crop 
insurance  program  and  would  like  to  rely  on  a  program  more  as  a 
risk  management  tool .  There  are  several  changes  in  the  current 
system  that  would  improve  its  usefulness  to  sunflower  growers: 

1)  Coverage  for  Solid  seed  Plant inq-Currentlv.  sunflower  producers 
wishing  to  solid  seed  (narrow  row  spacing)  sunflowers  are  not 
eligible  for  Federal  crop  insurance  coverage.  NSA  encourages  FCTC 
to  change  this  outdated  policy  as  a  growing  number  of  producers 
favor  narrow  row  spacing.  Solid  seed  planting  is  easier,  quicker, 
and  cheaper  than  conventional  row  spacing.  Generally,  less 
chemicals  and  labor  are  required,  and  new  modern  drills  are  very 
adaptable  to  this  type  of  seeding.  Narrow  row  spacing  is 
consistent  with  Soil  Conservation  Service  (SCS)  requirements  for 
cover  and  residue.  In  the  event  of  a  weed  problem,  two  post- 
emergent  chemicals  are  now  available  to  producers  which  control 
most  broad  leaf  and  grassy  weeds.  NSA  believes  that  producers 
using  the  most  environmentally  sound  and  economically  viable 
farming  practices  available  should  be  eligible  for  Federal  crop 
insurance . 

2)  Prevented  and  Late  Planting  Coverage-Prevented  and  late 
planting  are  currently  not  covered  under  the  standard  policy  for 
sunflowers.  Due  to  extreme  weather  conditions  in  the  sunflower 
production  regions,  prevented  and  late  planting  coverage  is  very 
much  needed  and  would  improve  the  usefulness  of  the  program. 

3 )  Premium  Price  Selection  for  Confectionery  Sunf lowers-The 
National  Sunflower  Association  believes  there  should  be  premium 
price  selection  for  confectionery  sunflowers.  The  cost  of 
production  is  higher  for  confectionery  seed,  yet  the  crop  insurance 
price  selection  is  the  same  as  for  oil-type  sunflowers.  NSA  hopes 
an  appropriate  price  distinction  between  the  two  types  of 
sunflowers  seed  can  be  made. 

4)  New  Regions  for  Coverage-Planting  of  sunflowers  is  expanding 
Kansas,  Colorado,  and  Nebraska.  A  number  of  counties  in  these 
states  are  already  eligible  for  crop  insurance.  However,  as  the 
crop  moves  into  new  areas,  we  strongly  suggest  a  reasonable 
mechanism  be  put  in  place  to  allow  additional  counties  to  become 
eligible  for  Federal  crop  insurance.  The  current  system  is 
inconsistent  and  serves  to  discourage  the  natural  spread  of 
production . 


351 


5)  Program  Consistency-Program  policies  are  not  always  consistent 
from  one  state  to  another.  For  example,  confection  sunflowers 
planted  in  Colorado  must  be  planted  after  fallow  to  be 
eligible  for  crop  insurance.  This  requirement  no  longer  applies  in 
Kansas  and  Nebraska,  and  is  contrary  to  SCS  recommendations  to 
abandon  fallow.  Also,  this  policy  is  discriminatory  against 
Colorado  confectionery  sunflowers  producers. 

With  regard  to  the  Administration's  reform  proposal,  sunflower 
growers  generally  are  supportive  of  the  basic  policy  and  direction. 
We  realize  the  need  to  move  away  from  dependency  on  Federal  ad  hoc 
disaster  programs,  and  hope  the  catastrophic  coverage  plan  will  be 
approved  by  Congress.  There  are  several  of  measures  included  in 
the  proposal  we  would  like  to  address: 

1)  Coverage  Levels -Cove rage  levels  up  to  85%  should  be  available. 
This  level  of  coverage  would  truly  provide  insurance  for  good 
farmers  who  suffer  a  bad  crop  year  but  do  not  qualify  for  the  lower 
levels  of  coverage. 

2)  Prevented  and  Late  Plantings  Coverage-As  indicated  in  our 
comments  on  the  current  program,  prevented  and  late  planting  should 
be  available  for  all  crops,  including  sunflowers. 

3)  Linkage  to  Farm  Prooraas-NSA  does  not  have  a  problem  with 
linking  crop  insurance  to  Federal  farm  programs.  However,  we  would 
like  to  see  a  cap  set  on  the  administrative  fee  charged  for 
catastrophic  coverage.  We  agree  a  $50  fee  per  crop  is  reasonable. 
However,  any  significant  increase  in  the  amount  used  for  budget 
offsets  or  to  raise  revenue  would  discourage  participation. 

4)  Group  Risk  Plan-Thc  National  sunflower  Association  would  prefer 
using  actual  production  records  rather  than  the  Group  Risk  Plan, 
sunflowers  are  traditionally  grown  in  states  with  large  counties 
which  have  diverse  soils  and  weather  conditions.  The  Group  Risk 
Plan  is  unfair  to  producers  who  suffer  disaster  conditions  in  one 
portion  of  the  county  when  the  entire  county  does  not  incur  the 
same  problems.  Under  this  plan,  producers  with  the  disaster-level 
losses  would  not  qualify  for  assistance. 

Again,  the  National  Sunflower  Association  appreciates  the 
opportunity  to  express  the  views  and  interests  of  our  producer 
members  regarding  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program.  We  look 
forward  to  working  with  the  Subcommittee  as  consideration  of  the 
reform  proposal  continues. 


352 


TESTIMONY  SUBMITTED  BY  RANDOLPH  NODLAND 
DAKOTA  RESOURCE  COUNCIL  -  NORTH  DAKOTA 
TO  THE  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT  AND  RURAL  DEVELOMENT  SUBCOMMITTEE  OF 
THE  HOUSE  AGRICULTURE  COMMITTEE 
April  21,  1994 

We  are  in  support  of  overhauling  the  disaster  crop  insurance 
system.  While  the  disaster  assistance  program  has  helped  many 
farmers  through  troubled  times  when  they  have  lost  their  crops 
the  crop  insurance  progreim  has  not  at  all  kept  pace  with  actual 
yield  losses. 

One  of  the  other  problems  is  that  we  have  had  a  general  failure 
in  farm  policy  in  this  country.  The  policy  of  keeping  grain 
prices  low  has  placed  many  farmers  in  a  position  of  consistently 
being  on  the  edge  so  that  when  a  bad  year  comes  along  there  is  an 
immediate  need  for  disaster  assistance.  Grain  producers  are 
receiving  no  more  for  their  crops  than  they  received  3  or  4  years 
ago,  yet  productivity  costs  have  tripled  or  quadrupled  in  that 
time.  It  now  takes  15-20,000  bushels  of  wheat  to  purchase  a 
medium  size  tractor  that  could  be  bought  for  5  thousand  bushels 
of  wheat  30  years  ago. 

We  do  believe  that  there  is  a  continued  need  for  federal  disaster 
assistance.  We  support  a  program  where  farmers  can  help  provide 
their  own  insurance  through  a  bushel-based  disaster  reserve  for 
losses  not  covered  by  the  catastrophic 'disaster  assistance. 

The  disaster  reserve  would  work  somewhat  like  the  fanner  owned 
reserve,  except  it  would  not  be  eligible  for  CCC  loans  or 
marketing  until  the  farmer  had  yield  losses  below  the  normal 
yield.  The  farmer  would  then  apply  to  the  ASCS  for  release  of 
enough  bushels  to  cover  their  losses. 

The  grain  for  this  disaster  reserve  has  to  come  from  somewhere. 
Given  the  current  state  of  farm  production  costs  and  the  farm 
economy,  it  is  unrealistic  to  assume  that  farmers  would  "donate" 
to  the  reserve  from  their  normal  production  base.   We  support  a 
bushel  based  program  or  acreage  set-aside  program  to  have  some 
mechanism  of  establish  a  level  of  production  that  meets  real 
needs.   Allowing  full  production  for  the  sake  of  exporting  a  lot 
of  grain  at  below  cost  of  production.   It  only  ensures  that  many 
farmers  continue  to  remain  below  the  poverty  line. 


A 


r 


353 


We  support  a  program  where  the  fanner  would  be  allowed  to  grow 
crops  for  the  disaster  reserve  on  what  would  have  been  set-aside 
acres  or  to  develop  a  percentage  of  overall  production  that  could 
be  produced  on  other  acreage.   This  grain  would  be  isolated  from 
the  market.  It  should  not  be  used  as  a  club  to  drive  down  grain 
prices.  When  a  producer  has  built  up  the  reserve  to  reasonable 
level,  for  instance,  enough  for  a   total  year's  loss  or  at  least 
enough  to  cover  losses  not  covered  by  disaster  assistance.  The 
set-aside  should  revert  back  to  a  conservancy  use  to  be  kept  in 
reserve  for  future  use . 

A  progreun  like  this  would  help  create  a  stable  supply.  When  a 
major  disaster  strikes  U.S.  farmers,  such  as  the  1988  drought,  or 
the  floods  of  1993,  the  grain  in  the  disaster  reserve  would 
ensure  that  consumers  would  not  be  hit  with  shortages  and  farmers 
would  have  grain  to  sell. 

At  the  very  least  the  disaster  reserve  program  should  be  offered 
as  an  option  to  crop  insurance  to  farmers.   The  grain  in  the 
disaster  reserve  should  be  eligible  for  rollover  each  year  to 
insure  it  remains  in  good  condition.  Storage  payments  should  be 
paid  on  the  grain  and  a  cost-share  to  cover  the  costs  of  building 
storage  facilities. 

We  urge  that  you  include  the  disaster  reserve  concept  as  part  of 
the  Federal  Disaster  and  Crop  Insurance  program. 


354 


TEXAS  WHEAT 

PlOOUCItS      ASSOCIATION 
803    FifstBank  Southwest 
2201  Civic  Circle 
AMARILLO.  TEXAS  7910908S3 


Telephone  18061  357  2191 

March  28,  1993 


The  Honorable  Larry  Combest 
Member  of  Congress 
Field  Information  Session 
Lubbock  TX 


Dear  Congressman  Combest: 

On  behalf  of  the  members'  of  the  Texas  Wheat  Producers  Association  (TWPA)  I  would  like 
to  thank  you  for  your  leadership  on  crop  insurance  reform.   1  have  had  an  opportunity 
to  discuss  the  crop  insurance  reform  proposal  within  our  organization  as  well  as  with 
board  members  of  the  National  Association  of  Wheat  Growers.   The  following  is  a 
condensed  version  of  the  concerns,  comments  and  questions  that  were  expressed. 

First,  TWPA  is  unwilling  to  step  away  from  standing  disaster  authority.   We  recognize 
that  while  some  firewalls  against  future  disaster  bills  may  be  needed  to  fund  reform, 
but  the  best  way  to  prevent  the  need  for  future  disaster  legislation  remains  an  adequ- 
ate, workable,  affordable  crop  insurance  program. 

The  change  to  the  new,  more  aggressive  APH  formula  has  not  been  without  pain.   Whether 
a  reform  package  moves  through  Congress  or  not,  the  highest  priority  for  FCIC  should 
be  to  develop  and  implement  a  catastrophic  yield  clause  to  put  the  brakes  on  yield 
declines  for  producers  with  multiple  catastrophic  losses.   At  the  same  time,  the  decision 
to  base  catastrophic  yield  coverage  from  individual  APH  yields  as  opposed  to  county  aver- 
age yields  Is  a  vital  and  important  component  of  the  current  reform  package. 

Another  issue  which  must  be  addressed  whether  or  not  there  is  a  reform  package  is  the 
need  for  a  de  minimus  yield  clause.   The  lack  of  a  de  minimus  yield  clause  for  small 
grains  continually  makes  a  mockery  of  MPCI  coverage  when  farmers  with  100%  losses  have 
their  payment  reduced  by  2  or  3  bushels  an  acre  because  an  adjuster  has  appraised  the 
yield  at  that  level.   This  inequity  is  further  exacerbated  by  ASCS  having  a  de  minimus 
policy  while  crop  insurance  continues  to  lack  such  a  clause. 

TWPA  understands  the  desire  and  pressure  for  FCIC  to  expand  coverage  to  new  crops.   How- 
ever, we  don't  want  to  see  limited  resources  spread  too  thin  while  the  program  is  still 
inadequate  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  seven  commodities  that  comprise  75%  of  the  existing 
crop  insurance  business  and  most  of  the  potential  business.   One  of  the  first  issues  FCIC 
should  explore  whould  be  to  develop  a  seed  wheat  policy  for  producers  raising  high-value 
seed  wheat.   These  producers  tend  to  be  very  low  risk  with  adequate  production  records 
however,  they  may  not  utilize  crop  insurance  due  to  inadequate  price  protection  compared 
to  the  higher  value  of  their  crop. 

The  1995  FCIC  Small  Grains  Policy,  Federal  Register,  Sec.  6  provides  ...  for  early  term- 
ination of  acreage  to  be  grazed,  or  destroyed  by  other  means.   If  such  acreage  is 
damaged  to  the  extent  a  loss  is  payable,  a  claim  can  be  filed  and  paid  before  destruction 


355 


The    Honorable    Larry    Corabest 


Page  :uo 


for  ASCS.   Full  preminum  will  be  due  on  this  acreage.   If  no  claim  is  payable  on  such 
acreage,  the  premium  will  be  reduced  and  the  acreage  can  be  disposed  of,  by  any  means, 
and  reduced  at  ASCS.   It  is  important  to  Texas  wheat  producers  that  the  above  provisions 
remain  in  any  future  revision  and  final  language  for  FCIC  provisions. 

Thank  you  for  advancing  the  reform  proposal,  many  of  the  items  in  this  letter  arc 
long-standing  concerns  that  can  be  addressed  independently  of  crop  insurance  reform. 
TWPA  looks  forward  to  working  with  you  on  the  reform  package.   Additional  questions  are 
being  submitted  for  your  attention  and  review  by  FCIC. 


Sincerily  yours 


Rodney  Ho^er 
Executive  Assistant 


356 


tron.:   •ii:.XAS  WUhAl  FKUUUChKS  Ab^UCiAXio:^; 


FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  CORPORATION 
REFORM  QUESTIONS 

1.  The  reform  proposal  book  contains  examples  of  disaster  and  crop  insurance 
comparisons  for  corn,  cotton  and  soybeans.   Will  FCIC  run  the  same  comparisons 
for  wheat? 

2.  Can  existing  policy  holders  get  catastrophic  coverage  based  upon  their  crop 
insurance  units  as  opptosed  to  whole  farm  coverage? 

3.  How  will  the  catastrophic  program  work  with  companion  hail?   Will  it  combine 
with  hail  insurance  for' those  farmers  that  don't  need  or  desire  MPCI? 

4.  Will  wheat  not  enrolled  in  the  farm  program  be  eligible  for  the  catastrophic 

gram? 

5.  How  will  the  $50  fee  be  applied  in  the  case  of  crop  share  or  similar  agreements? 
Could  the  fee  Instead  apply  to  ASCS  farm  number  or  units? 

6.  Has  FCIC  considered  expanding  the  principles  of  non-standard  classif iciation  to 
agents,  adjusters  and  companies? 

7.  Few  farmers  in  the  traditional  wheat  belt  are  interested  in  the  GRP  program 
and  would  object  fo  further  expansion  of  the  program.   However,  would  FCIC  consider 
offering  GRP  to  wheat  producers  in  those  counties  where  GRP  is  offered  for  soybeans 
that  are  double  cropped  with  wheat? 

8.  The  experience  this  fall  with  the  wheat  price  election  served  to  illustrate  the 
folly  of  tieing  the  market  price  election  to  the  world  agriculture  outlook  board. 
Can  the  price  election  process  be  modified  to  take  into  consideration  the  market- 
ability of  the  insurance  product? 

9.  As  a  marketing  tool,  can  a  good  experience  discount  be  developed  to  provide  a 
discount  to  existing  insureds  while  minimizing  snail  claims? 


357 


NACI/\ 


NATIONAL'ASSOCIATION'OF-CROP'INSURANCE'AGENTS 
April    20,     1994 

The  Honorable  Tim  Johnson 

Chairman 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit 

and  Rural  Development,  Committee  on  Agriculture 

House  of  Representatives 

1301  Longworth  House  Office  Building 

Washington,  D.C.  20515 

Dear  Congressman  Johnson: 

On  behalf  of  the  National  Association  of  Crop  Insurance 
Agents  ("NACIA") ,  I  regret  I  was  unable  to  accept  your  invitation 
to  testify  before  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and 
Rural  Development  on  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of 
1994.   I  am  pleased  to  enclose  for  the  record,  however,  copies  of 
a  prepared  statement  as  well  as  an  analysis  of  the  Reform  Act 
prepared  by  our  counsel. 

When  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  first  heralded 
its  Reform  Act,  but  before  its  provisions  were  public,  NACIA 
believed  it  would  be  able  to  put  aside  certain  reservations  and 
support  the  Act's  provisions.   Indeed,  I  was  privileged  to  stand 
with  Secretary  Espy  when  he  introduced  the  Act  to  the  public. 
Regrettably,  however,  the  Act's  provisions  and  the  Act's 
omissions  require  us  to  take  a  dimmer  view  than  we  originally 
anticipated. 

As  explained  in  our  statement,  we  now  believe  that  the  Act 

confuses  the  respective  roles  of  the  Government  and  the  private 

sector;  that  the  Act's  costs  will  be  higher  than  the  Government 

projects  and  its  administration  more  complicated;  and  that.,  in 

fact,  a  much  simpler  approach  exists  to  the  simultaneous 

promotion  of  widespread  participation  and  actuarial  soundness 

and,  indeed,  an  approach  that  does  not  require  legislation. 

If  any  members  of  the  Subcommittee  or  its  staff  have 
questions  concerning  NACIA' s  statement,  please  do  not  hesitate  to 
call  me  or  Linda  Vickers,  our  Washington  representative.   Again, 
I  appreciate  your  invitation  to  appear  before  the  Subcommittee. 


Sincerely, 
Deanna  Orwig 


1706  23rcl Streets.      •     Suite  100     •     Arlington, VA   22202-1552     •     (703)979-5542 


358 


STATEMENT  OF  THE 

NATIONAL  ASSOCIATION  OF  CROP  INSURANCE  AGENTS 

BEFORE  THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON  ENVIRONMENT,  CREDIT  AND 
RURAL  DEVELOPMENT,  COMMITTEE  ON  AGRICULTURE 

HOUSE  OF  REPRESENTATIVES 

April  21,  1994 

THE  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  REFORM  ACT  OF  1994 
The  National  Association  of  Crop  Insurance  Agents  ("NACIA") 
is  pleased  to  submit  its  views  on  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance 
Reform  Act  of  1994  to  the  Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and 
Rural  Development.   NACIA  was  organized  in  1981  as  a  non-profit 
corporation  to  foster  a  crop  insurance  program  that  will  serve 
the  needs  of  America's  farmers  and,  thereby,  to  promote  the  sale 
of  crop  insurance.   NACIA  has  been  an  active  participant  in  FCIC 
rule  making  proceedings  and  has  regularly  participated  in  the 
legislative  search  for  an  improved  crop  insurance  program  to  end 
ad  hoc  disaster  payments. 

NACIA  believes  that  the  statutory  declaration  of  purpose  in 
section  502  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  is  the  yardstick 
against  which  the  Reform  Act  must  be  measured.   That  section 
states  that  it  is  the  purpose  of  the  Act  "to  promote  the  national 
welfare  by  improving  the  economic  stability  of  agriculture 
through  a  sound  system  of  crop  insurance."   Will  the  Reform  Act 
improve  the  economic  stability  of  agriculture  by  making  more 
sound  the  present  system  of  crop  insurance  or  will  the  Reform  Act 
make  the  present  system  of  crop  insurance  less  sound  and. 


359 


thereby,  lessen  the  economic  stability  of  agriculture?   NACIA 
believes  the  latter  is  more  likely  than  the  former. 

I.   THE  GOVERNMENT'S  RESPONSIBILITY  AND 
THE  PRIVATE  SECTOR'S  RESPONSIBILITY 

As  will  be  shown  below,  the  Reform  Act  blurs  long-standing 

lines  that  distinguish  public  sector  functions  from  private 

sector  functions.   NACIA  believes  that  the  blurring  of  these 

lines  is  a  fundamental  defect  of  the  Reform  Act;  it  adds 

uncertainty  to  the  program,  creates  instability  for  its 

contractors  and,  ultimately,  will  redound  to  the  detriment  of  the 

producer  the  program  is  intended  to  serve.   NACIA  believes  that  a 

federal  program  that  creates  instability  among  those  responsible 

for  its  delivery  cannot  give  stability  to  its  beneficiaries. 

A.   UNDERWRITING  AND  LOSS  ADJUSTMENT 
In  any  insurance  company  there  is  always  a  tension  between 
the  conflicting  needs  of  actuarial  soundness  and  maximum 
participation.   That  tension  is  particularly  acute  in  the  Federal 
crop  insurance  program  where  Congress  has  mandated,  on  the  one 
hand,  that  there  be  a  projected  overall  loss  ratio  not  to  exceed 
110  percent  beginning  October  1,  1995  and,  on  the  other,  that  the 
expense  and  inefficiency  of  disaster  payments  be  eliminated 
through  maximum  participation  in  the  Federal  crop  insurance 
program.   Actuarial  soundness  precludes  the  acceptance  of  high 
risk  farmers  but  maximum  participation  bars  their  exclusion. 

This  tension  is  further  exacerbated  by  a  conflict  between 
the  Reform  Act  and  the  draft  of  the  1995  Standard  Reinsurance 

2 


360 


Agreement  ("SRA")  the  FCIC  recently  published  for  public 

consideration.   Section  2(d)(7)  of  the  Reform  Act  amends  section 

508(h)  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act,  7  U.S.C.  §  1508(h),  to 

state,  as  here  pertinent: 

"The  Corporation's  reinsurance  agreements  with  the 
reinsured  companies  shall  require  the  reinsured 
companies  to  bear  a  sufficient  share  of  any  potential 
loss  under  such  agreement  so  as  to  ensure  that  the 
reinsured  company  will  sell  and  service  policies  of 
insurance  in  a  sound  and  prudent  manner,  taking  into 
consideration  the  availability  of  private  reinsurance." 

In  other  words,  the  Reform  Act  would  require  the  FCIC  to 
transfer  a  sufficient  share  of  loss  (which  is  different  than  a 
share  of  risk)  to  reinsured  companies  so  that  they  do  not  sell 
policies  in  a  manner  that  is  not  "sound  and  prudent,"  taking  into 
consideration  the  availability  (a  factor  that  should  include  the 
cost)  of  reinsurance.   Because  this  section  requires  the  FCIC  to 
punish  reinsured  companies  that  sell  policies  to  high  risk 
producers  when  commercial  reinsurance  capacity  is  insufficient 
for  the  risk,  this  section  of  the  Reform  Act  clearly  resolves  the 
conflict  between  actuarial  soundness  and  participation  in  favor 
of  actuarial  soundness.   Parenthetically,  the  section  does  not, 
as  it  should,  direct  the  FCIC  to  increase  the  potential  profit  of 
reinsured  companies  that  sell  and  service  insurance  in  a  sound 
and  prudent  manner. 

Notwithstanding  the  fact  that  the  FCIC  drafted  section 
2(d)(7)  and  supports  its  enactment,  the  FCIC  took  the  exact 
opposite  view  in  its  draft  1995  SRA.   That  draft  requires 
reinsured  companies  - 


361 


"to  make  crop  insurance  available  to  all  eligible 
prof^ucers  for  the  crops  and  in  the  areas  which  are 
stated  in  its  Plan  of  Operation  as  approved  by  FCIC." 
Section  II. A. 1. 

This  section,  on  its  face,  requires  agents  to  sell  policies 
to  all  producers,  even  those  who  it  is  believed  will  present  a 
so-called  "moral  hazard"  to  the  program.   Compounding  this 
felony,  the  SRA  then  places  on  its  contractors  (and,  by 
implication,  their  agents)  the  burden  of  proof  they  are  not,  in 
any  way,  responsible  for  the  shenanigans  these  policyholders 
might  pull.   Thus,  the  draft  1995  SRA  resolves  the  conflict 
between  actuarial  soundness  and  participation  in  favor  of 
participation . 

To  resolve  the  tension  between  actuarial  soundness  and  full 
participation,  the  FCIC  must  recognize  that  while  crop  insurance 
is  a  form  of  catastrophic  insurance  there  are,  in  the  universe  of 
catastrophes,  so-called  "normal"  catastrophes  that  can  be 
underwritten  by  the  commercial  insurance  industry  and  cataclysmic 
disasters,  such  as  the  drought  of  1988  and  the  flood  of  1993, 
that  the  commercial  insurance  industry  simply  does  not  have  the 
surplus  to  underwrite.   Because  the  risk  of  cataclysmic  events  is 
not  a  true  insurance  risk,  the  indemnification  for  losses  from 
those  events  is  a  form  of  domestic  assistance  that  can  only  be 
borne  by  the  Government,  which  is  precisely  why  the  Federal  crop 
insurance  program  is  included  in  the  Catalogue  of  Domestic 
Assistance  Programs. 

The  Reform  Act  does  not  recognize  the  difference  between  the 
insurance  risk  that  commercial  companies  should  assume  and  the 

4 


362 


catastrophic  risk  that  the  Government  must  assume.   For  example, 
the  Reform  Act  does  not  state  who  will  underwrite  the  losses  on 
the  catastrophic  coverage  that  is  the  essence  of  the  Act.   This 
is  an  ominous  omission;  if  the  FCIC  intends  to  burden  the 
insurance  industry  with  liability  for  the  catastrophic  protection 
that  will  be  available  to  all  and  without  a  premium  charge  to 
any,  the  fundamental  premise  of  section  502  will  be  undermined. 
Societal  costs  cannot  be  assumed  by  "a  sound  system  of  crop 
insurance"  unless  the  insurance  system  can  spread  its  losses 
among  all  the  members  of  society. 

Similarly,  the  Reform  Act  does  not  specify  who  will  adjust 
losses  covered  by  its  catastrophic  risk  protection  plan.   This 
silence,  too,  is  unfortunate  and  deserves  inquiry.   Does  the  FCIC 
intend  to  assume  responsibility  for  adjusting  these  losses, 
either  directly  or  through  local  ASCS  offices?   If  so,  is  this 
the  first  step  in  a  preconceived  plan  to  eliminate  commercial 
insurers,  their  agents  and  their  adjusters  from  the  federal  crop 
insurance  program?  If  not,  why  is  the  Reform  Act  silent? 

B.   THE  DUAL  DELIVERY  SYSTEM 
At  different  times  NACIA  has  been  given  two  different 

reasons  for  the  Reform  Act's  dual  delivery  system.   Each  reason, 

however,  creates  its  own  contradictions  between  different 

sections  of  the  Act. 

We  first  understood  that  the  Reform  Act  created  a  separate 

government  delivery  system  to  process  applications  for 


363 


catastrophic  risk  protection  because  the  FCIC  expected  the  market 
to  divide  itself:   producers  who  wanted  only  catastrophic 
coverage  would  gravitate  towards  a  government  office  and 
producers  who  wanted  higher  levels  of  protection  would  contact 
their  agents.   If  the  FCIC  forced  producers  who  wanted  only 
catastrophic  coverage  to  spend  time  with  an  agent,  there  would  be 
a  backlash  of  complaints  that  would  undermine  the  Reform  Act. 

This  justification  for  a  government  delivery  system, 
however,  is  in  conflict  with  the  expense  reimbursement  formula 
the  Reform  Act  creates.   Under  that  formula,  the  expense 
reimbursement  for  selling  higher  levels  of  coverage  is  greater 
than  for  selling  lower  levels,  even  though  the  cost  of  selling 
both  levels  is  the  same.   The  admitted  purpose  of  this  disparity 
is  to  encourage  the  sale  of  higher  levels  of  production  because 
those  levels  are  consistent  with  the  public  interest.   If  higher 
levels  of  coverage  are  in  the  public  interest,  however,  why 
should  the  Reform  Act  create  a  mechanism  to  divert  producers  away 
from  agents  who,  alone,  are  qualified  to  explain  the  benefits  of 
higher  protection?   Instead,  the  Reform  Act  should  funnel 
producers  to  their  nearest  agent's  office. 

NACIA  was  later  informed  that  the  FCIC  does  not  expect  the 
market  to  divide  itself.   Instead,  the  FCIC  expects  that 
producers  who  want  catastrophic  coverage  only  will  visit  agents 
and  producers  who  want  higher  levels  of  coverage  only  will  visit 
government  delivery  offices.   According  to  the  explanation,  there 
are  certain  geographic  areas  that  are  underserved  by  agents  and 


/ 

364 

because  the  FCIC  cannot  define  "underservice, "  it  will  provide  an 
alternate  delivery  system  everywhere. 

This  theory  is  inconsistent  with  the  mechanism  the  Reform 
Act  creates  for  the  sale  of  catastrophic  coverage.   Producers  who 
purchase  catastrophic  coverage  must  remit  $50  with  their 
application  to  the  government  office  or  private  sales  agent. 
Because  that  check  will  be  deposited  in  the  U.S.  Treasury,  it 
must  be  transmitted  promptly  to  a  federal  reserve  bank.   If  a 
producer  who  purchased  catastrophic  coverage  from  a  government 
office  later  decides  to  purchase  a  higher  level  of  protection, 
the  government  office  would  have  to  send  the  producer's  file  to 
the  agent  and  the  government  would  have  to  refund  the  $50  check. 

The  problems  of  massive  transfers  of  policyholder  files,  of 
creating  an  audit  trail  for  the  collection,  remittance  and  refund 
of  tens  of  thousands  of  $50  checks,  and  the  paperwork  that  will 
be  created  for  agents  and  government  employees  alike  are  the 
antithesis  of  reform.   In  this  regard,  on  March  19,  1994,  the 
Washington  Post  reported  that  Senator  Leahy  was  investigating  the 
ASCS  Miami,  Florida  office  which  had  stored  up  to  $25  million  in 
negotiable  checks  in  a  file  cabinet.   According  to  the  Post,  the 
office  had  no  automated  system  for  keeping  track  of  its  checks 
and  had  no  way  of  being  certain  of  the  value  of  the  checks  on 
hand,  how  many  had  been  mailed  to  entitled  producers  or  whether 
some  had  been  stolen  and  fraudulently  cashed. 

Private  agents  cannot  deliver  catastrophic  risk  coverage  on 


365 


an  individual  yield  basis  for  $50  per  crop  per  producer,  not  to 
exceed  $100  per  producer  per  county.   An  actual  production  file 
for  a  typical  producer  may  be  an  inch  thick;  it  entails  hundreds 
of  entries  and  scores  of  calculations.   The  labor  involved  and 
the  legal  liability  agents  invite  for  innocent  error  under  the 
FCIC's  new  standard  of  strict  liability  cannot  be  recompensed  for 

$50  or  $100. 

In  short,  if  it  is  the  judgment  of  Congress  that 
catastrophic  risk  protection  must  be  delivered  for  remuneration 
less  than  the  cost  of  delivery,  there  must  be  a  dual  delivery 
system  and  the  Government  must  assume  responsibility  for  the 
delivery  of  that  plan.   On  the  other  hand,  if  it  is  the  judgment 
of  Congress  that  the  reasonable  and  allocable  costs  of  agents  are 
to  be  reimbursed,  a  dual  delivery  system  is  unnecessary;  indeed, 
it  is  wasteful  of  federal  funds  and  inconsistent  with  public 

policy. 

At  least  since  1921  and  the  passage  of  the  Budget  and 
Accounting  Act  of  1921,  the  civilian  procurement  of  supplies  and 
services  has  been  a  fundamental  public  policy.   That  policy  is 
presently  enunciated  in  0MB  Circular  A-7  6  which  states,  in 
pertinent  part: 

"The  Federal  Government  shall  rely  on  commercially 
available  sources  to  provide  commercial  products  and 
services.   In  accordance  with  the  provisions  of  this 
Circular,  the  Government  shall  not  start  or  carry  on 
any  activity  to  provide  a  commercial  product  or  service 
if  the  product  or  service  can  be  procured  more 
economically  from  a  commercial  source."   (See,  also  0MB 
Policy  Letter  on  Inherently  Governmental  Functions,  57 
F.R.  45096  et  sea. .  September  30,  1992). 


366 


In  1980,  Congress  was  able  to  make  crop  insurance  available 
for  all  crops  in  all  counties  because  it  amended  the  statute  to 
enlist  independent  insurance  agents  in  the  sale  and  service  of 
crop  insurance.   Those  agents  have  been  as  successful  as  the  free 
disaster  payments  that  compete  against  them  have  permitted  them 
to  be.   Indeed,  those  agents  have  been  so  successful  in  the  sale 
of  reinsured  policies  that  for  years  now  the  FCIC  has  recognized 
that  a  dual  delivery  system  for  the  sale  and  service  of  FCIC 
policies  was  wasteful  and  should  be  abolished. 

In  this  regard,  the  FCIC's  own  records  disclose  the 
inordinate  expenditures  that  were  made  to  train  ASCS  employees  to 
sell  Federal  crop  insurance  and  the  inadequacy  of  their 
accomplishments.   In  the  first  four  months  of  1992,  the 
Department  of  Agriculture  spent  $202,000.00  to  train  ASCS 
employees  to  sell,  service  and  adjust  losses  on  Federal  crop 
insurance  policies.   As  of  that  date,  a  total  of  50  ASCS 
employees  had  been  trained  to  sell  and  service  policies  and  two 
ASCS  employees  had  been  trained  to  adjust  losses.   The  return  on 
that  $202,000  was  two  policies  sold  and  one  of  those  policies  was 
sold  in  error.   The  two  policies  were  sold  to  a  husband  and  wife 
but  under  FCIC  procedures  a  husband  and  wife  must  insure  their 
production  together  under  one  policy.   Moreover,  the  policies 
were  not  sold  in  a  state  in  which  there  was  an  ASCS  employee 
qualified  to  adjust  losses. 

NACIA  believes  that,  notwithstanding  the  FCIC's  estimates, 
approximately  $250  million  will  be  required  to  train  the  public 


367 


sector  to  compete  against  the  private  sector  and  that  this 
expenditure  is  not  justified  by  experience,  is  wasteful  of 
private  sector  tax  dollars  and  is  inimical  to  the  survival  and 
success  of  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program. 

II.   EXPENSE  REIMBURSEMENTS 
The  FCIC  reimburses  its  contractors'  operating  and 
administrative  costs  based  on  a  percentage  of  premiums. 
Premiums.,  however,  are  a  function  of  crop  prices  which,  in  turn, 
are  unrelated  to  the  costs  of  selling  and  servicing  multiple 
peril  crop  insurance.   Those  costs  are  the  same  whether  wheat  is 
$1.00  a  bushel  or  $10.00  a  bushel.   Commissions  based  on  the 
former  price,  however,  would  bankrupt  contractors  and  commissions 
based  on  the  latter  price  would  unjustly  enrich  them.   Arthur 
Andersen  addressed  this  problem  in  a  1989  study  commissioned  by 

the  FCIC: 

"With  respect  to  our  evaluation  of  the  current  MPCI 
expense  reimbursement  structure,  we  believe  the 
reimbursement  structure,  excluding  consideration  of  the 
underwriting  gain,  is  not  designed  so  that  it  will 
always  result  in  a  reimbursement  that  is  fair  and 
equitable  to  all  parties.   This  is  primarily  because 
the  costs  incurred  by  the  contractors  are  not  directly 
dependent  on  the  factors  which  determine  the  premiums, 
yet  the  FCIC  reimbursement  is  directly  related  to 
premiums."   p.  IV. 

"The  FCIC  should  make  a  determination  regarding  which 
of  the  contractors'  costs  are  allowable  for  reim- 
bursement and  communicate  the  information  to  the 
contractors,  preferably  within  the  contractor 
agreements."   p.  10 

The  Federal  Acquisition  Regulation  defines  the  costs  of 
commercial  contractors  that  are  allowable  expenses  and  regulates 

10 


368 


the  amount  of  profit  government  contractors  can  make.   At 

present,  section  508(h)  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  states: 

"The  Corporation  shall  also  pay  operating  and 
administrative  costs  to  insurers  of  policies  on  which 
the  Corporation  provides  reinsurance  in  an  amount 
determined  by  the  Corporation." 

NACIA  urges  that  this  section  be  amended  as  follows: 

"The  Corporation  shall  reimburse  the  allowable, 
reasonable  and  allocable  costs,  as  those  terms  are 
defined  by  the  Federal  Acquisition  Regulation,  to 
insurers  of  policies  on  which  the  Corporation  provides 
reinsurance  and  pay  a  profit  for  the  sale  and  service 
of  such  policies,  as  authorized  by  law." 

This  amendment  would  subject  the  FCIC's  contractors  to  the 

same  cost  regulations  that  the  Government  has  promulgated  for  all 

of  its  commercial  contractors  and  it  would  require  FCIC  close-out 

audits  of  each  year's  reinsurance  agreement,  an  important  but 

neglected  discipline.   Finally,  we  believe  that  this  amendment  is 

one-half  of  the  solution  to  a  "sound  system  of  crop  insurance" 

that  will  protect  producers  against  natural  disaster  and  supplant 

disaster  payments.   The  second  half  of  that  system  is  the 

elimination  of  the  cost  of  cataclysmic  catastrophes  from  the 

FCIC's  rate  structure. 

III.   CATASTROPHIC  LOSSES 
In  1982,  Milliman  &  Robertson,  consulting  actuaries  with 
whom  the  FCIC  contracted,  recommended  that,  among  other  things, 
the  FCIC  define  catastrophic  losses  to  differentiate  them  from 
so-called  "normal"  losses.   Milliman  &  Robertson  suggested  that 
catastrophic  losses  could  be  defined  in  terms  of  the  frequency  of 
loss,  the  severity  of  loss  or  both.   In  addition,  we  believe  that 

11 


369 


catastrophic  losses  may  be  defined  differently  according  to  crop 
or  geographic  area  or  both. 

Catastrophic  crop  losses  are  not  traditional  insurance 
losses  for  which  commercial  insurance  and  reinsurance  are 
available.   For  this  reason,  protection  against  catastrophic 
losses  should  be  viewed,  as  Congress  all  along  intended,  as  a 
domestic  assistance  component  of  the  Federal  program  that  the 
Government  must  assume,  if  it  is  to  be  assumed  at  all.   Moreover, 
because  catastrophic  losses  are  not  insurance  losses  they  should 
be  excluded  from  the  calculation  of  insurance  premiums  and  loss 

ratios. 

The  assumption  of  liability  for  catastrophic  losses  by  the 
FCIC  and  the  concomitant  deletion  of  the  cost  of  those  losses 
from  premium  rates  and  loss  ratio  would  have  a  significant, 
salutary  effect  on  the  Federal  crop  insurance  program.   In  five 
years,  we  have  witnessed  two  catastrophes  of  biblical  proportion, 
the  drought  of  1988  and  the  flood  of  1993.   If  those  two 
catastrophes  alone  were  eliminated  from  the  FCIC's  rate  structure 
and  loss  ratios,  premium  rates  would  go  down,  making  the  program 
more  attractive  to  more  participants;  the  concomitant  cost  of  the 
FCIC's  subsidy  of  those  premiums  would  decrease;  and 
discriminatory  underwriting  practices,  necessitated  by  Congress' 
determination  to  achieve  a  1.1  loss  ratio  because  of  fiscal  needs 
and  not  program  needs,  could  be  avoided  because  the  FCIC  could 
more  readily  comply  with  the  statutory  requirement. 

The  FCIC  has  published  for  public  comment  a  proposed 

12 


370 


definition  of  catastrophic  losses.   When  defined,  these  losses 
should  be  deleted  from  all  premium  and  loss  ratio  calculations. 
Because  of  the  immediate,  salutary  benefits  of  such  a  rule,  we 
believe  it  is  a  viable  alternative  to  the  FCIC's  proposal  to 
provide  free  insurance  to  farmers  to  protect  60  percent  of  their 
yield  at  a  50  percent  price  election;  the  FCIC  could  use  the 
funds  to  be  allocated  to  disaster  insurance  to  subsidize 
catastrophic  losses  and  thereby  make  it  possible  for  private 
underwriters  to  assume  the  risk  of  "normal"  losses.   In  addition, 
if  the  Department  abandons  its  contemplated  second  delivery 
system,  the  cost  of  establishing  that  system  would  also  be 
available  to  fund  catastrophic  losses  or  premium  subsidies. 

IV.   CONCLUSION 
An  essential  element  in  "a  sound  system  of  crop  insurance," 
which  is  the  focus  and  concern  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act 
of  1938,  as  amended,  is  the  elimination  of  ad  hoc  disaster 
payments.   While  we  may  speculate  whether  the  Reform  Act  will 
contribute  to  that  result,  there  is  no  question  that  the  Act 
carries  too  much  baggage  of  its  own  creation.   Thus,  the  trade- 
off is  not  worth  the  gamble. 

(Attachment  follows:) 


13 


371 


LEVIN    Si    ROSENSTEIN.    P.C. 

ATTORNCVS 


SUITE    314 

1  1  30    SEVENTEENTH    STREET.    N  w 

WASHINGTON.    D     C.    2003e 


AREA   CODE    202 
TELEPHONE    -429-1795 
TELECOPIER     429-9729 

ANALYSIS  OF  THE  FEDERAL  CROP  INSURANCE  PROGRAM  ACT  OF  1994 

PREPARED  FOR 
THE  NATIONAL  ASSOCIATION  OF  CROP  INSURANCE  AGENTS 

AND 
RURAL  COMMIJNITY  INSURANCE  SERVICES.  INC. 

The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reform  Act  of  1994  represents 
another  effort  to  eliminate  ad  hoc  disaster  payments.   The  Reform 
Act  would  replace  those  discretionary  payments  with  guaranteed 
payments  of  catastrophic  risk  protection  coverage  to  producers 
who  applied  to  a  local  government  office  or  private  agent,  paid  a 
modest  administrative  fee,  and  suffered  a  50  percent  loss  in 
yield  coverage.   They  would  be  indemnified  at  60  percent  of  the 
expected  market  price.   Additional  levels  of  protection  would  be 
available  only  from  agents. 

At  the  same  time,  the  Reform  Act  would  also  vest  new 
authority  in  the  Secretary,  tri.nsf erring  to  that  Office  judgments 
that  were  previously  made  by  the  Congress  and  embodied  in  statute 
and  judgments  that  were  entrusted  to  the  Board  of  Directors  of 
the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  ("FCIC"). 

The  FCIC's  solution  to  the  problem  of  disaster  payments 
brings  a  host  of  new  problems  and  their  solutions  have  their 
problems.   Thus,  the  Reform  Act,  in  its  totality,  is  a  hodgepodge 
of  rubber  bands  and  bolsters,  balusters  and  glue  holding  together 


81-128  0-94-13 


372 


a  statutory  structure  whose  angles  are  not  right  and  whose  joints 
do  not  meet.   The  structure  tilts  acutely  against  private  agents 
and  insurers  and,  if  it  collapses,  it  is  upon  them  that  it  will 
fall. 

I.   THE  OFFER  OF  INSURANCE 
The  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Act  presently  names  each  peril 
against  which  loss  is  protected.   Thus,  at  the  time  of  the 
purchase  and  sale  of  a  crop  insurance  policy,  the  policyholder, 
the  agent  and  the  insurer  )cnow  the  insurable  causes  of  loss 
covered  by  the  policy.   Under  the  Reform  Act,  however,  insurance 
coverage  will  be  available  for  losses  due  to  "drought,  flood  or 
other  natural  disasters  as  determined  by  the  Secretary."   In 
other  words,  each  year,  as  of  the  sales  closing  date,  the 
policyholder,  the  agent  and  the  insurer  may  not  know  whether  a 
policy  would  protect  against  such  perils  as  hail,  wind,  frost, 
fire,  excessive  rain,  tornado,  insects  or  plant  disease.   Whether 
those  causes  of  loss  are  insured  causes  of  loss  would  be  left  to 
the  sole  discretion  of  the  Secretary  without  any  statutory 
guidelines  requiring  a  particular  decision. 

In  this  regard,  the  Reform  Act,  like  the  current  law, 
permits  the  deletion  of  fire  and  hail  coverage  provided  it  is 
purchased  commercially.   However,  because  at  the  sales  closing 
date  the  Secretary  may  not  have  declared  fire  and  hail  to  be 
covered  causes,  there  could  be  no  coverage  to  delete.   Thus,  the 
Reform  Act  forces  producers  to  purchase  fire  and  hail  insurance 
separately,  a  sharp  reversal  of  current  public  policy. 

2 


373 


A  number  of  undesirable  consequences  can  flow  from 
unfettered  Secretarial  discretion.   For  example,  the  Secretary 
can  declare  causes  to  be  covered  to  curry  political  favor  or  may 
decline  to  declare  a  cause  covered  for  budgetary  reasons  or  to 
force  Congress  to  revert  to  disaster  payments.   Concomitantly, 
insurers  might  seek  to  have  causes  of  loss  not  declared  insurable 
to  protect  diminishing  surplus  or  to  have  causes  of  loss  declared 
insurable  to  increase  sales. 

The  Reform  Act  should  contain  the  current  laundry  list  of 
all  insurable  causes  and,  like  the  present  law,  leave  it  to  the 
Board  of  Directors  to  supplement  that  list.   The  more  officials 
empowered  with  such  discretion,  the  less  likely  it  is  that  such 
discretion  will  be  abused. 

II.   CATASTROPHIC  RISK  PROTECTION 
As  a  condition  for  participation  in  any  Department  of 
Agriculture  benefit  program  for  any  crop  or  any  loan  program,  a 
producer  must  obtain  catastrophic  risk  protection.   The  scope  of 
such  coverage,  however,  is  confused.   New  section  508(b)(5) 
states  that  if  a  producer's  crop  on  any  land  in  the  county  is 
covered,  that  crop  on  all  of  the  producer's  insurable  land  in  the 
county  must  be  covered.   On  the  other  hand,  new  section  508(b)(6) 
states  that  to  qualify  for  any  price  support  or  loan  program, 
catastrophic  risk  protection  must  be  obtained  only  on  any  crop 
that  has  contributed  or  is  expected  to  contribute  10  percent  or 
more  of  the  total  expected  value  of  all  the  producer's  crops. 
While  these  formulas  may  not  be  mutually  exclusive,  one  should  be 

3 


374 


selected. 

Catastrophic  risk  protection  covers  a  50  percent  loss  in 
yield,  on  an  area  or  individual  yield  basis,  when  both  options 
are  offered  by  the  FCIC,  indemnified  at  60  percent  of  the 
expected  market  price  (i.e. .  coverage  for  a  30  percent  loss)  or  a 
comparable  coverage  as  determined  by  the  FCIC'   Producers  may 
elect  an  individual  yield  and  loss  basis  or  an  area  yield  and 
loss  basis.   Coverage  includes  losses  due  to  prevented  planting. 
The  cost  of  catastrophic  risk  coverage  is  $50  per  crop  per 
county,  not  to  exceed  $100  per  producer  per  county.   The  producer 
is  to  pay  the  fee  at  the  time  of  application  to  the  United  States 
Department  of  Agriculture  ("USDA")  or  the  agent.   The  fee  is  to 
be  waived  in  the  case  of  limited  resource  producers  or  refunded 
upon  the  purchase  of  additional  protection.   Assunedly,  any 
monies  collected  will  be  required  to  be  remitted  to  the  FCIC  for 
deposit  in  the  United  States  Treasury  because  the  funds  collected 
will  only  be  available  for  salaries  and  expenses  upon 
appropriation. 

Finally,  if  a  producer  applies  for  catastrophic  risk 
protection  from  a  USDA  office  and  then  elects  to  purchase 
additional  coverage,  the  USDA  office  will  have  to  transfer  the 
producer's  file  to  the  agent.   In  this  regard,  and  for  all  levels 
of  coverage,  the  producer  is  required  to: 


'  The  Reform  Act  creates  a  noninsured  assistance  program  to 
provide  coverage  "equivalent  to"  catastrophic  risk  protection  for 
crops  for  which  such  protection  is  not  available.   This  program 
is  discussed  below,  in  section  IX. 


375 


(1)  purchase  insurance  by  the  sales  closing  date; 

(2)  provide  acceptable  records  of  previous  acreage  and 
production  or  accept  a  determined  yield;  and 

(3)  report  acreage  planted  and  prevented  from  planting 
by  the  acreage  reporting  date. 

The  Reform  Act's  provisions  for  catastrophic  coverage  are 
cumbersome. 

First,  if  a  producer  does  not  apply  for  catastrophic  risk 
protection  on  a  crop  because  it  had  not  contributed  and  was  not 
expected  to  contribute  10  percent  of  the  value  of  all  of  the 
producer's  crops,  but,  in  fact,  the  crop  does  come  to  represent 
that  value,  what  happens?   Second,  the  Reform  Act  does  not  state 
what  degree  of  loss  in  an  area  triggers  catastrophic  protection. 
Third .  giving  a  producer  a  choice  of  individual  coverage  or  area 
yield  coverage  invites  adverse  selection.   Fourth,  the  actual 
cost  and  potential  liability  of  processing  applications  for 
catastrophic  coverage  on  an  individual  yield  basis  is  too  great 
for  the  compensation  allowed.   Indeed,  even  on  an  area  coverage 
basis,  the  producer's  administrative  fee  will  not  be  adequate 
compensation  for  the  ministerial  functions  described  below  or  for 
the  separate  costs  of  loss  adjustment.   Fifth,  requiring  the 
physical  handling  of  tens  of  thousands  of  checks  by  government 
employees  and  independent  agents  and  the  preparation  and 
recordation  of  receipts  for  each  of  those  checks  is  an  auditor's 
nightmare.   Sixth,  requiring  government  offices  to  transfer  their 
policy  folders  to  private  agents  in  advance  of  the  sales  closing 
date  is  impossible.   Producers  may  not  apply  for  catastrophic 


376 


protection  until  too  late  or  may  not  decide  until  too  late  to 
purchase  increased  protection.   And,  under  the  best  of 
circumstances  such  ministerial  functions  often  are  left  undone  or 
done  improperly.   Seventh .  what  is  the  cost  of  refunding  the  $50 
administrative  fees  to  the  producers  who  buy  higher  levels  of 
coverage  and  to  whom  wiJl  it  be  left  to  process  the  complaints 
when  those  fees  are  not  timely  or  properly  reimbursed? 

It  is  no  answer  to  the  sixth  objection  that  a  producer  who 
procrastinates  will  have  to  suffer  the  conseguences  of 
underinsurance;  that  answer  merely  invites  a  return  to  disaster 
payments.   Nor  is  it  an  acceptable  answer  to  permit  government 
offices  to  sell  all  levels  of  protection  in  order  to  lessen  the 
bureaucratic  entanglements  that  the  bureaucracy  proposed.   This 
answer  undermines  the  long-standing  government  policy  of  using 
the  private  sector  to  perform  the  Government's  commercial 
functions. 

Catastrophic  risk  protection  should  be  limited  to  area 
coverage  and  the  Reform  Act  should  specify  the  amount  of  damage 
to  a  county  that  triggers  the  catastrophic  risk  coverage  just  as 
the  Reform  Act  establishes  such  a  trigger  for  noninsured 
assistance  payments.   All  producers  who  suffer  a  loss  egual  to  or 
more  than  the  trigger  amount  should  receive  100  percent  of  their 
catastrophic  coverage  and  those  whose  crops  suffered  less  should 
receive  a  proportional  lesser  amount.   Again,  similar  provisions 
are  made  for  noninsured  assistance  payments. 

Moreover,  in  the  event  a  county  is  declared  eligible  for 


377 


catastrophic  risk  protection,  the  FCIC  should  reimburse  the 
actual  costs  of  loss  adjustment  in  that  county.   Finally,  payment 
should  not  be  collected  at  the  time  of  application.   Indeed, 
until  the  application  is  accepted,  there  is  no  insurance  for 
which  to  pay.   The  charge  for  catastrophic  protection  should  be 
billed  as  any  other  crop  insurance  premium. 

III.   THE  DUAL  DELIVERY  SYSTEM 

The  Refom  Act  creates  a  USDA  delivery  system  on  the  theory 
that  producers  who  only  want  catastrophic  protection  will  object 
if  required  to  visit  an  agent  and  listen  to  a  "sales  pitch"  and 
that  their  objections  will  be  so  loud  and  numerous  so  as  to 
undermine  a  single  delivery  system  and,  thereby,  the  entire  crop 
insurance  program.   The  government  also  believes  that  there  are 
areas  in  which  private  agents  will  not  deliver  insurance  because 
it  will  not  be  economical  for  them  to  do  so. 

The  government's  rationale  is  flawed.   First,  producers  can 
tell  agents  they  want  only  catastrophic  protection  and  thus  end 
any  "sales  pitch"  before  it  begins.   Second,  it  is  in  the  public 
interest  for  producers  to  visit  agents  and  be  captive  to  their 
"sales  pitch."   Catastrophic  protection  alone  simply  does  not 
pass  the  suitability  test.   Catastrophic  protection  does  not 
secure  a  loan;  it  does  not  cover  annual  operating  costs;  and  it 
does  not  protect  against  bankruptcy.   In  short,  federal  crop 
insurance  exists  because  catastrophic  protection  is  not  a 
prophylactic.   Indeed,  if  catastrophic  protection  was  adequate, 
why  is  each  USDA  office  going  to  have  available  for  distribution 

7 


378 


the  names  of  all  crop  insurance  agents  in  the  county? 

Finally,  and  notwithstanding  the  USOA's  own  estimates,  we 
believe  it  will  cost  approximately  $2  50  million  to  develop  and 
train  a  federal  sales  and  loss  adjustment  force.   Certainly,  for 
far  less  the  FCIC  could  make  it  economically  feasible  for  private 
agents  to  sell  and  service  multiple  peril  crop  insurance  in  those 
counties  where  the  delivery  system  may  be  inadequate.   For  far 
less,  the  FCIC  could  train  federal  agents  and  adjusters  just  in 
those  counties  that  are  not  adequately  served.   And,  perhaps  for 
less,  the  FCIC  could  buy  the  farms  of  those  producers  who  want 
crop  insurance  but  absolutely  have  no  way  to  buy  it. 

Apart  from  the  long-standing  public  policy  against  a  dual 
delivery  system,  which  RCIS  and  NACIA  documented  in  their 
respective  testimony  to  the  Subcommittee  on  Appropriations  for 
Agriculture,  is  the  fact  that  a  federal  delivery  system  and  the 
private  delivery  system  will  not  be  audited  by  the  same 
government  offices  applying  the  same  standards.   In  this  regard, 
it  may  reasonably  be  inferred  from  the  conduct  of  the  Compliance 
Division  and  the  Appeals  Branch  that  there  is,  in  the  FCIC,  a 
philosophic  antagonism  towards  the  private  sector.   Under  these 
circumstances,  any  comparison  of  the  two  delivery  systems  will 
suffer  from  an  institutional  prejudice  that,  like  any  prejudice, 
is  simply  unacceptable  and  will  redound  to  the  private  sector's 
permanent  detriment. 


379 


IV.   CROP  INSURANCE  COVERAGE 
A.   Levels  of  Coverage 
The  Reform  Act  gives  producers  the  option  of  purchasing 
additional  coverage  based  on  an  individual  yield  and  loss  basis 
or  on  an  area  yield  and  loss  basis,  when  both  options  are 
offered,  at  65  percent  or  more  of  the  recorded  or  appraised 
average  yield  and  100  percent  of  the  expected  market  price,  or  an 
equivalent  coverage.   The  level  of  coverage  is  to  be  dollar 
denominated  and  may  be  purchased  at  any  level  not  to  exceed  85 
percent  of  the  individual  yield  or  95  percent  of  the  area  yield 
as  determined  by  the  FCIC. 

The  Reform  Act  requires  the  FCIC  to  establish  a  price  level 
for  each  commodity  on  which  insurance  is  offered  that  - 

(1)  is  not  less  than  the  projected  market  price,  as 
determined  by  the  FCIC;  or 

(2)  may  be  based  on  the  actual  market  price  at  the 
time  of  harvest,  as  determined  by  the  FCIC. 

Insurance  coverage  shall  be  equal  to  less  than  the  level  the  FCIC 

so  establishes  and  shall  be  quoted  in  dollars  per  acre. 

.4  *.  -^ 
B.   Premiums 

The  Reform  Act  requires  the  FCIC  to  establish  premiums  at  a 
level  sufficient  to  attain  an  expected  loss  ratio  of  not  greater 
than  1.1.   As  to  each  level  of  coverage  the  Reform  Act  states: 

(1)   For  catastrophic  risk  coverage  (i.e. .  30  percent 
coverage) ,  the  amount  of  premium  is  to  cover:   (a)  anticipated 
losses;  and  (b)  a  reasonable  reserve.   The  FCIC  is  to  pay  the 
entire  premium. 


380 


(2)   For  levels  of  coverage  less  than  65  percent  of  the 
yield  and  100  percent  of  the  market  price  but  more  than 
catastrophic  risk  coverage  fi.e. .  coverage  between  31  percent  and 
64  percent),  the  premium  is  to  cover:   (a)  anticipated  losses; 
(b)  a  reasonable  reserve;  and  (c)  operating  and  administrative 
expenses  which  are  to  be  less  than  the  expenses  allowed  for  the 
highest  level  of  coverage.   The  FCIC  is  to  pay  the  premium  share 
covering  the  amount  of  premium  established  for  catastrophic  risk 
protection  plus  (b)  and  (c) . 

(3)   For  65  percent  and  higher  levels  of  coverage  the 
premium  is  to  cover:   (a)  anticipated  losses;  (b)  a  reasonable 
reserve;  and  (c)  operating  and  administrative  expenses  as 
determined  by  the  FCIC  on  an  industry-wide  basis  as  a  percent  of 
the  total  premium.   The  FCIC  is  to  pay  the  premium  share  covering 
a  50  percent  loss  in  yield  indemnified  at  75  percent  of  the 
expected  market  price  plus  (b)  and  (c) . 

The  Reform  Act  establishes  expense  reimbursements  for 
insurance  with  levels  of  coverage  between  31  percent  and  64 
percent  at  a  lower  rate  than  for  coverage  at  the  65  percent  level 
so  that  the  FCIC  may  penalize  agents  who  sell  31  percent  coverage 
to  a  producer  who  intended  to  buy  30  percent  catastrophic 
coverage.   Under  such  a  sale,  the  producer's  $50  administrative 
fee  would  be  reimbursed  and  the  agent  would  earn  a  full 
commission.   Thus,  the  Reform  Act  creates  a  formula  for  the 
reimbursement  of  operating  and  administrative  expenses  to  prevent 
agents  from  selling  the  very  coverage  that  the  Reform  Act  creates 


381 


and  authorizes  them  to  sell. 

The  cost  of  selling  and  servicing  a  policy  providing  64 
percent  coverage  is  no  different  than  the  cost  of  selling  and 
servicing  a  policy  providing  65  percent  coverage  or  a  policy 
providing  35  percent  coverage  and,  yet,  by  law,  the  reimbursement 
on  the  former  must  be  lower  than  the  reimbursement  on  the  latter. 
In  addition,  the  Reform  Act  contains  no  formula  for  calculating 
expense  reimbursements  at  the  lower  level  of  coverage,  whereas  at 
the  higher  level,  expenses  are  to  be  determined  on  an  "industry- 
wide basis,"  whatever  that  term  means  and  however  those  expenses 
are  to  be  calculated.   Will  companies  that  spend  six  percent  of 
premium  on  loss  adjustment  be  reimbursed  for  only  five  percent  if 
that  is  the  amount  determined  on  an  "industry-wide  basis"?   Will 
companies  that  pay  an  average  commission  of  16  percent  get  a 
windfall  if  the  "industry-wide  basis"  is  18  percent? 

Compounding  this  matter  and,  indeed,  complicating  the  entire 
issue  of  insurance  delivery  and  contract  compliance  is  a  new 
section  508(d)(3)  which  states: 

"If  a  private  insurance  provider  determines  that  it  may 
provide  insurance  more  efficiently  than  the  expense 
reimbursement  amount  set  by  the  Corporation,  the 
private  insurance  provider,  if  approved  by  the  Board, 
may  reduce  the  premium  charged  the  insured  by  the 
amount  of  such  efficiency.   Any  such  reductions  shall 
be  subject  to  the  rules,  limitations  and  procedures 
established  by  the  Corporation." 

This  section  invites  contractors  to  shortchange  amorphous 

but  crucial  components  of  contract  responsibilities,  such  as 

compliance,  and  rewards  them  with  increased  market  share  if  they 

are  successful.   At  the  same  time,  the  section  requires  the  FCIC 

11      ^'  •"'    "" 


382 


to  ferret  out  and  negate,  by  new  procedures  and  regulations, 
every  shortcut  a  contractor  might  invent.   This  is  a  battle  of 
wits  the  FCIC  will  lose  sufficiently  often  to  distort  the 
marketplace  and  sully  the  reputation  of  all  of  its  contractors. 

The  Federal  Acquisition  Regulation  establishes  a  government- 
wide  system  for  the  compensation  of  contractors.   Instead  of 
adopting  that  system,  which  compensates  contractors  for  their 
reasonable,  allocable  and  allowable  costs  and  permits  them  an 
agreed  upon  profit  according  to  an  established  body  of  precedent, 
the  Reform  Act  introduces  caprice  and  uncertainty  into  a  contract 
system  designed  to  eliminate  both. 

V.   YIELD  DETERMINATIONS 

The  Reform  Act  appears  to  mandate  yield  coverage  plans  based 
both  on  actual  production  history  ("APH")  and  on  area  yield.   On 
one  hand,  the  Reform  Act  states  that  the  FCIC  "shall"  provide  an 
APH  plan  and  an  area  yield  plan.   On  the  other  hand,  two 
paragraphs  later,  the  Reform  Act  states  the  FCIC  "may"  provide  an 
area  yield  plan. 

The  APH  yield  plan  uses  the  producer's  APH  for  the  four 
previous,  consecutive  crop  years  up  to  a  data  base  of  10  years. 
If  the  producer  does  not  submit  adequate  documentation,  the  FCIC 
is  to  assign  a  yield  of  not  less  than  65  percent  of  the 
transitional  yield,  adjusted  to  reflect  available  APH 
documentation. 

The  area  yield  plan  allows  an  insured  producer  to  qualify 
for  an  indemnity  if  a  loss  has  occurred  in  the  "area"  in  which 

12 


383 


the  insured  farm  is  located.^  The  producer  will  be  allowed  to 
select  the  level  of  area  production  at  which  an  indemnity  will  be 
paid.   The  producer  may  choose  between  individual  or  area  yield 
coverage  on  a  commodity-by-commodity  basis. 

The  section  on  area  yield  should  make  clear  that  the 
producer  in  the  damaged  "area"  must  also  have  damage  to  be 
indemnified. 

VI.   CLAIMS  FOR  LOSSES 
The  Reform  Act  introduces  a  new  procedure  for  the  resolution 
of  disputes  between  producers  and  insurance  companies.   Under  the 
Reform  Act,  the  FCIC  is  to  promulgate  standards  to  ensure  that 
all  claims  are  adjusted  uniformly  and  timely.   The  Reform  Act 
then  states  that  if  a  claim  is  denied  by  the  FCIC,  the  producer 
may  bring  an  action  against  the  FCIC  and  the  insurer  in  the 
United  States  District  Court  for  the  district  in  which  the 
insured  farm  is  located. 

Under  these  provisions,  if  an  insurer  denied  a  producer's 
claim,  the  producer  would  not  sue  the  insurer  or  institute  an 
arbitration  action.   Instead,  we  understand  that  the  insurer 
would  appeal  to  the  FCIC  and  a  formal,  administrative  hearing 
would  be  held  before  an  administrative  law  judge  ("ALJ") .   If  the 
ALJ  ruled  against  the  producer,  the  producer  could  sue  the  FCIC 
and  the  insurer. 


'  New  section  508(b)(5),  discussed  above,  requires  "all 
insurable  land  of  the  producer  in  the  county"  to  be  covered  by 
catastrophic  risk  protection  insurance.   Will  an  area  be  other 
than  a  county  for  purposes  of  an  area  yield  plan? 

13 


384 


This  process  is  both  inefficient  and  incorrect.   First,  it 
eliminates  alternative  dispute  resolution  procedures,  such  as 
arbitration  and  mediation.   Second,  if  an  ALJ  denies  a  claim,  it 
then  becomes  the  Government  and  not  the  insurer  that  issued  an 
appealable  order;  clearly,  under  those  circumstances  the  insurer 
should  not  be  a  party  to  the  suit.   In  this  regard,  the 
producer's  appeal  would  rest  on  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act 
with  which  the  Government  must  comply,  not  insurers.   This 
provision  will  substantially  increase  contractors'  costs. 

VII.   REINSURANCE 

The  Reform  Act  mandates  that  the  Standard  Reinsurance 

Agreement  ("SRA")  shall  require  reinsured  companies  - 

"...to  bear  a  sufficient  share  of  any  potential 
loss... so  as  to  ensure  that  the  reinsured  company  will 
sell  and  service  policies  of  insurance  in  a  sound  and 
prudent  manner,  taking  into  consideration  the 
availability  of  private  reinsurance." 

This  section  is  curious.   Insurance  companies  that  sell 

policies  in  "a  sound  and  prudent  manner"  do  not  sell  policies  to 

high  risk  producers  or  on  high  risk  crops.   And  when  insurance 

companies  take  into  consideration  the  lack  of  available  private 

reinsurance,  prudence  makes  them  even  more  risk  adverse.   This 

section  makes  sense  only  if  its  purpose  is  to  limit  the 

availability  of  crop  insurance  to  producers  whose  potential  loss 

ratio  will  yield  an  underwriting  gain.   And  this  purpose  is 

contrary  to  the  public  policy  underlying  the  Federal  crop 

insurance  program,  as  demonstrated  by  the  FCIC's  own 

interpretations  and  public  statements. 

14       P' 


385 


VIII.   MISCELLANEOUS 
The  Reform  Act  makes  the  following  changes  in  the  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Act  which  changes  are  of  varying  import. 

1.  A  technical  change  is  made  in  the  USDA's  representation 
on  the  FCIC's  Board. 

2.  The  Reform  Act  would  give  the  FCIC  the  authority  to 
settle  claims,  an  authority  that  now  rests  in  the  Justice 
Department.   This  provision  may  cause  the  Reform  Act  to  be 
referred  to  the  Judiciary  Committee. 

3.  The  Reform  Act  contains  standards  for  the 
disqualification  of  producers. 

4.  The  Reform  Act  states: 

"There  is  hereby  appropriated,  without  fiscal  year 
limitation,  such  sums  as  may  be  necessary  to  carry  out 
the  purpose  of  the  insurance  fund." 

Appropriations  are  not  customarily  made  in  substantive  laws; 

funds  are  appropriated  by  laws  limited  to  appropriations.   This 

provision  should  require  the  Reform  Act  to  be  referred  to  the 

Appropriations  Committee. 

5.  The  provisions  for  reasonably  compensating  master 
marketers  for  sales  and  renewals  in  section  507(c)(3)  and  for 
indemnifying  agents  for  FCIC  errors  are  eliminated. 

6.  Local  USDA  offices  will  be  required  to  make  available 
to  producers  current  and  complete  information  on  all  aspects  of 
federal  crop  insurance  and  a  listing  of  insurance  agents,   vnio 
will  provide  the  listing?  Who  will  verify  its  accuracy? 


15 


386 


7.  Different  persons  may  be  eligible  for  catastrophic  risk 
protection  insurance  than  for  other  plans  of  insurance.   Any 
producer  that  meets  the  definition  of  "person"  as  defined  by  the 
Secretary  is  eligible  for  the  former.   A  producer  who  is  at  least 
18  and  has  a  bona  fide  insurable  interest  in  a  crop  as  an  owner- 
operator,  landlord,  tenant  or  sharecropper  is  eligible  for  the 
higher  levels  of  coverage.   This  distinction  is  needless. 
Moreover,  it  creates  another  audit  responsibility  and  another 
layer  of  record  keeping. 

8.  The  Reform  Act  authorizes  the  Secretary  to  establish  a 
permanent  advisory  committee  to  advise  the  Secretary  on  the 
implementation  of  the  Act. 

9.  The  Reform  Act  is  to  t«Uce  effect  beginning  with  the 
crop  year  immediately  following  its  enactment.   Different  crops, 
however,  have  different  crop  years. 

10.  The  Reform  Act  neither  defines  nor  sets  forth  standards 
for  the  definition  of  the  term  "market  price."  This  definition 
is  crucial  to  participation  and  should  not  be  left  to  changing 
administrative  fiats. 

IX   MOWINSURED  ASSISTANCE 
The  Reform  Act  creates  a  program  of  noninsured  assistance  to 
provide  the  equivalent  of  catastrophic  risk  protection  for  crops 
for  which  catastrophic  insurance  is  not  available.   Noninsured 
assistance  does  not  cover  losses  due  to:   (1)  the  producer's 
neglect  or  malfeasance;  (2)  the  producer's  failure  to  reseed  to 
the  same  crop  where  it  is  customary  to  do  so;  and  (3)  the 

16 


387 


producer's  failure  to  follow  good  farming  practices,  as  defined 
by  the  FCIC. 

Producers  must  apply  to  the  USDA  for  assistance;  provide  all 
required  records  to  the  FCIC  or  accept  a  yield  as  determined  by 
the  FCIC;  and  report  acreage  planted  and  prevented  from  being 
planted  by  the  acreage  reporting  date.   Producers  of  non-program 
crops  are  not  eligible  unless  the  area  average  yield  for  the 
particular  crop  falls  below  65  percent  of  the  expected  area 
yield. 

The  FCIC  is  to  make  a  prevented  planting  payment  if  the 
producer  is  prevented  from  planting  more  than  3  5  percent  of  the 
acreage  intended  for  the  crop.   The  FCIC  is  to  make  a  reduced 
yield  noninsured  assistance  payment  if  the  total  quantity  of  the 
crop  that  a  producer  is  able  to  harvest  on  any  farm  is  less  than 
50  percent  of  the  expected  area  yield,  factored  for  the 
producer's  interest  in  the  crop.   (Query,  if  a  producer  harvests 
less  than  50  percent  of  the  expected  area  yield  on  one  farm  and 
more  than  50  percent  on  another,  can  the  producer  receive  a 
payment  for  both  farms  because  a  loss  occurred  on  "any  farm"?) . 

A  "person"  (as  opposed  to  a  producer)  who  has  qualifying 
gross  revenues  in  excess  of  $2  million  is  not  eligible  for 
noninsured  assistance  payments. 

Payments  of  noninsured  assistance  shall  be  made  for  losses 
in  excess  of  50  percent  of  the  established  yield  at  60  percent  of 


388 


the  average  market  price  for  that  crop.'  Payments  under  this 
progran  that  a  person  is  entitled  to  receive  nay  not  exceed 
$100,000. 


March  14,  1994 


'  This  section  is  poorly  drafted.   Literally,  it  states  that 
payments  shall  be  mad*  for  losses  in  excess  of  30  percent,  i.e. . 
"in  excess  of  50  percent  of  the  established  yield  for  the  crop  at 
60  percent  of  the  average  market  price."   The  section  should 
state  "payments  shall  be  made  for  losses  in  excess  of  50  percent 
of  the  established  yield  for  the  crop  indBBPK^***  at  60  percent 
of  the  average  market  price." 

18 


389 


EXECUTIVE  OFFICE  OF  THS  PRESIDBNT 
OPnCS  OF  MANAOIMINT  AND  lUMVT 

WAawwroN,  O.O.  soaia 


April  14.  1994 

Bononible  Maitin  Olav  Sabo 

Cmnmitiec  oa  tl»  Budget 
U.S.  Hooic  of  Sqiireseatativei 
Wuhlostoii.  D.C.  20S1S 

DMT  Mr.  C3ialrman: 

Laat  month,  the  Dqmtmait  of  A(nciilture,  oo  behalf  of  fiia  Administiation,  unveiled 
in  innovitive  |KOpoul  to  refism  Ao  Fedenl  govenuoBot'i  rale  in  helpin|  &nnen  itnick  by 
utmil  dinsten.  The  plan  comUna  two  lednndanl,  npeuiive  govenunent  prognma  -^ 
Fedenl  oop  iniuiaacc  tnd  Fedenl  ad  hoc  diaster  xeUef  -  into  a  angle,  unified,  on  budget 
pTQgnm.  Ta  the  proccu,  tutaea  and  tazpayen  both  benefit  from  greater  oedalnly,  and 
taxpayoa  aave  $750  mtlllon  in  ftffidfinciaa  over  fiw  jfcan. 

This  inidattve  gicw  directly  fiom  the  Pnddent'i  visits  to  tbt  devastated  Midwest 
flood  areas  last  sommcr.  He  and  other  Admlnistnlioa  officials  met  widi  many  vlcdms  of 
that  catastrophe,  fiomen  and  noa-faimen  alike,  and  the  Administntion  promised  to  make 
govecament  WQik  better  to  deliver  help  in  a  crisis.  Now,  we  must  locq)  dnt  promiae. 

Ai  the  FY  1993  budget  lesolutlaa  confiacnce  convenes  oeod  week,  I  uige  the 
conferees  to  malm  the  needed  yearly  baseline  a4)ustment  of  $1  billion  to  reflect  histodcal 
spending  on  crap  disaster  relief,  so  that  our  crop  Insunnoe  reform  plan  can  move  fiorwaid.  I 
strongly  believe  dut  this  baseline  adjustment  win  more  accurately  reflect  Fedenl  govenunent 
qwnding  pacdoei  and  win  result  in  a  men  icalistic  FY  1993  budget  jcsolulioo. 

The  Admbdstntlon's  crap  insurance  jdan  is  a  model  for  making  government  perform 
better  for  people.  It  dlminales  redundant  prognnu,  it  promotea  realistic  budgeting,  it  relies 
tm  the  private  sector  to  deliver  goveffimental  assistancft,  and  11  provides  security  and 
confidence  fot  American  pradnoen. 

I  hope  you  will  support  us  In  this  Important  e£R»t. 

SlnceselT. 


■X"' 


390 


Statement  of  Plains  Cotton  Growers,  Inc. 

On  Proposed  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Reforms 

Presented  By  Myrl  D.  Mitchell 

March  29, 1994 


I  would  just  like  to  say  a  short  thank  you  to  Congressman  Combest 
and  to  Mr.  Ackerman  for  taking  the  time  to  be  here  this  morning.  My  name 
is  Myrl  D.  Mitchell  and  I  am  a  cotton  producer  and  ginner  from  Lenorah, 
Texas.  I  am  here  today  to  present  a  few  comments  on  behalf  of  the  producer 
members  of  Plains  Cotton  Growers  many  of  whom  are  constituents  of  yours 
Congressman  Combest.  As  you  are  no  doubt  aware  this  area  produces  some 
15  to  20  percent  of  the  cotton  grown  in  the  United  States  each  year.  We  plant 
on  average  three  to  three  and  one-hsJf  million  acres  of  cotton  in  the  25 
counties  surrounding  Lubbock.  Through  the  years  the  need  for  affordable, 
high  quality  income  protection  has  been  a  constant  for  the  producers  in  this 
area.  In  fact  many  of  the  banks  we  deal  with  now  require  crop  insurance 
before  a  producer  can  obtain  financing  to  grow  his  next  crop.  Through  the 
years  cotton  producers  on  the  High  Plains  have  becoine  well  acquainted 
with  Federal  Crop  Insurance  and  we  believe  their  experiences  shed  light  on 

4 

the  good  and  bad  contained  in  the  current  system.  " 

Making  a  viable  crop  insurance  progreun  available  is  vitally 
important  to  the  producers  in  this  area.  Like  you,  we  believe  that  a  move 
needs  to  be  made  towards  making  Federal  Crop  Insurance  work  and  away 
from  ad  hoc  disaster  programs  that,  while  helpful,  often  illustrates  the  old 
saying  "its  too  little,  too  late".  Here  on  the  High  Plains,  producers  need  a 
responsive  form  of  protection  that  allows  them  to  protect  themselves  and 
provide  the  greatest  number  of  alternatives  following  a  crop  loss.  Any 
reforms  that  are  made  to  the  current  crop  insurance  system  need  to  be 


391 


fiscally  sound,  both  from  the  government's  point  of  view  of  limiting  the 
overall  losses  and  from  a  producers  point  of  view  that  the  coverage  provided 
must  be  economically  accessible  and  adequately  meet  his  protection 
requirements. 

I  would  also  like  to  point  out  that  in  the  past  producers  often  decided 
not  to  take  crop  insurance  because  the  potential  return  they  could  expect  did 
not  adequately  reflect  the  yields  they  typically  manage  for  and  count  on  to 
msike  a  profit.  Much  of  this  is  due  to  the  adoption  of  many  of  the  latest 
tillage,  irrigation  and  fertilization  technologies  that  allow  them  to  grow 
more  high  quality  cotton  on  the  same  number  of  acres.  Accordingly  a 
method  of  developing  yields  for  insurance  purposes  that  more  closely 
matches  the  actual  production  capabilities  of  a  farm  or  farmer  is  an 
absolute  necessity  and  I  believe  we  are  on  the  right  path  with  the  use  of 
Actual  Production  History  (APH). 

The  last  point  I  would  like  to  make  regarding  the  old  crop  insurance 
system  basically  sums  up  what  producers  have  felt  about  the  coverage 
available.  The  general  feeling  was  that  crop  insurance  cost  too  much  and 
provided  too  little  protection  in  the  event  of  a  loss.  This  is  probably  the  major 
reason  crop  insurance  has  been  underutilized  as  a  management  tool  in  the 
past. 

Now  that  you  know  some  of  the  concerns  producers  have  had  with 
crop  insurance  in  the  past,  lets  look  at  how  the  federal  crop  insurance 
reform  proposal  addresses  some  of  these  issues.  In  general  the  current 
proposal  addresses  most  of  the  concerns  we  have  voiced  over  and  over 
through  the  years.  It  has  many  changes  that  we  wholeheartedly  approve  as 
well  as  some  things  that  we  feel  need  to  be  explored  further.  The  idea  of 
providing  basic  catastrophic  coverage  at  a  minimal  cost,  allowing 


392 


producers  the  option  to  purchase  additional  coverage  levels  up  to  85  percent 
of  their  insurable  yields,  and  providing  a  mechanism  through  which  a 
producers  true  production  potential  is  used  as  the  insured  yield  are  all 
excellent  suggestions.  There  are  many  more  good  points  in  the  proposal, 
however,  I  do  not  ^ave  the  time  to  get  into  them  right  now.  We,  the  Federal 
Crop  Insurance  Corporation,  legislators  and  producers,  need  to  continue  to 
work  together  to  work  out  reforms  that  will  make  affordable,  high  quality 
catastrophic  crop  insurance  a  reality.  We  have  taken  a  giant  step  towards 
achieving  this  goal  and  we  welcome  the  opportunity  to  participate  in  this 
process. 

Along  those  lines  there  are  several  areas  in  which  we  feel  further 
work  needs  to  be  done.  We  would  like  to  see  more  work  done  to  refme 
variables  such  as  harvest  incentives  and  de  minimus  j^elds  that  are  fair  to 
both  the  producer  and  federal  government.  Improvement  in  adjustment 
procedures  and  speedier  adjustments  are  also  high  on  the  list  of  producers 
looking  for  change.  Again,  these  are  only  a  few  of  the  things  that  come  to 
mind.  I'm  sure  that  before  this  process  is  finished  there  will  be  a  number  of 
further  changes  and  that  each  will  make  the  orerall  package  better  and 
more  attractive  to  producers.  In  conclusion  let  me  say  that  I  appreciate  the 
opportunity  to  be  here  today  and  talk  about  some  of  the  issues  that  are  on  the 
minds  of  people  from  this  area.  We  seem  to  be  on  the  right  track  and  the 
proposed  changes  address  many  of  the  concerns  and  answer  some  of  the 
questions  producers  have  about  Federal  Crop  Insurance.  Thank  you. 


393 


Testimony  of 

William  R.  Weber 

President  and  Chief  Executive  Officer 

The  Farm  Credit  Council 

before  the 

Subcommittee  on  Environment,  Credit  and  Rural  Development 
U.S.  House  of  Representatives 

April  21.  1994 


394 


Mr.  Chairman  and  members  of  the  subcommittee,  thank  you  for  allowing  us  the 
opportunity  to  show  our  support  for  reform  of  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Program.   I  testify 
today  on  behalf  of  the  institutions  of  the  Farm  Credit  System,  which  are  committed  to 
working  with  the  administration  and  this  subcommittee  to  help  provide  farmers  with  a  high 
quality  crop  insurance  product  at  an  affordable  price. 

Farm  Credit  is  in  a  unique  position  in  the  crop  insurance  industry.    As  a  provider  of 
credit  to  production  agriculture.  Farm  Credit  depends  on  crop  insurance  to  preserve  the  value 
of  its  loan  collateral.    As  a  provider  of  crop  insurance  to  its  farmer/borrowers.  Farm  Credit  is 
keenly  interested  in  the  marketability  of  the  product.    Finally,  as  a  cooperative  owned  and 
directed  primarily  by  agricultxiral  producers,  we  advocate  a  crop  insurance  program  that 
provides  farmers  with  the  best  possible  tool  to  manage  one  of  their  most  unmanageable  risks  - 
-  weather. 

From  each  of  these  perspectives,  the  Farm  Credit  System  supports  the  administration's 
proposed  crop  insurance  reform  package.    We  congratulate  Secretary  Espy  and  his  staff,  and 
especially  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation  Manager  Ken  Ackerman,  on  their  proposal. 
We  also  thank  you  and  your  subcommittee,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  quick  consideration  of  the 
proposal  and  for  providing  this  and  other  forums  across  the  country  for  farmers  and  others  in 
agriculture  to  express  their  views. 

Today,  I  would  like  to  make  several  points  about  the  proposed  legislation.    First  and 
most  important,  since  the  Congress  through  its  budget  process  will  be  making  the  initial 
decision  on  crop  insurance  reform  very  soon,  we  urge  members  to  vote  for  full  funding  of  the 
administration's  proposed  program. 

By  combining  the  money  used  for  crop-related  disaster  payments  with  the  money 
already  being  spent  on  crop  insurance.  Congress  can  provide  farmers  with  a  high  quality  tool 
to  manage  weather-related  risks  at  a  price  that  will  attract  enough  participation  to  make  the 
program  viable.     With  cunent  crop  insurance  participation  rates  at  just  over  30  percent  of 
eligible  acres,  the  program  cannot  be  actuarially  sound  and  affordable  to  farmers.    To  get  the 
kind  of  participation  rate  necessary  for  a  true  insurance  program,  the  product  must  provide  a 
benefit  that  producers  consider  worth  the  price.   Full  funding  for  the  proposal  is  crucial  for  its 
success. 

In  addition,  a  budget-conscious  Congress  could  find  needed  budget  savings  ft^om  the 
elimination  of  crop-related  disaster  payments.   Almost  every  year,  a  region  of  the  United 
States  faces  severe  weather  or  natural  disaster.    If  it's  not  a  flood,  it's  a  drought.    If  not  an 
earthquake,  then  a  hurricane.   Under  the  current  disaster  program,  the  federal  government's 
costs  are  uncontrollable.    In  an  atmosphere  where  the  budget  deficit  is  forcing  hard  decisions 
in  farm  policy,  cost  control  is  critical. 

The  administration's  proposal  takes  money  that  is  already  being  spent,  uses  it  to  fund  a 
program  that  will  provide  farmers  with  the  risk  management  tools  they  need  at  price  they  can 


395 


afford,  and  lowers  the  budget  deficit.    It's  good  farm  and  fiscal  policy  and  the  Fann  Credit 
System  heartily  endorses  it.    Again  Mr.  Chairman,  we  urge  Congress  to  fully  fund  the 
administration's  request.    Inadequate  funding  severely  limits  the  possibility  for  workable 
reform  of  the  program  and  potentially  exposes  U.S.  fanners  to  uncontrollable  risk. 

My  final  two  points  are  more  technical  details  and  concern  the  proposed  dual  delivery 
system  and  the  processing  fee  for  the  catastrophic  product. 

Dual  Delivery  System 

Currently,  when  they  purchase  crop  insurance  products,  farmers  have  the  benefit  of 
service  from  trained  professional  crop  insurance  agents,  be  they  located  in  insurance  agencies, 
banks,  Farm  Credit  institutions,  or  elsewhere.    Risks  and  needs  vary  across  the  nation,  and 
farmers  need  sound  advice  when  they  try  to  decide  which  insurance  product  is  right  for  their 
particular  operation. 

Farmers  benefit  from  the  professional  advice  they  receive  when  purchasing  insurance 
from  an  experienced  insurance  professional.    Under  the  proposed  dual  delivery  mechanism, 
USDA  will  be  forced  to  absorb  the  huge  cost  of  training  its  staff  to  essentially  do  the  job 
private  agents  are  already  prepared  to  do.    We  are  also  concerned  that  because  USDA  would 
offer  only  catastrophic  coverage,  farmers  would  be  left  with  the  impression  that  government  is 
advocating  only  this  level  of  coverage. 

We  agree  that  in  some  areas  of  the  United  States,  the  capacity  of  the  private  crop 
insurance  delivery  network  will  be  unable  to  handle  the  increase  in  volume  once  the 
mandatory  participation  requirements  are  in  place.   The  Farm  Credit  System,  with  238  local 
lending  institutions  and  almost  fourteen  hundred  local  offices  nationwide,  can  help  ease  the 
burden.    We  hope  to  work  with  the  committee  to  explore  options  in  this  area  and  to  preserve 
the  private  delivery  system. 

Processing  Fee  for  Catastrophic  Covera2e 

Under  current  practices  and  procedures  required  for  participation  in  the  crop  msurance 
program,  a  SSO  fee  for  processing  an  application  is  probably  insufficient  for  most  institutions 
to  cover  the  cost  of  necessary  overhead.    However,  with  participation  in  the  catastrophic 
program  a  condition  of  participation  in  other  USDA  farm  programs,  it  is  very  important  to 
keep  down  the  cost  to  producers. 

By  significantly  reducing  the  paperwork  process,  it  might  be  possible  to  provide 
farmers  with  the  lowest  possible  fee  requirement  without  requiring  private  insurance  vendors 
to  lose  money  when  they  take  a  catastrophic  application.    It  might  be  possible  to  streamline 
the  application  needed  to  obtain  catastrophic  insurance  coverage. 

Agents  could  collect  only  a  very  limited  amount  of  information  at  application  time. 
One  page  of  basic  data  about  the  producer  and  his  or  her  operation  might  be  sufficient    Only 
af^er  a  producer  filed  a  claim,  would  more  detailed  information,  like  proof  of  yield,  be 


396 


required.    Producer  and  agent  alike  would  benefit  from  such  an  arrangement. 

In  summary  Mr.  Chairman,  the  Fann  Credit  System  supports  the  administration's 
efTorts  to  reform  the  Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation's  programs.   We  remain  concerned 
however,  that  the  program  will  receive  inadequate  funding.    Without  adequate  fimding,  the 
program  has  little  chance  to  offer  the  high  quality  risk  management  tool  fanners  need. 

We  look  forward  to  working  widi  this  subcommittee  and  the  administration  toward 
swift  enactment  of  the  proposal.   Thank  you  again  for  this  opportunity  to  testify. 

o 


BOSTON  PUBLIC  LIBRARY 


3  9999  05018  507  1 


ISBN  0-16-046037-9 


780160"460371 


90000